Tuesday, May 30, 2000

Pipeline Regulations Flawed

Duke Energy's Eastern Gas Pipeline will soon carry gas between the Bass Strait and Sydney.  Regulators' manoeuvrings regarding this new pipeline have demonstrated that the regulatory structure, finalised only last year, is seriously flawed.

Under the national Gas Code, pipelines are generally envisaged to be natural monopolies.  Their prices are regulated and they are not allowed to discriminate between potential users.

Two alternative regulatory routes are in place.

The first is through Graeme Samuel's National Competition Council (NCC).  This establishes the need for regulation, then passes the baton to Alan Fels' Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) to determine prices.

The alternative is for the ACCC to accept an "undertaking" by the pipeline owner on price and other conditions.  At least according to the ACCC, this pre-empts the need for NCC involvement.

These alternatives have resulted in a regulatory demarcation dispute with both the ACCC and the NCC seeking to control the regulation of Duke's Eastern Gas Pipeline.  That pipeline will compete in the NSW market with the existing East Australia Pipeline (EAPL) which transports gas from the Cooper Basin.  EAPL is presently majority owned by AGL but is in the process of being floated.

Faced with two alternative regulatory paths, for its part, Duke opted for the ACCC route, because this allows it to offer a uniform price while avoiding the Gas Code procedures with their tortuous and inflexible cost based pricing formulae.  But both regulatory paths leaves Duke vulnerable since the company already has the pipeline in the ground and can hardly walk away in the face of regulatory zeal to lower prices.  And, in the past, the ACCC has only accepted price "undertakings" after slicing something off suppliers' proposed prices.

A more fundamental issue than who has the regulatory authority is why should there be any regulation at all?  The existence of two transmission pipelines serving NSW is the very definition of competition, the absence of which provided the initial rationale for regulation.

Some may claim that the two pipelines both need to be controlled because they traverse different paths.  But it is rarely the case that two competitive products are identical and if we were to use their differences to justify regulation, almost everything would be covered.  Two robust competitors, as long as they do not collude, are usually sufficient to bring the required efficiency driving customer focus.  With the Eastern Gas Pipeline and EAPL, we have Coke versus Pepsi, Ansett versus Qantas, and Lion Nathan versus Fosters.  Competition -- even where there are only two rivals -- prevents price-gouging and promotes cost savings far more effectively than regulation.  And it does so without the price distortions and paperburden costs that are inevitable with regulation.

Hence the issue for the Eastern Gas Pipeline is not whether the ACCC or the NCC should regulate the NSW pipelines.  Competition has broken out.  The Eastern Gas Pipeline should not be regulated and the regulatory controls on the existing East Australian Pipeline from the Cooper Basin should be lifted.  EAPL and Duke both now take the view that regulation of the two competing pipelines is unnecessary and constitutes paperburden costs and costly operational rigidities.

Not so the NCC.  In its draft recommendation it has shown an admirable defence of its regulatory turf.  Unsurprisingly, it has confirmed that it, rather than the ACCC, should determine the need for regulation.  In addition, assuring itself of a continuing busy-body role, the NCC wishes to regulate both pipelines on the basis that they are not exactly parallel.  And it further argues that even if the lines were parallel regulation would be necessary because each of the lines would have "market power"!

The distressing aspect of all this is the negative value the regulatory authorities add.  If each new pipeline needs to pass an exhaustive regulatory review before it can seek customers, there will be far fewer pipelines built.  Companies will be unwilling to leave their money hostage to an unnecessary regulatory regime and consumers will lose fuel choice options.  Ironically, not only will this mean fewer opportunities for increased income but it will mean fewer competitive pressures.

Of course, the regulatory authorities will gain since they are assured of an on-going role for themselves.  But should we really be running the economy for the benefit of the regulators?  For gas, electricity, telecommunications, ports, etc.  Australia's supposed "light handed" regulation is a masquerade for one of the world's most intrusive regulatory regimes.  The demarcation dispute between the regulators over gas illustrates the absurdity of the present regulatory morass.  The NCC's draft recommendation on the matter indicates some urgency in the need to revisit the entire regulatory structure.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, May 28, 2000

Airbrush Has no Place in History

"The struggle of man against power is the struggle of memory against forgetting", wrote the Czech dissident novelist Milan Kundera.  One of the stories he told in "The Book of Laughter and Forgetting" is of Vladimir Clementis, the Foreign Affairs Minister of Czechoslovakia in the early days of the Communist regime, who was hanged in 1952 on trumped up charges of treason.

The authorities immediately airbrushed Clementis's image out of a famous photo which showed him standing next to the Communist leader Klement Gottwald during a triumphal party rally in 1948.  All that remained of Clementis was his fur cap, which he had placed on Gottwald's bare head to protect his leader from the snow just before the photo was taken.

Having lived under a regime which drastically rewrote history to suit its own sordid ends, Kundera understood that truth is always the potential enemy of powerful vested interests.  This tension is present even in liberal democratic states such as our own, and when politicians start talking about "historical facts" people suspect that they may well be thinking of a past which has been airbrushed clean of embarrassing details.

Given the loathing Australia's intellectuals feel for Prime Minister John Howard, it is not surprising that this is how they chose to interpret remarks he made last month that school history teachers had placed "perhaps a little too much of an emphasis on issues rather than on exactly what happened".  Professor Martin Stuart-Fox from the University of Queensland claimed in the Courier-Mail that this must mean history should "avoid all those aspects of Australian society that Howard would prefer not to discuss -- such as deviation, deprivation, multiculturalism or Aboriginal affairs".

John Tonkin, professor of history at the University of Western Australia, sneered that Mr Howard had a "simplistic understanding" because "history is not just facts".  But the Prime Minister never suggested that it was.  He was merely urging a more balanced integration between teaching facts to school children and exploring broad issues, and by giving their own jaundiced and misleading twist to his actual statement, the history profs were demonstrating that Mr Howard really did have a point.  Clearly, the facts don't matter much to these guys.

Without a good knowledge of exactly what did happen, any consideration of historical "issues" is always likely to become captive to political fashion and feelgood moralising, which is what seems to be occurring in many Australian schools and universities today.  Students can discuss "deviation, deprivation, multiculturalism or Aboriginal affairs" till their bodies light up with a warm inner glow, but unless their discussions are constrained by a rigorous adherence to facts, they might as well be playing video games.

Unfortunately, along with conservation and the environment, these four issues are the very ones where academics have been most diligent in applying a political airbrush, and where hard information is always under threat of contamination by propaganda -- usually of the "Australia is wicked" kind.

The problem is made worse by many academics in the humanities and social sciences believing that "truths" and "facts" are culturally constructed.  According to them, people who insist on drawing a firm distinction between fact and fiction are "privileging" a white Western view at the expense of other equally valid ways of thinking about the world.

At a Melbourne University seminar a few years ago, I heard a prominent "progressive" historian cheerfully explain that all she and her colleagues could hope to do with their research and writing was to present coherent and interesting stories;  but stories whose truth could never be decided.  A Holocaust survivor in the audience told her that this was a foolish and highly irresponsible position, which made it easier for people like David Irving and other Holocaust deniers to spread their lies.

The historian indignantly rejected any suggestion that this might be the consequence of her remarks.  But she could not explain why it was possible to speak of facts in relation to the Holocaust, and not about other historical events.  The seminar broke up in turmoil and bitter recriminations, with the "story teller" and her supporters refusing to join their critics at the customary post-seminar meal at a nearby restaurant.

Certainly, in many circumstances determining "exactly what happened" can be a very difficult task.  Students need to learn how historians and other scholars handle conflicting evidence, and the criteria for deciding why one account might be preferable to another.  Some kinds of facts are harder to establish than others, and certain matters, such as a person's reasons for behaving in a particular way, will always be open to interpretation and debate.  But none of this is any excuse for ridiculing those who call for a greater emphasis on factual information in the teaching of history.

One of the great strengths of a liberal democratic society is the widespread belief in the importance of ensuring the independence and neutrality of the courts, the media, and the universities.  In their different ways, and with varying effectiveness, these institutions ensure that collective memory is not lost or seriously distorted, and so help to protect us from abuses common in societies where political or economic power reigns untrammelled, and where the airbrushing of history can proceed with little hindrance.

But these institutions can achieve their purpose only if they are committed to a notion of objective truth, and if they jealously guard the rules and procedures that are designed to discover and transmit the facts about the situations they investigate.

By stressing the importance of historical facts, John Howard may be expressing a notion that seems hopelessly simplistic and unfashionable to our sophisticated "progressive" intellectuals.  But his comments -- and the intellectuals' response -- show that he has a better instinctive understanding of the things that protect our freedoms than they have.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, May 27, 2000

Black and White Corroboree

Many people will feel really good about themselves after walking across Sydney Harbour Bridge next Sunday, as part of the weekend's Corroboree 2000 events.

The walk, and Saturday's formal launch of the "Declaration Towards Reconciliation" at the Sydney Opera House, are supposed to be the pinnacle of the decade-long reconciliation process.  Participants will be making a symbolic statement that they are committed to the vision of "a united Australia that respects this land of ours;  values the Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander heritage;  and provides justice and equity for all".

For nothing more than the cost of their travel to the Harbour Bridge and their time, they will be telling the world that they are caring and righteous people.  Not like all those other Australians, such as heartless John Howard and his legion of redneck supporters, who refuse to apologise to the "stolen generations" and reject the idea of indigenous rights and Aboriginal self-determination.

And that points to the key problem with the whole reconciliation process.  Despite protestations to the contrary, it is not about healing, or about celebrating the common humanity which binds Aboriginal and non-Aboriginal Australians.  Rather, it has become a highly political exercise designed to pressure governments and people into supporting an unpopular agenda which is much more likely to bring increased divisiveness and resentment than unity.

An overwhelming number of Australians now acknowledge that serious wrongs were done to Aborigines in the past, sometimes through contempt or animosity, sometimes through indifference, and sometimes as a result of good intentions that were badly misguided.  But it is also clear that the majority of Australians are deeply troubled by calls for special indigenous rights and other separatist measures.

These Australians may not have the academics' detailed grasp of every outrage committed over the past two centuries, and some may well be blasé about the extent of the humiliation and suffering that many Aborigines experienced.  But they possess a compensating quality that most of our pious intellectuals and clerics lack -- a common sense which alerts them to the dangers of currently fashionable ideas about indigenous affairs.

We could even say that these Australians have a better grasp of the real lesson to be learnt from the depressing history of relations between black and white in this country.  The root cause of all the problems has been the belief that Aborigines are a different sort of human being from other Australians, with different kinds of rights and civil obligations.  But the inappropriately named "Declaration Towards Reconciliation" has not addressed this destructive belief.

Indeed, with its talk of the "unique status" of Aborigines and Torres Strait Islanders, its sly reference to a "treaty", its call for what can only be a racially based "self-determination", and its failure to recognise that it is advocating an impossible jumble of inconsistencies, the declaration will only perpetuate this kind of thinking.

It takes a particular kind of mind-set to believe that the follies we are being offered in the name of reconciliation will create a more harmonious nation, or that they will help to reduce the deplorable levels of social and economic disadvantage that blight large parts of Aboriginal Australia.  It is a mind-set which values conspicuous displays of moral fervour over carefully considered and honestly presented solutions to national problems.

But don't get me wrong.  It is possible that some good may still come out of next Sunday's walk across the bridge in Sydney.  Invigorated by bracing harbour breezes and the marvellous vistas of a great city, some of the participants may be moved to reflect on the reasons why ten years of reconciliation seem to have produced so little of lasting benefit.

Even better, they may find that they have far more in common with the Aboriginal person walking next to them than they had ever been led to believe, and so begin the kind of friendship on which true reconciliation is based.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, May 19, 2000

Urban Transport -- the Ideologues are back in the driver seat

A mark of a good government is a willingness to jettison ideological baggage and silly ideas accumulated in opposition.

Although the Bracks Government has shown promise in some areas, it remains strangely unreconstructed in the area of urban road transport.

For decades urban road planning in Melbourne was controlled and contorted by ideologues and interests groups.  Planning has been dominated by people who hated cars, freeways and suburbs.  Interest groups prevented change and politicians used the transport budget as lolly bag.

As a result the urban transit system in and around Melbourne has until recently has been a logistical mess.  All roads converged chaotically into the CBD despite people and jobs moving to the suburbs.  There were few expressways and those that existed where short in length and not interconnected.

The Kennett Government changed the urban transport landscape for the better.  It instituted a planning process which diluted the influence of interest groups.  It put in place a long term road transport plan which included an integrated network of radial and orbital expressways.  As part of this plan the Kennett Government converted the South Eastern Arterial into a freeway by the replacing stop lights with overpasses.  The Government also expanded the western ring road and commissioned City Link toll road complex.

In opposition the Labor Party opposed virtually all these reforms even when they were clearly in the public interest.  They are continuing this short sighted opposition in Government.

They have dropped the commitment to an integrated network of expressways.  While continuing with the extension of the Eastern Freeway to Ringwood, they have abandoned the Scoresby Freeway proposal which would links the Frankston industrial belt to the City Link system.  They have failed to address the remaining bottle necks in the orbital system including the Hume Freeway from Craigieburn to the Metropolitan Ring Road, Western Freeway from Rockbank to the Metropolitan Ring Road at Deer Park and link between the Eastern Freeway to City Link.

The abandonment of the orbital network is not for lack of money or identified need.  The Government is loaded with cash, thanks to Kennett and Co, and is committed to "Linking Victoria".  Moreover the urban expressway network could be completed at no cost to the State or to spending in the bush or to spending on public transport.  That is by extending the City Link system.  But alas the Bracks Government remains wedded to a no toll policy.

The Government's opposition to the network stems from a lack of political will to override noisy interest groups and car haters.

Victoria will suffer from this short sightedness.  As an anonymous Treasury official stated in this weeks crikey.com.au, logistics ... "is a major business in these days of electronic B2B commerce and web-based retailing:  fulfilment of orders means moving things around in trucks and planes and trains.  Those best at this, win.  Melbourne's national "hub" function puts it in front now.  To stay there, Melbourne must invest.  Scoresby is the next key link in the logistics chain".

I hope the Treasurer is listening.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, May 12, 2000

Should the Constitution expressly recognise the indigenous peoples of Australia?

Speaking Notes for Talk at Regional Schools Constitutional Convention,
Lowther Hall Anglican Girls Grammar, Thursday 11 May 2000


  • This is one of those "how long is a piece of string?" questions.  The answer is:  it depends on how and why.
  • For most of the history of the Australian Federation, Aboriginal Australians were specially mentioned in the Australian Constitution until the 1967 referendum removed those references.
  • That referendum was the most consensual political act ever put to the Australian people, with a total "Yes" vote of over 90% -- it was more successful than the original proposals to federate Australia.
  • The reason the removal of those provisions -- that Aboriginals not be counted in the Census and that the Commonwealth could legislate for any race other than Aboriginals -- was so popular is that those provisions transgressed a very powerful Australian norm:  that there should be one set of rules for everyone.
  • This norm -- one set of rules for everyone -- is, in fact, a very liberating norm.  It is hard to overstate its power.
  • The position of women has improved dramatically from its power.  The position of minorities have improved greatly from its power.  The point that we are all "just people", with the same basic rights and obligations is a powerful and liberating idea.
  • No reference which seriously transgresses that norm should be included in the Constitution.
  • Which is just as well, since no reference which transgresses that norm will be included.  The Australian public will never vote for it.
  • We should be careful not to mistake media debate and comment for public opinion.  Polling clearly indicates that constitutional matters are not a major popular concern -- not even during the recent Republic debate.  And it was particularly perverse to commentators blame Howard when he is the only PM in our history to allow a proposal he did not agree with to go to the people:  neither of his immediate predecessors, Bob Hawke and Paul Keating, would ever had done that.
  • People are clearly reluctant to change the Constitution.  Of the 44 amendment proposals put to the people, only eight have passed.
  • Yet, if a proposal has the support of both sides of politics, they tend to pass.  Of the 13 proposals supported by both Prime Minister and Opposition Leader of the day, eight have passed.  None have passed without such support.
  • Should also be very careful about handing power over to judges, which adding claims or principles to the Constitution can easily do.  The popular support for mandatory sentencing fairly clearly comes from a distrust of judges.  The role of judges is important, but should be limited, since it is so difficult to hold them accountable.
  • Indigenous Australians do confront very particular historical legacies.
  • It may be appropriate to acknowledge that ancestors of indigenous Australians were the first human occupants of this land, but we are ultimately about building a common society, with common general rules, and our Constitution should reflect that.

Budget Gets the Tick

Mr Court faced two challenges in this year's budget which go to the core of his credibility as a economic manager.

First he had to produce a credible measure of the bottom-line.  Second he had to put the budget back on a sustainable footing.

He accomplishes both in the 2000-2001 State Budget.

Over the last 12 months we received four different and divergent measures of the bottom-line.  Applied to this year's accounts these produce results ranging from a healthy surplus to a massive deficit.  Understandably people have become more than a bit confused and sceptical.

The Budget properly solves this by adopting an accounting system developed by the Australian Bureau of Statistics.

What the 2000-2001 Budget shows -- and one suspects why the this accounting system was not used in previous years -- is that the budget has been in deficit in each of the last four years.

What this means is that the government has been borrowing to meet operating or running costs for each of the last four years.  In short, it has been relying on the proverbial Bankcard.

Its only been able to run these deficits without losing its triple-A credit rating because of gains from privatisation.  However, if they continue the deficit spending much longer, a down grading is on the cards.

The Court Government has in place -- indeed is continuing with -- a massive capital works program.  However, capital spending has not been the problem.  The budget is an operating budget and it does not include capital spending.  The deficits have arisen simply because the running cost have exceed taxes, grants and other income.

The challenge was to get the budget back into sustainable balance.

And he is on track to achieve this albeit just.  The budget is expected to finish the current year (1999-2000) in deficit by around $60 million which is about $160 million better than at the start of the year and better than the $135 million deficit record the previous year.

Importantly the budget is forecast to go into surplus next year by $42 million and remain in surplus in each of the four subsequent years.  This is not a large figure and has yet to be achieved, but is clearly in the right direction.

How has this turn-around been achieved?

First and foremost operating spending has been brought under control.  Departments have been kept to budget with few overruns -- they should after years of excessive spending.  Recurrent spending will increased -- by 3.8 per cent in 2000-2001 -- but is concentrated in priority areas including health, education, public safety and welfare.

Second, the economy is on the mend and as a result revenue is growing again.  The economy has recovered from a "growth recession" and is now growing at 4 per cent and is conservatively forecast in the Budget to improve slightly over the next few years.  Mineral royalties are up and payroll tax receipts are expected to improve with faster in employment and wage growth.

Importantly business investment which went into decline during the last few years of the 1990s, is on the rise and is expected to once again drive the WA economy.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, May 09, 2000

Globalisation:  A Blight or a Bounty?

An Address to the Essex-Heights Branch of the Liberal Party,
8 May 2000


THE DEMONISATION OF GLOBALISM

When I started to consider what I might say tonight, as a reflex action I turned to the Internet and typed in globalisation.  One of the first sites highlighted was that of our very own Pravda-on-the-Yarra, the Age.  This, the Australian Green Left daily, true to its colours offered a rich tapestry of matters addressing globalisation.

The first of these was the globalisation of sex.  This did not strike me as a new dimension of the issue and I reckoned it would prove too distracting to wade through the piece.  Other articles discussed the massive wealth divide, globalisation brings further injustice, the men have it better, the gap grows wider, and even The Globalised World According to Marx.  Predictably, Pamela Bone, the lioness of the Fitzroy communes, was able to warn Age readers that the planet would pay a high price for John Howard's short-sighted policies.

You've got to hand it to the Age.  They rarely miss an opportunity to propagandise about the ruin that capitalism and free markets are bringing to mankind.  In fact such attitudes have bounced back very rapidly since the shock of the end of Communism (in Europe) and its transformation (in China).  The tub thumping of those with faith in government managed economies barely missed a beat as the facts about the pathetic living standards, low life expectancy and general dreariness of life under the planned economy gained full frontal exposure in the wake of the 1989 Fall of the Berlin Wall

The most contemporary opposition to globalisation erupted at the recent World Trade Organisation meeting in Seattle.  That meeting was convened to do nothing more than had been done in five or six previous trade negotiation rounds.  But unlike previous such meetings we had a vast range of protesters feeding off each others' frenzies.  And they were doing so on a matter that few present understood, a matter that would otherwise have commenced a further stage along the road to having governments agree to allow their citizens the freedom to buy the goods and services they want to buy from the suppliers they favour.

The precursor to the Seattle riots occurred with an even more obscure proposal, the OECD's Multilateral Agreement on Investment.  That proposal was simply to codify what is the practice in virtually all successful world economies:  namely that foreign investors will be treated no less favourably than locals.  And if you stop to think about it, equal treatment of foreign and domestic capital is the centrepiece of the global capital flows that have allowed new world economies like Australia to develop and have been an essential ingredient to the rise of economies we once called backward.  Some of these -- HK, Taiwan, Singapore now have higher wages and living standards that many long established developed economies including Australia.


WHAT IS GLOBALISATION?

The notion encompasses several dimensions.  Some of these are traditional, particularly trade in goods.  Others, like trade in insurance and other services, have also been around a long time.  Capital movements are more modern, and the ability of nations to implement new techniques is almost the definition of a resilient and hence successful economy.  Open access to migrants, at least those capable of paying their own way, is a major aspect of this.  Indeed, prominent Japanese analysts who, acknowledging that the 20th Century was the American Century, from time to time have considered that the 21st Century will be theirs.  But, around 1990 they acknowledged that the 21st Century is also likely to be the American Century.  This is because American society and culture can readily absorb all-comers while the Japanese reject the notion of immigrant Japanese.

One vital component permitting globalisation to happen is the Rule of Law.  That is, well understood concepts of honesty and reasonableness in people dealing with each other.  This was a central feature of the growth of western civilisation as we presently know it.  Relatively unfettered trade between different political entities allowed a considerable cross fertilisation of ideas and allowed specialisation in production, while placing competitive pressures on monopolies.  And one can see for example in the Merchant of Venice how general courts arbitrated disputes so that even those considered to be outcasts obtained the same justice as others.  There was a very good reason why this was so.  Those political entities that did not offer the same respect for the rights of foreigners as they afforded their own were by-passed by traders.  They tended to decline in wealth and sometimes faced political emasculation as a result of the reduced capacity to defend themselves this entailed.

Trade and freedom of capital flows remain important aspects of globalisation today.  Freedom of capital flows -- or foreign investment -- allows countries that can convince foreigners they offer good opportunities and security to top up their domestic savings with infusions from abroad.  This is important for another dimension of globalisation:  the ability to copy other people's ideas.  Thus we see firms setting up overseas in non-tradeable services from McDonalds through to supermarkets, and construction.  The host countries benefit from these investments because they bring know-how and with it increased productivity.

Of all the forces for globalisation, the internet and telecommunications is probably the most powerful newcomer.  But there is nothing inevitable about technology driving increased economic integration.  In fact, trade was much more important in places like Australia a century ago than it was in the 1970s.  The long period of peace in the nineteenth century had brought a far greater globalisation than we were to see for close to a century -- the world was more integrated in some respects in 1900 than in 1990.  Passports, for example, were required in only the two most backward nations:  the Ottoman and Tsarist Empires.

For Australia, what is sometimes called the Deakin Settlement at the turn of the last century had two or three features that were decidedly anti-globalisation.  These included the adoption of the tariff and the White Australia policy.  The adverse effects of the first of these was supported by Australia's unique centralised wage determination system.

Australia's policy stance shifted this country further towards the false god of isolationism and away from integration with the world at large than other small and remote countries.  And we slipped from being the most prosperous nation in the world in 1900 to barely making the top twenty 90 years later.

Some of the most significant steps in unravelling this were taken by the Whitlam Government -- in most respects the worst administration in Australia's history.  Whitlam introduced the first assault on tariffs with the 25% across the board reduction.  And he put the final nail in the coffin of White Australia.

Globalisation has been a long trend, though as the setback post 1914 demonstrates it is not an inevitable one.  It is made possible by improvements in transport, and this century, improvements in communications.  Over the past forty years, the gradual increase in efficiency in sea transport has been maintained and what it took 16 days in male earnings to buy in 1950 now takes only five days earnings.  But more dramatic has been the lowering of other prices.  Thus 16 days earnings worth of air travel now takes only one and three quarters of a day to earn.  16 days' earnings of international phone calls now takes less than two hours' earnings.

And all this is being further revolutionised by the internet.  Ironically, it is the internet that has allowed disaffected groups to caucus and assist each other in pushing agendas that are in general seeking to thwart the greater global interconnection that has made their caucusing possible.

For many people in these disaffected groups, globalisation can be stylised to mean:

  • big business and an acceleration of what used to be called the rat race
  • less job security than was enjoyed in previous times
  • and a grinding down of living standards.
  • For those outside major urban areas it means an intensification of the relative disadvantages that mass populations can avoid -- communications transport, culture.

To examine what globalisation means in this stylised version I consulted one of the feral sites that were prominent in derailing the Multilateral Agreement on Investment.  The site said


1. CITIZENS WILL HAVE NO RIGHTS TO LIVELIHOOD, TO WORK, TO FOOD, TO WATER, TO SAFE ENVIRONMENT.

Well if we examine this what do we find?  The countries that have adopted globalisation most readily:  US, UK, Australia, Singapore, HK Canada, have prospered most over the past decade or so.  These countries have enjoyed rising living standards and considerable employment growth.  Within the developing nations the countries that adopted freedom of capital movements and reduced tariff protection saw an acceleration of growth.  One outstanding example in Latin America was Chile.  Castigated as a 'fascist' state in the 1970s and subject to shipping sanctions from militant unions like the freedom loving Australian Waterside Workers, its policy of reducing taxation abandoning tariff and other support for particular industries pushed its citizens prosperity to the head of the Latin countries.  Its success was not lost on others in the continent and one after the other Latin American countries have abandoned the protectionism with which they sought to insulate themselves from Yankee Imperialism.  The outcome has been an end to the sluggish growth the Continent experienced over the four decades to the 1990s and a new dynamism.

The one Latin American country that refused to join this capitalist resurgence was Cuba.  Once portrayed as the model for the Continent, Cuba is now recognised as an international basket case.  It is a place to which many are flocking to see a 1950s museum piece, but a place from which its own citizens are so desperate to escape that they take colossal risks to do so.

A similar contrast can be seen in Asia.  During my lifetime I have seen the disparity in outcomes between nations like Burma and North Korea and the Asian tiger economies.  At least two Asian Tigers have overtaken Australia and enjoy income levels twentyfold those of nations that were comparably placed forty years ago.  In a less dramatic fashion, we have seen India and Pakistan, both of which have adopted insular policies for most of the post war years, being surpassed in wealth by nations like Taiwan and South Korea.  These countries started the Post World War II era in a far more wretched condition.

Even environmental outcomes have proven to be better under globalisation embracing economies.  Partly this is because the economic freedom entailed in globalisation improves the capacity of economies to afford better environments.  In countries like Australia we have seen an immense improvement in things like Melbourne's atmospheric pollution ozone, smoke, carbon monoxide now down to half their levels of the early 1970s.  Perhaps we'll even return the Yarra to a genuine fishable and swimmable condition that has now been achieved with the Thames.

Similarly improved living standards have also allowed us to set aside more land for the environmental assets we prize.  There is for example considerably more forested area in Australia today than there was a century ago.  Partly this is due to national parks but it is also due to the increased productivity of land that has made it unnecessary and unprofitable to farm marginal land.  This is in contrast to outcomes in the poorer countries where low living standards and low levels of capital force a more intensive agriculture.

But better environmental outcomes also result from the same forces that bring globalisation.  The more insular economies with arbitrary law, like the old East European economies have had the worst possible economic outcomes with the eutrification pollution of vast inland seas and air pollution in the cities.  The better outcomes in the economies embracing globalisation have come about partly because of the accompanying facets:  individual property rights and obligations.  These mean there can be no headlong rush towards a goal if that means impinging on others' rights.  This is an automatic stabiliser that has been free societies' guardian against some of the grievous environmental outcomes seen in Eastern Europe.


2. YOU SHALL HAVE NO OTHER IDENTITY OR MORALITY EXCEPT THAT OF BEING CONSUMERS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET PLACE

The opponents of globalisation argue that it will bring a uniformity, a McDonaldisation.  Indeed at Seattle, the Starbucks coffee chain was targetted.  But nothing is further from the truth.  Globalisation means cosmopolitisation.  It has brought the transformation of Australian cuisine.  Some people object to it also bringing the Pizza Hut but their objection is to others' preferences.  We must ask ourselves whether we would rather be consumers in a global market place or in a local one.  Because if we want the latter we can opt for it.  Globalisation simply offers us an option, one that its enemies would seek to deny us, preferring instead to impose on us their own doubtlessly impeccable taste.

Opponents of globalisation also argue that the outcome will be a concentration of power in transnational firms.  This was previously a refrain in France during the 1970's with Servain-Schreiber's Le Defi Americain.  At the present time we have some transnationals growing and some downsizing.  For many years now, more jobs have been created by smaller businesses as a result of downsizing and subcontracting, the latter resulting from firms outsourcing non-core functions.  In other cases we have seen the rapid growth of the innovative firms that, at least until recently, was dragging some of the best managers away from established concerns into start-ups where they had an opportunity to back themselves and make fortunes.


3. YOU SHALL ELECT GOVERNMENTS BUT THE GOVERNMENTS' ROLE SHALL NOT BE TO PROTECT YOU.  THEY WILL PROTECT CORPORATIONS.

Well I hope the corporations will be protected from arbitrary assault.  Because if they are not, we would see the undermining of the security of property rights and the rule of law that has been the bedrock of our present prosperity.  Equally, the individual is protected from the corporation and any others who are deemed to be rich and powerful.

This demonisation of the corporation has never made less sense than it does today.  Corporations are not remote institutions owned by an oligarchy of rich people.  They are businesses desperately trying to seek out customers and ways of meeting their ever-changing needs, and doing so with a constant eye on better techniques and other cost savings.  Competition forces these cost savings to be passed on to customers if the firm is to continue to exist.

Even more significantly, the corporations are owned by individuals, by everyone who has superannuation or any other form of saving.  And the corporations are desperate to keep our money by constantly showing us, if we are individual shareholders, or our institutional agents in the case of superannuation etc. that they are augmenting our funds.


GOBALISATION:  THE REALITY

Over the past decade or so we have seen a transformation of the Australian economy.  This has greatly enriched us.  In the decade to 1980, average wealth per capita actually declined by a couple of percent.  During the 1980's this rebounded with a 21 per cent increase.  But during the 1990s wealth per capita increased by 38 per cent.

The same sorts of trends are seen in income levels.

Major stimulants to these trends have been globalisation and our adoption of it.  During the 1980's we saw tariff reform that forced Australian industry to cease being coddled and to take its place within the world economy.  The outcome was a quantum leap in productivity.  During the 1990s we saw governments react to the need to maintain global efficiency by reinforcing the importance of competition law.  This meant subjecting government owned businesses to the same market disciplines the private sector faced.  It also, especially here in Victoria, meant privatisation with the unlocking of previously hidden value and a massive upsurge in productivity.

These developments were in part a response to the avalanche of increased global interaction that technology was bringing.  In many cases the response was to the manifestations of technology rather than technology itself.  Thus, the inefficiency of Victoria's gas and electricity industries had been tolerated for years but was becoming less so as industry sought every opportunity to achieve international competitiveness.  The financial catastrophes visited on Victoria, South Australia and Western Australia by government owned financial institutions failing might have been avoided in an era where finance houses could be insulated.  But once individuals could see better returns than those that the mistake riven state owned businesses could offer they voted with their own dollars, leading to crises.

This greater discipline on financial institutions to perform is another example of the benefits of greater globalisation.  When citizens can respond to uncertainties in the domestic investment climate by moving funds elsewhere, inefficient firms or financial intermediaries become unable to continue their poor management.  Globalisation of capital flows and the freedom of the saver to shift funds overseas puts pressure on governments to cease their previous policies of favouring certain kinds of investment and placing the risks onto captive local savers.  It is no coincidence that the failings of state owned banks and investment houses occurred with the greater globalisation we have seen in recent years.  Globalisation revealed these failures much more starkly.  It is also no coincidence that such occurrences have led to the abandonment of state owned banking worldwide.  This is yet another way that globalisation has brought benefits:  it has delivered us from some of the tyrannies that governments are apt to impose on their citizens.

This and other changes have made their mark on our prosperity.  The Productivity Commission has estimated that Australian labour productivity in the period since 1993 has risen from its long term trend of 2.1 per cent per annum to 3.1 per cent.  The most rapid increased in productivity were in the industries that adapted most closely to the needs of globalisation:  energy, communications and finance and insurance.  Even more strikingly, the productivity with which we make use of our capital had been steadily declining until the 1990's but is now increasing.

Perhaps for the first time in a century, over the past decade, we have now embarked on a period where our productivity levels are higher than those of the average OECD nation.  Moreover, we weathered the Asian crisis without a pause spite of our close export ties to the countries that suffered catastrophic reductions in their production levels.

The outcome of embracing globalisation has meant a far more efficient set of industries and object lessons to governments that they are poor operators of businesses, lessons learned even by Labor administrations which follow the role model set up by Tony Blair.

Globalisation is often used as a bogey word like economic rationalism before it.  In both cases the words are neutral but are used to impart notions of imposed helplessness on a hapless public.  Such constructions are the worst forms of Orwellian Newspeek.  They reverse the meaning of concepts that simply represent freedom for the consumer to choose for herself what to spend her money on.  Economic rationalism means getting government out of the way of decisions and allowing individuals to decide whether they buy one good rather than another, whether they buy services produced overseas rather than at home, whether they choose to spend their own money or save it, whether they invest at home or overseas.  Globalisation does the same thing by making it difficult to do otherwise.  The great advantages of this policy approach are:

  • it means freedom for the individual to do what he or she pleases with her own money
  • it offers no privileged path of a domestic producer into the pocket of a domestic consumer and forces the producer to constantly seek to ensure good value is given and to scrutinise developments overseas to ensure competitiveness is maintained
  • it means as a result of these processes that the productivity of the economy is constantly honed and as this is the only way to enjoy high living standards,
  • and it means a diminished role for government in bossing individuals around and dictating their patterns of consumption and tastes;  such a diminished role offers immense hope for the future emerging as we have from a century which the enlarged role of governments brought untold misery with totalitarian regimes.  And this is so even in the softer, gentler regimes of expanded state control and nationalisation that reduced living standards in many western countries like Australia.

In summary, globalisation brings greater prosperity and freedom from government control.  As can be seen from the relative peace we presently enjoy, and in contrast to the inter war and Cold War years it also tends to foster international harmony because its focus is on cooperation and win-win interchanges rather than use of force.

Sunday, May 07, 2000

Apology is Not a Clear Black and White Case

Australians with an ironic appreciation of the folly that pervades much of our contemporary politics must be savouring the fact that reconciliation has become such a source of strife.

After considerable argument last weekend, the Council for Aboriginal Reconciliation approved a document called the Australian Declaration Towards Reconciliation, which will be launched in three weeks time at Corroborree 2000 in the Sydney Opera House.  This corroborree was supposed to be a high point of the reconciliation process, but already it has caused a great deal of anger.

Prominent Aborigines such as Charles Perkins and Galarrwuy Yunipingu have said they will join former CAR chairman Pat Dodson in boycotting the event to protest against the Howard Government's approach to dealing with reconciliation and Aboriginal issues.  In response, Senator Aden Ridgeway has accused Dodson of a "blatant and bitter act", and of attempting to undermine the Council for Aboriginal Reconciliation for his own ends.

On the other hand, if media reports about its contents are correct, the Declaration will only increase the disquiet and irritation that many Australians feel about the thrust of demands for atonement for past wrongs against Aborigines.  Instead of adopting something that could gain the support of the Howard Government as well as ordinary Australians, CAR extended the very aspects of its previous drafts that caused the greatest concern.

The Declaration reportedly strengthens the demand for a national apology to Aborigines and bemoans the fact that there was never a treaty between Aborigines and white authorities.  It also calls for "self-determination" which, as interpreted by many activists -- including CAR member and ATSIC chairman Geoff Clark -- means a much greater push for Aboriginal separatism.

All this suggests what many of us have long suspected.  Some of the most vocal advocates of "Reconciliation" have no interest in a healing process which would create a unitary and harmonious nation and produce constructive solutions to Aboriginal disadvantage and resentment.  Rather, they seek new issues that will help them to "maintain the rage" amongst their constituency, and further ways of making claims on non-Aboriginal Australia.

Many Aboriginal individuals and communities still suffer serious social and economic hardship.  But one of their greatest misfortunes is that their misery is the plaything of middle class whites keen to engage in displays of conspicuous compassion, as well as being a resource for the cynical beneficiaries of the "Aboriginal industry", both black and white.

Until this ends Australia will never make genuine progress in solving Aboriginal problems.  Any attempts to identify the real causes of these problems or to propose solutions which do not meet the psychological requirements of the breast-beaters, or which threaten the interests of the "Aboriginal industry", occasion a storm of righteous abuse.

An example of the harmful consequences of this situation was presented earlier this week by Bernard Lane, The Australian's legal correspondent.  Lane wrote about Joan Kimm, a Monash University academic whose research forced her to conclude, against all her previous "politically correct" convictions, that "Aboriginal customary law had to carry much of the blame for the horrific violence suffered by Aboriginal women".

Unfortunately for Ms Kimm, the recognition of customary law has become a supposed pre-requisite for reconciliation -- although any effectiveness such law may once have had depended on punishments, including execution, that would cause even the most florid rednecks to blanch.  So while she is now publicly discussing her work, Ms Kimm was initially so distressed by her findings and the reaction they might cause that she abandoned her research for 18 months, fearful of giving ammunition to "Pauline Hansonites".

Both John Howard and Aboriginal Affairs Minister John Herron seem to recognise the need to break the logjam that bedevils their attempts to chart a more constructive approach.  Their strong focus on practical outcomes for Aborigines is admirable, but they continue to stumble on the important symbolic issues, allowing their political opponents to portray them as heartless at best, and racist at worst.

Even were the Prime Minister to offer an apology so grovelling as to embarrass the most sanctimonious member of the Australian Democrats, it would not be enough.  New grounds for berating him and his government would quickly be invented, designed to ensure that the Coalition will forever be denied the moral high ground.

So Mr Howard should forget about ever winning over the cultural elites.  But this does not mean that he should ignore the need to undermine their posturing by offering a worthy and morally justifiable alternative vision that could appeal to the majority of Australians, whether white or Aboriginal.

Perhaps he could begin by offering an appropriate apology to Aborigines.  Not the destructive kind of apology he is currently being told he must make, which would enshrine Aboriginal victimhood;  but one which would encourage Australians to reflect on what has really been wrong in our treatment of Aborigines.

The root cause of all the problems has been the belief that Aborigines are a different sort of human being from other Australians, with different kinds of rights and civil obligations.  For over 200 years Aborigines have been treated as inferior and requiring protection -- either explicitly, as was the case in the past, or implicitly, as is the case with today's nostrums which seek to cosset Aborigines from facing the realities of individual responsibility and freedom.

As Peter Howson pointed out in the Courier-Mail a couple of weeks ago, all sides of politics have been guilty of this kind of thinking, of expecting Aborigines to conform to a different set of rules to those which apply to the rest of us.  Mr Howard knows this is wrong, but because he has been generally ineffective in conveying this understanding to the Australian people, his government has not had the courage and the will to urge the radical rethink that is necessary.  And for this, he should apologise.


ADVERTISEMENT

Thursday, May 04, 2000

China, Taiwan:  One Future?  Which Future?

Introduction for Dialogue
"China, Taiwan:  One Future?  Which Future?"
3 May 2000


Tonight, rather than a single speaker, we have two speakers.  One, Rowan Callick, is an award-winning journalist:  one of those, who, as the phrase goes, write the first draft of history.  The other, Dr Thomas Bartlett, is an academic specialising in Chinese history:  something which has gone through more drafts than just about any other history.

There is a great deal of fashionable boosting of China about:  all that stuff about if current trends continue then China will be the largest economy in the world by 2000-and-whatever.

But it was a mere 10 years ago people were talking about the Japanese challenge to American economic hegemony:  predictions which now look incredibly sad.

Trends are the result of the interaction of institutions, people and circumstances.  If we look more carefully at institutional structures, much of that China-boosting looks very hollow.

After, what is the greatest riddle of human history?  Is it why Europe and European-descended societies came to dominate the globe?  Or why China did not?  China apparently had everything going for it -- numbers, culture, technology, institutional complexity.  A Ming Dynasty Admiral, Zheng He, reached Mogadishu (in what is now Somalia) and Mombasa (in what is now Kenya) with a fleet of about 300 ships and 28,000 men 77 years before Vasco da Gama, coming the other way, went to India with 4 small ships and 171 men.  The enormous force of a mighty empire achieved far less of lasting significance than the tiny expedition of a small kingdom on the periphery of Europe.  The failure of China is as least as much a subject for thoughtful consideration as the success of Europe.

China is presently attempting a form of the capitalist road to economic development while being ruled by a regime whose mandate to rule rests on transcending and abolishing capitalism.

So we have a Great Power whose path to modernisation fundamentally undermines the legitimacy of the ruling regime.  We have been here before:  Imperial Germany before the First World War, Imperial Japan before the Pacific War.  They are not reassuring antecedents.  And China is geographically closer to us than Japan:  less than an hour's flight by missile.

Meanwhile, on 20 May, the first peaceful transfer of power in Chinese history will take place when Chen Shui-bian will be sworn in as President of what is still officially the Republic of China in Taipei on the island of Taiwan.

Our two speakers tonight are very well qualified to speak of these events of hope and portents of danger.

Rowan Callick has recently returned from being the Hong Kong-based Greater China Correspondent of The Australian Financial Review for almost four years.  He is the author of Comrades & Capitalists:  Hong Kong Since the Handover.  He has won the Graham Perkin Award of Australian Journalist of the Year, for 1995 and the Walkley Award for Coverage of Asia, for 1997.

Dr Thomas Bartlett was born in London to American parents, and was educated at Harvard, National Taiwan and Princeton Universities.  He was Director of the Chinese Language Teaching Programme at Harvard from 1989 to 1994 before moving to John Hopkins and then on to La Trobe in 1996, where his wife also teaches.  His doctoral dissertation was on late Imperial Political Thought.

Accountability in the new Millennium:  Accountability to Whom, For What and Why?

Keynote Address to the the CPA's Congress 2000,
Sheraton Hotel, Perth, 3 May 2000


INTRODUCTION

Over the last decade and half there has been a veritable revolution in the level and breadth of accountability in corporate Australia.

Corporations -- in both the private and public sector -- have become much more responsive to achieving value for shareholder's and more focused on core activities.

Naturally, shareholders have been amongst the major beneficiaries of this process -- a groups which now represents well over 50 per cent of the Australian population.

Society as a whole has also benefited greatly.  The enhanced focus on maximising returns for the shareholder lies behind the large improvement in productivity growth achieved over the last decade by the corporate sector and the economy as a whole.  It also lies behind corporate Australia's increased level of international competitiveness and profitability.  And it has produced a marked improvement in the level and quality of investment -- which augers well for the future.

Importantly, the increased focus on shareholder value has contributed to a fairer, more open society.  It has reduced the potential for both management and influential interest groups to capture corporations for their own advantage and at the expense of shareholders.

It has -- in conjunction with reductions in tariffs and through the introduction of competition policy -- broken down the positions of privilege and special advantage.

It has allowed -- indeed encouraged -- a large number of additional people to become part of the shareholder class.

The focussing of corporate activity on maximising shareholder value has not been achieved at the cost of the social or environmental considerations or at the expense of regional development.

The general government sector -- the sector with prime responsible for collective decisions -- has undergone a parallel process of reform aimed at obtaining greater value for money, greater focus on outcomes and reducing the scope for program capture.

Importantly, it has not shirked its social or environmental responsibilities.  The amount of funds allocated to these responsibilities has increased substantially over the last two decade in all areas of government.  Moreover the pursuit of value for money has allowed these dollars to go further than they would have in the past.  In addition, the increased targeting and monitoring of budgetary expenditure has ensured that the dollars went for the intended purposes.

The enhanced focus on the bottomline by government business enterprises (GBE's) has greatly reduced taxpayer subsidies and freed-up funds for social purposes.

Governments have also put in place a panoply of regulations designed to enforce sound environmental, social and ethical practices by corporations.  In other words, the rights and responsibilities of corporations and their shareholders with regard to the environment and society have been more thoroughly codified in the laws of the land.  As a result, they have been incorporated in the accountability processes.

Corporate Australia has also contributed to the environmental and social well being of the country in the most effective and appropriate way, which is by creating wealth, jobs and opportunities.

It has also, by and large, embraced the community's desire for greater conservation and protection of environmental resources -- for proof one need only peruse the environmental statements of our major mining firms and visit their sites.

Of course there is long way to go in many areas, particularly in the public sector.  Nonetheless, much has been achieved.  Shareholder and society at large are the better for it.


THE CHALLENGE

Not everyone is pleased with this process.  Many managers and workers have lost power and have been adversely effected by the pursuit of greater shareholder value.

Governments have seen their ability to use GBEs as cash cows greatly diminished and many public servants have lost power over the public purse.

Most of these -- private sector managers, workers, politicians, public servants -- though lamenting the change, accepted it as either irreversible, inevitable or in the public interest.

There is, however, a challenge afoot led by some academics, management consultants -- including the accounting fraternity -- and non-government organisations.

The challenge comes under various headings including:

  • stakeholder capitalism;
  • business ethics;  and,
  • triple bottom line.

These approaches differ to some degree.

The aim of stakeholder capitalism is to provide so-called stakeholders -- most typically unions, local political leaders, environmental activists, charities and social activitists -- with rights over the resources and operation of companies on a par with those of the shareholders.

The aim of the business ethics movement is to impose ethical standards -- which have more to do with the promotion of wider social ideals rather than business practice -- on corporations.

The triple bottom line approach is to have corporations report on environmental and social outcomes in concert and on a par with financial outcomes.

The movements, however, have a common set of general aims.

First, they do not seek to overtly overthrow capitalism, but rather to control and direct it for the so-called greater good.

Second, they aim to use the corporate accountability mechanisms to impose social objectives or collective ideals on corporations.

Third, they seek to give rights to thirds parties on a par with those of shareholders and as such, they seek to reduce the priority given to shareholder value.

These movements are seductive.  They are craftily packaged and offer an almost endless supply of work for consultants, accountants, NGOs, and management.

They are invariably packaged as a new, middle-of-the-road approache to solving the age-old problem of getting a better mix of social and individual goals, that is, a new approach to the "new economy".

The truth is that they are a return to the past.

What is proposed is a model of corporate governace which was the norm in Australia in the past:  that is, corporations which put the interest of stakeholders such as government, unions, suppliers, and management on a par with shareholders;  corporations in which stakeholders -- particular workers and government -- have an direct input into management decisions;  and corporations which give equal weight to non-financial social considerations.

Although the movements are centred in the UK and the US, their ideas are based on a corporate ethos common to Europe and Asia.

Their fundamental aim is to transform the Anglo-American model of capitalism -- with its focus on maximising shareholder value and rights -- to a more social democratic, stakeholder model common in Germany and Japan.

The irony is that these movements are gaining strength at the time when European and Asian companies are rapidly adopting the Anglo-American model.

These new movements do differ in some areas from the approach in the past.

First, the old socialist ideal that government must occupy the commanding heights of industry has been jettisoned.  Overt socialism is dead.  Instead, the aim of these movements is not to nationalise the corporation but simply to control it.

Their aim is not to throw-out the accountability mechanisms but to use them to obtain and enforce control.

Although the movements' aim is to promote the interests of many of the old players -- concerns such as unions and factory closures -- they have introduced a new set of players and issues.

The chief new stakeholders and prime proponents of the movements are the NGOs -- the shelf proclaimed representatives of civil society.

Indeed, the ultruistic, general-interest mien of the NGOs is one of the most seductive aspect of these movements.  The view put forward is that in the past, companies may have been captured by groups seeking selfish, personal gain, but the new movements are different, as they focus on doing good for the greater good.

This is, however, at best simplistic.  First, the movements include many of the same old players and issues.

Second, many of the NGOs and other advocates are far from benign or acting for the general good.  Many advocates are what is aptly known as "watermelons" -- green on the outside but red on the inside.  That is, they are old left-wing opponents of the capitalist system dressed up in new green clothes.  Moreover, many of these groups are both unrepresentative of, and unaccountable to, the broader community they claim to represent.

Third, although many proponents of these movements do not seek remuneration, they do seek influence and control -- and who needs money when you share control over a multi-billion dollar corporation?

Another appealing aspect of these movements is their focus on wider social and environmental issues.  In the past, the focus of interest groups was on day-to-day issues such as wages, jobs security and local development.  These new movements retain an interest in these issues but focus more on broader objectives such as protecting tropical rainforests, overcoming poverty in the third world, and protecting human rights.

But, as they say, "the road to heaven is paved with good intentions".  The ideal may be noble but what counts is achieving it.  If attempts to achieve noble end only undermines a valuable institution -- such as a corporation -- or otherwise fails to achieve its aims, then the exercise is hardly a noble one.

One thing is certain, these movements will create a great deal of work for many people.  The question however, is, will this work be productive or destructive.

I fear the latter.

These movement are threats in a number of ways.

First, they seek to undermine the rights of individuals shareholders.  They seeks to impose social or collective rights on corporations and to elevate these objectives to the same status as those of shareholders.

The pursuit of such objectives must come at a cost to shareholders.  Collective goods are not free;  they cost money and resources to produce.  By definition, the shareholders are not the main or even primary beneficiary of these goods.  Yet the aim is to have shareholders pay the money, produce the goods, and all free of charge.

Second, the movements will severely undermine the efficiency of the corporate sector and the economy as a whole.  These movements seeks to give third parties rights over the operation of corporations and to elevate these rights on a par with those of shareholders.  Under the existing system, shareholders rights are paramount and it is the primacy of shareholders rights and the pursuit of these rights by management that drives the capitalist system.

They will dull or distort the search for profit, so growth will slow, jobs disappear, unequal distribution of income will increase and the capacity and interest in protecting the environment will wane.

Under the stakeholder system, choices will need to be made between the rights of shareholders and the rights of so-called stakeholders.  This choice will necessarily dull the incentive to maximise profit as stakeholders do not share in the profit and therefore will not be interested in achieving it.

Risk taking will be lower under a stakeholder system, simply because some stakeholders get little benefit from the higher profit it may yield.

Under the stakeholder system, resources will not be shifted to the highest valued use, because some stakeholder will not allow it.  For example, the existing workforce will use their "stakeholder rights" to stop firm closures or downsizing even if these changes are necessary for profit.  Local communities will also use their "stakeholder" rights to resist relocation of a firm even if there are important gains to the larger community.  The "local society for the preservation of the spotted owl" will claim a stakeholder right to block a dam or a pipeline.

Of course, under the existing system there are impediments to the free flow of resource -- workers have rights to redundancy.  The social impact of projects must be considered and the environmental impact of a project must be ascertained and comply with the laws of the land.  However, in the end, it is the rights and responsibilities of shareholders that prevail.

Third, the stakeholder systems will impose a heavy burden on management and undermine its ability to function in an appropriate and accountable manner.

Under the existing system there are always conflicting desires -- between, for example management, workers and owners -- but in the end, the owners' rights usually prevail.

Under the stakeholder system their is no hierarchy of rights and an almost endless list of "rights holders" with conflicting desires.  Therefore, a stakeholder system requires a mechanism of choosing amongst the competing rights holders.

For example, in a plant relocation decision, a choice must be made between the rights of present employees who will have their lives disrupted by the move, and potential stakeholders and residents in the new locations whose employment prospects and life chances will be badly damaged if the move does not take place.

The system of adjudication of rights would necessarily be political in nature -- since the stakeholders rights are collective rights -- each having an equal right to be heard and having their views considered.  As a result, the decision-making process will necessarily be costly, unpredictable, and focused on equity rather than efficiency, transparency or profitability.

Fourth, a stakeholder system will spur destructive rent seeking behaviour.

Under the stakeholder system, rights to control over a corporation, and the benefits that flow from these rights, are on offer without payment but simply by making a stakeholder claim.

Accordingly, people will expend a great deal of resources lobbying and otherwise trying to acquire these free but highly valuable goods.  This not only wastes resources but bogs down management.

The problem of rent seeking is compounded by the unrepresentative and unaccountable nature of many of the proponents.  In the past, stakeholder representatives were generally appointed by, and accountable to, stakeholders.  They were union leaders, local politicians, or managers of local suppliers.  The new movements are driven by NGOs where the link between the executives and the members or ideas they claim to represent is more tenuous and open to fraud.

Indeed, the claims by many NGOs to represent the environment, the world's poor, women and the third world are without substance.  Not only is such representation impossible -- given the diversity of views and interest within these groups -- but these NGOs make no effort to put in place the necessary process to be representative.  As a result, many of their so-called stakeholder claims are bogus.

Fifth, these movement attempt to force corporations to do things for which they are unsuitable.  For example, they demand that managers of businesses determine wages so as to bring about a more equal distribution of income, which in reality is impossible to achieve.

It is also inappropriate to hold corporations responsible for providing charity, addressing third world poverty or addressing human rights abuse in China and other global ideals.  These are problems that go far beyond the power of the corporate sector and are best addressed through other means.  They can even back-fire.  For example, inducing firms not to operate in China because of the latter's poor human rights record could well augment rather than help solve the problems.


WHAT TO DO

It would be a serious mistake to ignore some of the requests and ideas that lie behind these movements.  During the last 50 years, many large companies have gone bankrupt or have been taken over because they failed to respond to social, political, economic or technological change.  There has been a sharp increase in the value placed on environment by society.  Corporations now play a much larger role in society than they did in the past and the world is increasingly global.

However, it would be wrong -- both for companies and society -- to accept their main argument and solutions.  They are flawed and would send us back to the past.  They would create privilege, undermine people's property rights, undermine wealth and economic growth and eventually undermine our capacity and willingness to redistribute income and protect the environment.

Instead, first, we should continue with the process of improving corporate and public sector accountability, focusing on ensuring greater shareholder value.

Second, corporations should establish quantifiable standards, and report on these to stakeholders, on the range of environmental and social impacts under their direct control, including worker safety, pollution, resource conservation, and community impact.  Many companies are, of course, already doing this.

Third, corporate Australia needs to take a more active lead in intellectual debate about the legitimacy of business.

Fourth, the accountability spot light should be firmly placed on the NGO sector.

These organisations play an increasingly pivotal role in society, including the representation of stakeholders.  Yet their systems of governance, accounting standards, level of transparency and reporting standards are often rudimentary.  Moreover, many claim representative status without even trying to put in place the necessary processes.  Even though ethical standards of many of these organisation are above reproach, others have ethical standards which, if adopted in the business of public sector, would result in prison.

In short, it is also time for civil society to become accountable.

Tuesday, May 02, 2000

Public Good Conservation -- Impact Of Environmental Measures Imposed on Landholders

Submission to the House of Representatives Standing Committee
on Environment and Heritage Inquiry, May 2000.


INTRODUCTION

The Standing Committee raised four issues:

  • What is public good conservation?
  • Impacts of conservation measures and their costs
  • Financial assistance for conservation by landholders
  • Sharing costs of conservation by all Australians

Public goods are best thought of as goods from which people cannot readily be excluded.  As a result, unlike food, warmth and shelter, their provision cannot easily be left to individuals pursuing their own separate interests.  Clean air is often cited as the classic example.  The notion of public goods conservation with respect to land can be divided into two categories:  maintaining the productivity of the land by measures that will automatically affect all landholdings in a particular area;  and preserving native flora and fauna which may compete with normal concepts of land productivity.

The first of these is a long-established issue.  The general success over many centuries in maintaining the productivity of the land is due to ownership of land having been vested in individuals, thus creating powerful incentives to maintain and enhance its productivity.  The legal obligations and rights of different property owners allow conflicts to be resolved where their activities impinge on each other.  Private interests have broadly conformed to public goods as a result of these mechanisms.  They may diverge where adverse impacts from features that are highly diverse and difficult to measure.  River pollution from use of fertilizers is an example of this.

The second concern -- preserving native species -- is a more modern one.  In the past, elimination of many such species may have been considered a public good, just as was drainage of wetlands (then known as swamps).

Public goods can be addressed using two broad routes:

  • Maintenance of the rule of law based on individually-owned and tradable property rights so that just trade-offs are made where there is conflicting interests.  This can be built upon in several ways but should not be undermined.
  • The alternative approach is regulatory determination of the uses of property;  a variation of this involves the use for regulatory purposes of the incentives -- fees and rewards -- that are automatically present with property rights.

THE RULE OF LAW BASED ON PROPERTY RIGHTS

THE NEED FOR EXCLUSIVE PROPERTY RIGHTS

Individuals will seek to make intensive use of free inputs whilst economising on inputs for which they have to pay.  As a result, where the free input has a value, society will not be making the best use of its factor endowments such as land.  Property which is unowned will lead each individual to maximise his own benefit with little regard to the ongoing value of the resource.  Failure of the individual to take the value for himself will simply mean others will do so.  Baden and Stroup (1) liken the process to five young boys sucking soda from a glass -- the law of capture prevails and no conservation control or temporal allocation of the depletable resource is possible.  If the asset's ownership is vested the owner will attempt to maximise its present value, taking into account future alternative uses.  By ensuring that others are excluded, a landowner can determine whether the property merits conservation or modification;  whether it warrants spending resources to improve its fertility, accessibility, aesthetic qualities etc..

For this reason, Hayek maintained "The aim of the rules of law is merely to prevent, as much as possible, by drawing boundaries, the actions of different individuals from interfering with each other." Drawing of boundaries and further defining them as the need arises has been a major force in allowing efficient trade to take place on the basis of separate pursuit of the individual's own interest.  Boundary drawing and minimizing communal, and especially unowned, property allows the assignment of appropriate values to different inputs.

This boundary drawing has allowed normal legal recourse to adjudicate rights that are in collision.  Over hundreds of years, litigation has established the priority of rights and obligations.  It has also allowed the allocation of these rights to become modified to account for changes in community standards.  Thus, during the nineteenth century, courts gave a greater priority of rights to productive uses of goods than to non-productive, a diversion from a neutral law that was perhaps justified by the public priority placed on increasing income levels.  Some such similar priority is seen today in many developing countries where forest clearing is claimed to be placing an excessive value on immediate over longer term income and national welfare.


BENEFICIAL OUTCOMES FROM PROPERTY RIGHTS PROTECTION

Legal definitions of rights and responsibilities based on firmly understood property rights have been major forces for economic progress while ensuring the sustainability of production.  Faith in this process has often been shaky.  Thus, Theodore Roosevelt in 1911 said,

"... the time has come to enquire seriously what will happen when our forests are gone, when the coal, the iron, the oil and gas are exhausted, when the soils have been further impoverished and washed into streams, polluting the rivers, denuding the fields and obstructing navigation."

Yet not one of Roosevelt's anxieties have proved well founded.  Economies have become increasingly, not decreasingly productive.  World development has clearly proven sustainable.  Over the past 100 years income of OECD countries as measured by Gross Domestic Product has increased more than 20-fold and income per head has quintupled.

If we look at agricultural output, we find even more encouraging signs.  In the past forty years, Australia's farm production has increased by 130 per cent.  Performance in other countries has been comparable.  Table 1 offers some quantification of this in Australia.

Table 1:  Average % Increase in Volume of Farm Output

1951-19621962-19721972-19821977/8-1998/9
4.03.51.02.6

Source:  ABARE

Even though many claim we are approaching the limits to increased productivity, and a downturn is imminent, in recent years, output has continued to increase faster than inputs (2).

These facts suggest scepticism is warranted with regard to a recent report published by the ACF and NFF (3).  The report calls for annually an additional $3.7 billion of government spending and a total $6.5 billion.

The report claims that, currently, degradation costs at least $2 billion each year, and is increasing at an accelerating rate.  It estimates the investment expenditure it advocates has the potential to generate a 6.5% annual return, for the next 100 years.  The bulk of the benefits are in forestry and the report envisages a 20 fold growth in that industry.


SECURE PROPERTY RIGHTS:  THE KEY TO PROSPERITY

The reasons behind the generally satisfactory out-turn are well known.  Property rights offer individuals an unparalleled incentive to gauge immediate and longer term costs and benefits against their own preferences.  Having these costs and benefits self-contained with the property owner has proven far superior to any other form of ownership.  Its supremacy over its main rival, government determination of use, has been unambiguously demonstrated with the collapse of socialism over the past decade or so.

Indeed, the overwhelming cause of England leading the world’s economic take-off of recent centuries was painstakingly documented by Tom Bethell (4).  Bethell showed this was due to the security over property rights that the English and, to a lesser extent, other Europeans enjoyed.  Secure property rights allow basic human goals to be pursued by allowing those who are successful, frugal or hard-working to enjoy the benefits without having to share them, giving them much greater incentive to create wealth and preserve the value of assets.

Codifying the English implied property rights, the US Constitution under the Bill of Rights (Amendment 5, 1791) established the inviolability of property rights (called takings) from government seizure.  This was adopted in the Australian Constitution (s 51 xxxi), although in a form that required an activist High Court shortly after the turn of the last century to fully define.  In Australia, the provisions do not extend to State constitutions (and the Lucas case in the US demonstrates, in some people’s eyes, that property rights are imperfectly protected in that country (5)).

De facto takings occur where governments adopt zoning laws to prevent certain crops being grown, thereby denying the landowner of the best possible use of the land.  The High Court’s "discovery" of native title in Mabo 2 also led to a considerable attenuation of property rights as they were previously understood.  Nonetheless, Australian property rights have largely retained their value and certainty notwithstanding the various assaults on them by governments and a politically active judiciary.

Any departure from a property-rights approach to ensure a more sustainable productivity needs to be carefully founded on sound principles.  The experiences of countries that have emasculated individual property rights (e.g. the former Soviet Union) or whose governments have not had the capacity to ensure the upholding of the owners’ rights (e.g. much of Africa) does not offer hope of finding promising approaches that do not include a pre-eminent role for property rights.

The foregoing suggests that financial compensation is essential for any property rights that are taken.  This accords with several sound principles, including:

  • placing a direct impost on budgets, thus avoiding he misapprehension that a taking is costless and injecting a discipline into government to select priorities regarding goods that warrant such a taking;  this also allows an accurate measure to be made of the costs of conservation measures;
  • providing compensation conforms with equity;
  • in the absence of conservation, perverse outcomes are likely;  thus it is said in the US that the Endangered Species Act -- which often paralyses income producing activity on private land once such a species is discovered -- leads to the three SSS’s;  Shoot, Shovel and Shut-up.

USE OF PRIVATE PROPERTY TRANSACTIONS TO ACHIEVE A PARTICULAR OUTCOME

Superimposed on this property-rights platform on which the rule of law can arbitrate conflicting interests, is the possibility that one party can resolve a conflict by buying out the property of another.  Where the interests of parties clash, one option is for one party (or set of parties) to buy the opposing interests.  This occurs not infrequently in urban real estate where a property owner may buy out an adjacent property that may have been developed in a way that would potentially (but legally) reduce his enjoyment of his own property.  The purchaser may either retain the adjacent property or re-sell it with a caveat on its use.  Other private efforts, sometimes by single individuals, in the US have been important in preserving eagles, and even the native bison.

The Nature Conservancy in the USA is a major participant in strategies whereby clubs of interested parties operating through the law and property rights system to promote beneficial outcomes..  The Nature Conservancy obtains subscriptions from donors and buys land holdings to preserve certain features or species that would otherwise be lost.  Sometimes the organisation buys a "hold-out" stake in an area which may be scheduled for changed use in order to influence the nature of the change to preserve or enhanced the values favoured by it, as the agent of its donors.

In Australia, environmental organisations have generally eschewed such approaches, preferring instead to use the funds at their disposal for advocacy purposes.  This is a pity.  Advocacy generally means seeking others -- the private owner or the taxpayer -- to fund their goals.


REGULATORY DETERMINATIONS OF THE USE OF PROPERTY

The reflex action to the issues of public goods is to impose a regulatory solution.  A public good often means a good that all will share in automatically–it is not practicable to exclude all from use of the good.  The regulatory solution however has three major disadvantages:

  • there is no yardstick on which to judge the real demand for particular public goods, and the strength of feeling in favour of it.  Market research techniques, often called contingent valuation, were thought to offer promise in this regard but tended to throw up results that were highly improbable.  Thus, a study conducted on the value of disallowing mining in Kakadu revealed an apparent value per hectare for "clapped out buffalo country" far in excess of that of the Sydney CBD.
  • it disregards the dispersion of that demand;  the preservation of tracts of land as "old growth" forests is unlikely to be valued similarly by different people and if the withdrawal of land from other uses is entailed in this, the benefits are unevenly spread.  Commonly, environmnental benefits are valued more by the more affluent members of the community and regulatory moves (which are seldom costless) therefore have implications for many people’s notions of equity.
  • regulatory solutions often fail to provide the incentives to meet the objective to which they are targetted.  This is because the (government) custodians lack the motives of individual gain that underpins the benefits brought by property rights and because governments tend to be poor managers and allocators of funds due to the distorted connection between incentives, consequences and decision-making.

A timely reminder of the disadvantages of regulatory solutions to conservation is offered by the recent fires in the forests enclosing the Los Alamos nuclear research facility has illustrated some of the deficiencies in having government agencies seek to preserve areas in a "natural" state.  The fire, although due to a controlled burn that went wrong, was a consequence of attempting to preserve forests in a way that is no longer possible.  As Robert Nelson, Senior Fellow in Environmental Studies at the Competitive Enterprise Institute and author of the forthcoming book, A Burning Issue:  A Case for Abolishing the U.S. Forest Service has said,

Unless it is removed mechanically, most of the wood will have to burn eventually.  Consequently, an abundance of dead and dying trees due to the long time absence of fire results in fire intensities that cause enormous damage to soils, watersheds, fisheries, and other ecosystem components.

Some parallel deficiencies of government-controlled Australian national parks are well documented.  These include lack of care and infestation by feral cats, pigs and vegetation like blackberries.  Where the forest service is able to combat fire, this often stores up greater problems for the future.

Totally private forests with recreation as the main income earning feature are not a ready option in Australia, since the abundance of "free" government national parks crowds out most private provision.  Nonetheless, a number of "exclosure"-based parks, particularly those operated by Dr Walmsley, appear to have been successful.


SPECIES PROTECTION

The previously mentioned ACF/NFF report National Investment in Rural Landscapes calls for expenditure of $8.3 billion ($7.1 billion in public money) for non-commercial or biodiversity plantings and $722 million (all of it public money) for rangeland retirement for biodiversity.  While the report has the merit of apparently fully compensating land owners for foregoing their income levels in the pursuit of these public goods, it can be criticised in two respects:  first the level of urgency may be exaggerated;  and secondly, it makes no efforts to explore private means of pursing the target.


THE EXTENT OF THE PROBLEM

In terms of extinctions, the report notes that since European settlement some 20 mammals have become extinct and suggests that 97 plant species are also known to be extinct.  While any species loss is a matter of regret, two factors need to be considered in addressing these sorts of numbers.

First, the extent of the loss comprises about 7 per cent of the pre-European mammals and a tiny fraction of the 25,000 plant and 40,000 plus other vegetation species identified in Australia.  The loss was not caused by deliberate extirpation but as a consequence of new species.  The previous isolation of Australia made it inevitable that native species would be vulnerable to competition of new strains.  Other isolated areas like Hawaii and the south west of the US suffered comparable species loss.

Secondly, species loss largely occurred in the period prior to 1920.  In that period, the premium on species preservation was much weaker than it is today.  If it has not been arrested, species loss has certainly been considerably reduced in recent decades.  This casts doubt on the estimates of future loss ("3329 plant categories threatened" and an estimated "50% of Australia’s woodland birds will become extinct") in the ACF/NFF report.  Such figures also seem to be considerably higher than those in the OECD Environmental Data Compendium, 1999, which records 1,085 plant species as threatened out of 25,000 (or 4 per cent) and 50 threatened bird species out of 777 (or 6 per cent).


MAKING USE OF MARKET MECHANISMS TO PRESERVE SPECIES

Owned species with market value are not in danger of extinction.  Vesting of ownership of species presents a potentially useful way of recruiting the market system to promote environmental goals.  At present many Australian fauna are devalued because they have no market value, hence they are often considered vermin.

Outcomes overseas present pointers to a more hopeful win-win approach.  With Kenyan elephants, protection in national parks under government ownership has resulted in the excessive hunting of creatures that have valued properties but are also a nuisance;  by contrast, southern Africa’s herds are vested with villages who ensure their protection to take advantage of tourism and the outcome has been far superior in terms of preservation.  Those with the property right or its franchise equivalent will assume an automatic role of policing against poachers (who would be seizing their property).

Such experiences present useful indicators for Australian policy.  Overseas demand for Australian birds and wildlife is high and "harvesting" the wildlife could promote its sustainability while:

  • ensuring against excessive taking
  • ensuring humane collection and transport

Such solutions are inhibited by current ideological attitudes against commercialising wild life and these need to be combated.  There is scope for gain (including gain in rural employment levels) by deregulating and franchising.  This scope should be explored, especially since such measures could contribute to species preservation and protection without impositions on the taxpayer.


LIMITS OF INDIVIDUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AND USE OF MARKET MECHANISMS

In many cases the environmental values cannot be maintained by private action.  In the case of much pollution, for example, non-point sources it is impracticable to measure the individual causes and voluntary actions may be impracticable.

However, there is an over-abundance of voices calling for regulatory action to combat imperfections.  Salt encroachment in dry land areas (especially in Western Australia) and in the Murray Darling system is presently the object of considerable attention.  Real though these issues are, a sober judgement on the need to take action is suggested by their ostensibly modest impact on overall levels of agricultural productivity (see Table 1).

If regulatory measures are to be taken, these are best done through use of market-based instruments.  Tradeable rights are one such instrument capable of being employed in the case of wildlife preservation.  Taxes are another means of using market-based incentives.  In principle, there is little difference between the two methods.  Both encourage behaviour under which costs are minimised with the stimulus of a financial incentive.

Taxes, for example on river pollutants, have been very effective in cleaning inland waterways in the US.  Tradeable rights to pollute have the same effect (placing a quantitative limit on pollutants and allowing the price to determine itself, rather than setting a price for polluting and allowing the quantity to set itself).

The dominant issue for Australia is the health of the Murray-Darling system.  Governments have struggled to overcome salinity and other degradation in this system for decades.  Some prospect for improvement is evident with appropriate pricing levels being introduced for water use.  A superior approach, in view of the importance of property rights (and current water users and their bankers clearly consider they have firm rights to a level of water use) is to vest ownership of the water at an aggregate level considered to be appropriate for the recovery of the waterway.  Trading in these rights should be permitted and this would ensure the water is used for its most valued purposes.  It would allow farm and other output to be maximised while reducing the public "bad" level of salinity.

This use of quasi-property right solutions is likely to yield far superior outcomes than micro-regulating farm and water use.


CONCLUDING COMMENTS

The Australian Constitution, like the American, incorporates the view that individual freedom should prevail alongside a limited role for government.  Section 51(xxxi) requires that if the government acquires property from any State or person, it does so on just terms.  Just terms have been defined by the High Court as "full and adequate compensation" where the acquisition is a compulsory taking.

However, section 51 (xxxi) only applies to the Commonwealth.  It does not bind the States nor do the States have "just compensation" clauses in their own constitutions.


DECLINING SUPPORT FOR PROPERTY RIGHTS

There has been a substantial decline in support for upholding the security of private property rights by the courts and by governments of all levels over the last 50 years.

This decline has not led to ignoring these property rights altogether.  Rather, it has led to the narrowing of the definition of property rights, a widening of the definition of "public use" and the limiting of the grounds for compensation.

When governments expropriate property outright, taking title from the owner, courts relying on Section 51(xxxi) generally require governments, at least the Commonwealth government, to compensate owners for their losses.  The modern problem does not lie there.  The problem lies with governments taking part of the use of the property while leaving title with the owner.  Courts have been reluctant to award compensation in such cases because they have failed to grasp the principle of the matter -- due, in part, to an unwarranted deference to the regulatory state.

The central principle is that property is not a singular concept.  Property is a bundle of rights and different owners can co-exist by owning different services on the same piece of land––the normal case in Australia for mining rights and is also found with water rights.  But if any of these rights is taken away the owner is deprived of something.

Contrary to this reality, takings law has clung to the idea that only if the entire bundle is taken does the government have to pay compensation.  This all-or-nothing view enables government to extinguish nearly all uses through regulation -- and hence to regulate nearly all value out of the property -- yet escape the compensation requirement because the all-but-empty title remains with owner.

This is clearly wrong.  Compensation should be required when government takes any right -- whether partial or full title.


WHEN IS COMPENSATION REQUIRED?

It is preferable to answer the question when is compensation not required?  Rather than the question when is compensation required?

Compensation is not required

  • First, when government acts to secure rights -- when, for example, it stops someone from polluting his neighbour's land -- it is acting under its police powers and no compensation is due to the owner, whatever his financial loss, because the use -- pollution -- was wrong in the first place.  Since there is no right to pollute, we do not have to pay polluters not to pollute.  The relevant question is not whether value has been taken by regulation but whether a right has been taken.
  • Second, if governments act to provide the public with some good and that act does not take a right, then even if it results in a financial loss, no compensation is due.  For example, if a government builds a public housing estate and neighbouring property values decline, no compensation is due because the action took nothing that they owned.  The neighbours own their property and its uses.  They do not own the value in their property.

Compensation is required when governments act not to secure rights but to provide the public with some good -- for example, a wildlife habitat or the preservation of historic buildings -- and in doing so take away some otherwise legitimate use.

The principle is quite simple:  the public has to pay for the goods it wants and takes, just like any private person would have to.


PROMOTING INCREASED PRIVATE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS

Although public goods benefit us all, a great many such goods are freely provided by individuals—many may gain enjoyment from a neighbour’s flower garden but nobody would chip in to maintain it.  In fact people are very often unable to obtain all the benefits from a purchase or action but the market system still operates without an additional massive transfer of notional benefits.

Hence it makes sense to leave room for those placing a higher priority on public goods conservation to do so of their own volition.  It is also more admirable for those with strong environmental preferences to use their own monies to fund the provision of public goods rather than campaign to have government force the taxpayer to fund them.

In addition, the need to provide funding for public goods could be reduced by allowing ownership and trade in wildlife species.  Particularly in the case of the major fauna—exotic birds, frilly necked lizards, koalas etc, there is a ready demand both for observing the species in situ and for specimens.



ENDNOTES

1.  Baden R and Stroup J "Property Rights and Natural Resource Management" Literature of Liberty Vol II No 4, September-December 1979

2.  There is frequent concern about sustainability of present productivity trends.  Thus, Bartle in the NFF publication, Reform Autumn 2000 notes that the WA Salinity Plan is estimated to expand to cover 32% of the land area from the present 9% in the coming decades.  The numbers however refer to affected land which in the main remains productive.  Like other parts of Australia, WA land productivity has not shown signs of falling.

3.  National Investment in Rural Landscapes, NFF and ACF, May 2000

4.  Bethell, Tom, The Noblest Triumph, St Martin’s Press, New York, 1998.

5.  Henry N. Butler Regulatory Takings after Lucas, Regulation, (1993 #3)