Saturday, October 31, 2009

Jobs, living standards run second to other goals

National governments protect their citizens' interests in many ways.  They negotiate trade deals to get better overseas market access, raise loans at the best interest rate and aggressively promote their countries' merits as tourist destinations.

This same pursuit of citizens' interests is equally evident within federal systems like Australia's.

Bitter disputes take place each year at premiers' conferences about each state's contribution to and share of the national cake.

However, uniquely among the world's nations, the Australian Government's approach to international climate change negotiations has jettisoned this conventional approach.

India and China are engaged in endless negotiations and posturing over their carbon dioxide emissions.  They say they may contemplate measures that reduce those emissions if they get copious amounts of compensation from the developed countries.

The US is stalling while making pious noises.

The European Union has placed a cap on its carbon emissions policy but carefully shields its companies from any detrimental effects.

By contrast, the Rudd Government wants Australia to implement job-sapping and business-bashing carbon emission reduction policies no matter what other countries do.  Moreover, the Government's proposed emission reduction policies entail us buying emission rights from overseas -- by mid-century at a cost of $26 billion a year, more than Australia now earns from its meat, grain and other food exports.

And whatever their domestic impact, these measures will have a zero effect on overall global emission levels, even in the unlikely event that there is a global agreement.

Australian CO2 emission levels are relatively high, partly because our low-cost coal provides economical electricity allowing us to export energy-intensive goods like aluminium.  Importing countries are therefore outsourcing carbon emissions to us.

Nonetheless, the Government fails to explain why we have high emissions, preferring to wear them as a badge of shame.

Nor does it advertise that Australia's vast land mass also absorbs carbon dioxide.  Based on CSIRO estimates, Australian soils absorb 138 million tonnes of carbon dioxide a year.  That's a fair chunk of the 330 tonnes of yearly emissions by our households, producers and transport vehicles.

Much of the motive for the Australian Government's apparent unconcern about the national interest stems from its wish to obtain international credits for other goals.

It hopes to use these credits to further its aspirations for Australia to obtain a seat on the United Nations Security Council and, perhaps, to promote Prime Minister Kevin Rudd's ambition to become secretary-general of that body.

After all, former New Zealand PM Helen Clark has a gig as head of the UN development program.  So the top job in the world body cannot be beyond the reach of a Chinese-speaking Australian PM.

A step on the way to this may be Mr Rudd's invitation to become a "friend of the chair" of next month's Copenhagen climate change conference.

Some Australians would be pleased to see their country as a member of the UN Security Council and would be thrilled to see their PM as UN secretary-general.

However, few would think it worth sacrificing jobs and living standards to promote those goals.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, October 30, 2009

Palming off livelihoods?  The misguided campaign against palm oil

ABBREVIATIONS

EU = European Union
FSANZ = Food Standards Australia and New Zealand
NGOs = Non government organisations
RSPO = Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil
UNICEF = United Nations Children's Fund


1.0 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Internationally environmental non-government organisations and activists are campaigning against industry and consumer use of palm oil.  Their opposition to is driven by claims that it is unsustainable promotes deforestation and reduces orang-utan populations.

Regulations have now been approved in the European Union to artificially reduce the capacity for palm oil to be imported as a biofuel.

But these campaigns are based on false foundations.

The primary cause of deforestation is poverty -- not palm oil.  One of the core reasons forests are converted to agricultural use is because poor farmers need land to grow crops to sell on the international market to help themselves, and their communities, be lifted out of poverty.  In fact small holders account for up to 40 per cent of planted palm oil plantations in Malaysia and 45 per cent in Indonesia.

Palm oil is in demand in the developing world.  If palm oil isn't consumed in developed countries, developing countries will simply be flooded with cheaper product, and other lower-yield agriculture products may be grown to replace it.  And in contrast to the activist campaigns, because palm oil is a high yield oil seed in comparison to its competitors, its use is likely to cause less deforestation and keep more forests intact.

In recognising the impact that the industry is having, private certification regimes, like the RSPO, have developed to give consumers confidence that palm oil is produced sustainably.

Deliberately reducing consumption of palm oil is not going address the primary reasons behind the declining orang-utan population, but it will definitely harm one of their closest cousins in the area -- poor farmers and their communities.  Reducing demand for palm oil will harm their livelihoods and their capacity to lift themselves out of poverty.

Palm oil is also a necessary dietary staple for the poor because it is a rich source of Vitamin A.  Vitamin A is essential to boost the immune system, and Vitamin A deficiency leads to the death of one million children in the developing world each year.

Rather than being a campaign to help conserve animal and plant life in Malaysia and Indonesia, opposing palm oil is a misguided campaign that will alleviate developed world consumers of guilt, at the expense of the world's poor.


2.0 INTRODUCTION

Recently NGOs and activists have run campaigns in Australia and New Zealand attacking the use of palm oil as an ingredient in consumer products.  As a staple agriculture product in Indonesia and Malaysia the consequences of reducing consumer demand has the potential to have a real impact on these countries and those who depend on the industry for their livelihoods.

This backgrounder will analyse the palm oil industry, the campaign against it, whether it is justified and who will deal with the consequences.


3.0 WHY PALM OIL?

Palm oil, extracted from the fruit of oil palms, is the world's most produced oil seed and all-round one of the world's most produced agriculture commodities.  Brought to South East Asia in the 19th Century from Africa, (1) nearly 90 per cent of the world's palm oil is currently grown in Malaysia and Indonesia.

Palm oil is a valuable commodity in Indonesia and Malaysia because it is an inexpensive, high yield oil crop that is in demand in the lucrative export market because it is used as an ingredient in many common household products including margarine, potato chips, chocolate, margarine and soap. (2)  Palm oil is particularly popular in developed country markets because is it trans-fat free. (3)

Global production of palm oil has risen from 16.9 million tonnes in 1995 to 43.1 million tonnes (4) in 2008 and is the world's most traded edible oil.

Since December 2007 Indonesia has overtaken Malaysia as the world's largest producer of palm oil, (5) with around 40 per cent of plantations run by small holders in Malaysia, and 45 per cent in Indonesia. (6)  In 2006 the Indonesian palm oil industry employed approximately 1.5 million people. (7)  Employees are also provided with free or heavily subsidised housing, schools and healthcare. (8)

Earlier this year the Indonesian government announced plans to double its palm oil output by 2020, but only 20 per cent of that growth is expected from increased plantations. (9)  Most is expected from improved yields;  especially the yields of small holders.

One of the core reasons that palm oil is grown in Indonesia is because the government is seen as "aware of the need to alleviate poverty and to provide food and employment on an economically sound and sustainable basis to an already large and rapidly increasing population", (10) and holds the belief that "labor and land remain plentiful" (11) for production.

Despite historically producing more palm oil than Indonesia, the Malaysian industry has a higher yield output than Indonesia because of "improved tree varieties, improved cultural practices, and perhaps the biological yield cycle" (12) -- not expanding land use.  As of 2007 the Malaysian industry supported more than half a million workers. (13)


4.0 THE CAMPAIGN AGAINST PALM OIL

Yet, despite the benefits of palm oil to farmers in Asia and the Pacific islands, campaigns are now run against palm oil based on allegations that it is grown on land converted from natural forest, causes carbon dioxide emissions and reduces habitat for endangered species like the orang-utan.

Despite only emerging in Australia and New Zealand's mainstream media this year, Greenpeace (14) and Friends of the Earth (15) have been campaigning against the growth, importation and commercial use of palm oil for years.  Their campaigning activities have ranged from opposing the loading of palm oil shipments to developed country markets, (16) to lobbying European officials to ban the importation of palm oil as a biofuel (17) to working to get palm oil industry advertisements taken off television. (18)

And they have had some success.  In 2002 Swiss-based supermarket chain, Migros, announced plans to hire auditors every year to assess the sustainability of palm oil suppliers. (19)  A number of US and EU-based companies have taken equivalent measures or stopped using palm oil all together.  And in 2008 the European Parliament accepted a directive imposing limitations on biofuels that can be imported into the EU.  As a result, from 2009 imported biofuels must reduce carbon dioxide emissions by at least 35 per cent against fossil fuel alternatives, (20) artificially locking out palm oil because its bottom range can be as low as a 19 per cent saving, but actually has the potential of a 72 per cent saving. (21)

And in early 2008 the campaign against palm oil reached Australia and New Zealand.  Following complaints from anti-palm groups the Auckland Zoo took Cadbury chocolates off its shelves, and anti-palm oil activists encouraged consumers to "Boycott Cadbury".  Their campaign was also supported by the establishment of Facebook group claiming "Only d*cks eat Cadbury". (22)  After a relatively short campaign, Cadbury New Zealand advised that they were removing palm oil as a key ingredient from chocolate, despite health benefits.

The campaign then moved across the Tasman and Cadbury also removed palm oil as an ingredient in its Australian chocolate products. (23)  The Melbourne Zoo, partnering with celebrities from popular television and radio programs, have established a similar campaign criticising the use of palm oil. (24)  Their "Don't Palm Us Off" campaign is designed to request the Food Standards Australia and New Zealand (FSANZ), an intergovernmental body that establishes standards on food labelling, to specifically require palm oil to be labelled on all products. (25)  Currently it is labelled as part of a family of vegetable oils.  The objective of the campaign is to encourage consumers to haze products that include palm oil, and by default push industry to stop using it as an ingredient in their products. (26)

And more recently the web-based Palm Oil Action Group has produced and supplied coloured stickers to activists that state "Warning:  contains palm oil".  These stickers are being used on supermarket products that have palm oil as an ingredient to encourage consumers not to buy them. (27)


5.0 PALMING OFF LIVELIHOODS?

The campaign run against palm oil is multi-faceted, but has one clear objective -- to reduce the consumption of palm oil in its raw and processed forms in developed country markets, like Europe, the United States, Australia and New Zealand.  But these campaigns have been built on false foundations.


5.1 DEFORESTATION AND ORANG-UTANS

The principle claim by anti-palm oil activists against the industry is that it causes deforestation in Malaysia and Indonesia and the loss of habitat for orang-utans.  But what activists miss is the core driver for the demand for increased agriculture land;  it isn't palm oil specifically, but the development of primary industries to help lift rural communities out of poverty.  This was the same driver that saw wealthy countries redevelop land for agriculture practices to support economic development.

Without palm oil deforestation would still occur, it would just be for a different crop.  But farmers have used palm oil because it is a high yield oil seed that delivers between three and four tonnes per hectare.  By comparison competitor seeds such as rapeseed, sunflower and soybean oils yield less than 0.7 tonnes per hectare. (28)

Behind the claims that expanding plantations for palm oil is driving increased deforestation, and increased output from the industry, the reality is that recent growth in industry output has been a direct result of increased yields driven by industry improvements.

While deforestation is legitimately concerning, like in developed countries, not all land can be kept as forest.  The European average is only 25 per cent, which is roughly the same as allocated in Indonesia, and less than half of Malaysia's allocation at more than 55 per cent. (29)  As the Stern Review found less than 20 per cent of forest land cleared in Indonesia was to support the palm oil industry, and it is only 30 per cent in Malaysia. (30)

And behind the superficial claims of activists arguing that virgin rainforest is behind destroyed, a deeper reading of their material points out that "it is unlikely that virgin forests are still cleared for palm oil expansion in Malaysia on any significant scale, merely because most forests have already been logged, at least once". (31)

Measures should reasonably be taken to protect wildlife like orang-utans, such as the Malaysian government's plan to ban planting palm oil near rivers to maintain wildlife habitats. (32)  But pressuring consumers off consuming palm oil won't solve the problem, but it does have the potential to increase the amount of land needed to produce equivalent agriculture output.

In 2004 the palm oil industry established the Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil to develop and enforce private certification standards to "promote the growth and use of sustainable oil palm products through credible global standards and engagement of stakeholders". (33)  Part of RSPO criteria for certification is that new plantations not replace land with a high conservation value and damage to high conservation value habitat is avoided.  And under the GreenPalm program consumers can buy GreenPalm certified palm oil products and make a contribution to farmers who voluntarily choose to have their product independently certified. (34)

Industry has also partnered with civil society in projects like the Borneo Conservation Trust and the World Wildlife Fund to develop programs that ensure endangered wildlife are not threatened.


5.2 SUSTAINABILITY FOR WHOM?

The campaign against palm oil is underpinned by the expectation that palm oil cannot be produced in an environmentally, socially and economically sustainable way.  Yet even the United Nations Development program recognises the potential for it to be grown and harvested in a sustainable manner. (35)

But there is one area that palm oil activist campaigns won't deliver a sustainable outcome -- the economic sustainability of the roughly one million Indonesians and Malaysian workers who depend on the industry for their livelihoods and the millions of people dependent on it as a dietary staple.

An agriculture crop principally grown in developing countries, small holder palm oil farmers include some of the world's poorest producers.  And they are not insignificant contributors to the industry.  In Malaysia small holders account for up to 40 per cent of the total area of planted oil palm and in Indonesia it is 45 per cent. (36)  And the industries in both countries support hundreds of thousands of workers.  And that is one of the reasons why the Asian Development Bank finances palm oil projects, whose success ensures that it delivers strong repayment rates on loans from funded projects. (37)

Supporting poor farmers is not the only contribution of palm oil.  Is also a dietary staple for millions of Indonesians and Malaysians, as well as the poor in other developing countries.  Palm oil also has a high Vitamin A content, an essential dietary vitamin to boost the immune system.  According to UNICEF an estimated one million young children die each year as a consequence of complications from Vitamin A deficiency. (38)


6.0 CONCLUSIONS

Palm oil is an essential crop in the developing world, but most importantly for the world's two largest producers -- Indonesia and Malaysia.  Recent campaigns against palm oil by developed country activists may appear to be well intentioned to promote the best interests of communities and wildlife in these countries, but they are misguided in blaming palm oil.

Lost forest and the impact that may have on endangered species isn't a consequence of growing palm oil, but the consequence of the developing world's process toward economic development.  Contrary to the claims of anti-palm oil activists, because it is a high yield crop, palm oil may actually be limiting any deforestation needed by farmers to expand holdings and increase usable land.  And recent significant increases of output by the industry have not been driven by increased land use, but increased yields which have progressively grown.

Reducing demand in developed world markets may make consumers feel good, but it will not be cost free.  An essential crop, it provides nearly one million workers in Indonesia and Malaysia with a sustainable livelihood and is also a vital dietary supplement in these countries to boost immune systems and stave off developing world diseases that can kill millions each year.


7.0 REFERENCE LIST

___., 2009, "Buttering up chocolates", Daily Telegraph, August 20, Sydney, Australia

___., 2006, "Indonesia counting on biofuel", International Herald Tribune, August 16

___., 2009, "Malaysia argues for green palm with own CO2 standard", The Malaysian Insider, October 19

___., 2009, "Malaysia to ban some palm oil plantations to protect orangutans", Malaysia in Focus, October 15

AFP, 2009, "Indonesia to double palm oil production by 2020", Khaleej Times (Business), May 27

Asian Development Bank, 1999, "Project performance audit report on the West New Britain small holder development project"

Basiron, Y. 2008, "Malaysia's Oil Palm -- Hallmark of Sustainable Development", Global Oils & Fats Business Magazine, v5, i4

Brown, E. & Jacobson, M., 2005, "Cruel oil:  How palm oil harms health, rainforest and wildlife", Centre for Science in the Public Interest, Washington DC, United States of America

Commission of the European Communities, 2008, "Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources", Brussels, January 23

Datuk, A.Y., 2009, "Case of biofuel in Asia:  Palm oil based biofueld in Indonesia, Malaysia and Papua New Guinea", Nueva Sociedad

Forest Watch Indonesia, World Resources Institute & Global Forest Watch, 2002, "The State of the Forest:  Indonesia", Washington DC, United States of America, February

Friends of the Earth International, 2008, "Malaysian palm oil -- green gold or green wash:  A commentary on the sustainability claims of Malaysia's palm oil lobby, with a special focus on the state of Sarawak", October

Friends of the Earth International and Friends of the Earth Europe, 2007, "Complaint to the Advertising Standards Authority", July 25

GreenPalm, "How it works", London, United Kingdom

Greenpeace, 2007, "How the palm oil industry is cooking the climate", November 8

Greenpeace, 2009, "Greenpeace challenges RSPO to stop green-washing member companies", November 14

Greig-Gran, M., 2008, "The cost of avoiding deforestation:  Update of the report prepared for the Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change", International Institute for Environment and Development, London, United Kingdom

NZPA, 2009, "Cadbury sweet with Auckland Zoo", New Zealand Herald, August 18

Oil World, 2008, "Oil World Annual 2008", Hamburg, Germany

Riedner, U., 2002, "Palm oil from sustainable production -- a Migros pilot project", Migros

Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil, "Overview of RSPO", Factsheet, RSPO, Malaysia

Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil, "Palm Oil, Factsheet, RSPO, Malaysia

Sargeant, H., 2001, "Vegetation fires in Sumatra Indonesia:  Oil palm agriculture in the wetlands of Sumatra:  Destruction or development?", Forest fire prevention and control project, Ministry of Forestry, European Union

Sunday Star-Times, 2009, "Palm oil foes sticking it to supermarkets", New Zealand, October 11

UNICEF, 2004, "Vitamin and mineral deficiency:  A global damage assessment report", United Nations, New York

United Nations Development Program, 2007, "Human Development Report 2007/08", United Nations

United States Department of Agriculture, 2007, "Indonesia:  Palm oil production prospects continue to grow", Foreign agriculture service, Commodity intelligence report, December 31

United States Department of Agriculture, 2005, "Malaysia:  Palm oil yields surprisingly high", Production estimates and crop assessment division, Foreign Agriculture Service, June 24

Vermeulen, S. & Goad, N., 2006, "Towards better practice in smallholder palm oil production", International Institute for Environment and Development

World Growth, 2009, "Palm oil -- the sustainable oil", Washington DC, United States of America September

Zoos Victoria, 2009, "Campaign launch"

Zoos Victoria, 2009, "Don't palm us off", October 2

Zoos Victoria, 2009, "What do I need to know?"



ENDNOTES

1.  Datuk, A.Y., 2009, "Case of biofuel in Asia:  Palm oil based biofueld in Indonesia, Malaysia and Papua New Guinea", Nueva Sociedad

2.  Forest Watch Indonesia, World Resources Institute & Global Forest Watch, 2002, "The State of the Forest:  Indonesia", Washington DC, United States of America, February, p42

3.  Brown, E. & Jacobson, M., 2005, "Cruel oil:  How palm oil harms health, rainforest and wildlife", Centre for Science in the Public Interest, Washington DC, United States of America, p27

4.  Oil World, 2008, "Oil World Annual 2008", Hamburg, Germany

5.  United States Department of Agriculture, 2007, "Indonesia:  Palm oil production prospects continue to grow", Foreign agriculture service, Commodity intelligence report, December 31

6.  AFP, 2009, "Indonesia to double palm oil production by 2020", Khaleej Times (Business), May 27

7.  ___., 2006, "Indonesia counting on biofuel", International Herald Tribune, August 16

8.  Sargeant, H., 2001, "Vegetation fires in Sumatra Indonesia:  Oil palm agriculture in the wetlands of Sumatra:  Destruction or development?", Forest fire prevention and control project, Ministry of Forestry, European Union, pvi

9.  AFP, 2009

10.  Sargeant, 2001, pv

11.  Sargeant, 2001, pvi

12.  United States Department of Agriculture, 2005, "Malaysia:  Palm oil yields surprisingly high", Production estimates and crop assessment division, Foreign Agriculture Service, June 24

13.  Basiron, Y. 2008, "Malaysia's Oil Palm -- Hallmark of Sustainable Development", Global Oils & Fats Business Magazine, v5, i4

14.  Greenpeace, 2007, "How the palm oil industry is cooking the climate", November 8

15.  Friends of the Earth International, 2008, "Malaysian palm oil -- green gold or green wash:  A commentary on the sustainability claims of Malaysia's palm oil lobby, with a special focus on the state of Sarawak", October, i114

16.  Greenpeace, 2009, "Greenpeace challenges RSPO to stop green-washing member companies", November 14

17.  Greenpeace, 2007, "How the palm oil industry is cooking the climate", November 8

18.  Friends of the Earth International and Friends of the Earth Europe, 2007, "Complaint to the Advertising Standards Authority", July 25

19.  Riedner, U., 2002, "Palm oil from sustainable production -- a Migros pilot project", Migros

20.  Commission of the European Communities, 2008, "Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources", Brussels, January 23, p32

21.  ___., 2009, "Malaysia argues for green palm with own CO2 standard", The Malaysian Insider, October 19

22.  NZPA, 2009, "Cadbury sweet with Auckland Zoo", New Zealand Herald, August 18

23.  ___., 2009, "Buttering up chocolates", Daily Telegraph, August 20, Sydney, Australia

24.  Zoos Victoria, 2009, "Don't palm us off", October 2

25.  Zoos Victoria, 2009, "Campaign launch"

26.  Zoos Victoria, 2009, "What do I need to know?"

27.  Sunday Star-Times, 2009, "Palm oil foes sticking it to supermarkets", New Zealand, October 11

28.  Oil World, 2008, "Oil World Annual 2008", Hamburg, Germany, and Brown, E. & Jacobson, M., 2005, "Cruel oil:  How palm oil harms health, rainforest and wildlife", Centre for Science in the Public Interest, Washington DC, United States of America, p7

29.  World Growth, 2009, "Palm oil -- the sustainable oil", Washington DC, United States of America September

30.  Greig-Gran, M., 2008, "The cost of avoiding deforestation:  Update of the report prepared for the Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change", International Institute for Environment and Development, London, United Kingdom

31.  Friends of the Earth International, 2008, "Malaysian palm oil -- green gold or green wash:  A commentary on the sustainability claims of Malaysia's palm oil lobby, with a special focus on the state of Sarawak", October, i114, p30

32.  ___., 2009, "Malaysia to ban some palm oil plantations to protect orangutans", Malaysia in Focus, October 15

33.  Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil, "Overview of RSPO", Factsheet, RSPO, Malaysia

34.  GreenPalm, "How it works", London, United Kingdom

35.  United Nations Development Program, 2007, "Human Development Report 2007/08", United Nations, p144

36.  Vermeulen, S. & Goad, N., 2006, "Towards better practice in smallholder palm oil production", International Institute for Environment and Development, p4

37.  Asian Development Bank, 1999, "Project performance audit report on the West New Britain small holder development project"

38.  UNICEF, 2004, "Vitamin and mineral deficiency:  A global damage assessment report", United Nations, New York

Commonwealth rules tax roost over states

The avalanche of reviews ordered by the Federal Government has not been shy in recommending changes to how state governments operate.  The Henry tax review will be next in the conga line of top-down advice.

The recommendations by Treasury secretary Ken Henry on state revenue reform will be of vital importance to the quality of government in the future.  This is because the basic rule of Australian federalism is that who holds the tax rules the roost on policymaking.

On this score, the states are widely viewed to have been consigned to feather-duster status.  The Commonwealth has progressively gained extra taxing powers, leaving the states in a mendicant position of relying on federal grants for much of their revenue.

It is in this context of so-called "vertical fiscal imbalance" that Henry will redraw the line on what taxes should be allocated to which level of government.

Will the Rudd Government's top economic adviser recommend that the Commonwealth remains on top of the revenue pecking order, or will he suggest that the feds show fiscal humility by giving some revenue room to the states?

It is difficult to predict the outcome of a closed-door review, but keynote speeches by Henry, and media reports, can serve as some guide.

Twice this year, at least, Henry has spoken of the virtues of greater co-ordination of state taxes.

The idea that the Tax Office manage state tax administration on behalf of the states was viewed as a way to apply broader tax bases, including for payroll tax, and eliminate the alleged evils of interstate tax competition once and for all.

The creation of state tax sub-divisions of the Tax Office would effectively extend the policy influence of the head of the Henry review secretariat.

Others, including major business representative organisations concerned about compliance costs, would also welcome the extinction of tax base competition between the states.

But wholesale state tax harmonisation would restrict opportunities for taxpayers to select a jurisdiction with a more amenable tax structure.  In other words, two key virtues of fiscal federalism -- choice and diversity -- would be further diminished in the tax realm.

As explained by Australian National University economist Geoffrey Brennan, any efficiency gains due to broader taxes might also be more than offset by the consequent growth of inefficient government spending.

The idea that tax centralism is desirable has also infused Henry's suggestion that the Commonwealth introduce a profit-based royalty regime in place of royalties levied by the states.

Several specific arguments raised by Henry in March appear spurious.  It was suggested that the states are in a weak bargaining position when negotiating with mobile resource developers, leading to greater revenue constraints for jurisdictions.

This scenario would be no less of a reality for the Commonwealth with central resource royalty powers, as developers make decisions about competing projects located in, say, Brazil, Canada or South Africa.

The veracity of the claim that a single Commonwealth royalty regime might be less subject to change, reducing sovereign risk, is undercut by frequent changes already made to existing federal tax streams.

One glimmer of hope is that the Henry review may commend at least a personal income tax-sharing system between the Commonwealth and states.

In general terms, the Commonwealth would reduce its income tax rates, giving room for the states to levy their own rates on top.

While this proposal is a far cry from a much better policy to return all of the personal income tax responsibility to the states, there are some likely benefits from a tax-sharing deal.

If states set their own rates of income tax, up to a certain limit, they would be somewhat more accountable to voters.

For a Henry review sure to contain plenty of advice, it will be intriguing to see if it urges the Commonwealth to step aside and give federalism a fighting chance.


ADVERTISEMENT

Enough of the hysteria ... refugees are good for us

Australia has an open-borders arrangement with New Zealand and, despite what they say, we are just not being over-run by Kiwis.  They don't even share our cultural values -- they play rugby union.  It is simply ridiculous to imagine that we will be "over-run" by anyone else.

It is just not credible to label the current hysteria as being an "immigration debate".  The Rudd government's Indonesia policy is a total shambles and but for the magnitude of the human tragedy and loss of life the sight of Rudd being hoist on the petard of hypocrisy would be one of the all-time great moments of schadenfreude.

Refugee policy stupidity is bipartisan; the only party that has had a consistent and sensible approach to illegal immigrants and refugees has been the Greens.  Both the ALP and the Coalition has tried to gain the high moral ground while peddling xenophobia as viable policy.

Australia has a deep and ugly xenophobia running through its psyche.  This manifests itself in many ways:  the Foreign Investment Review Board operates to vet foreign investment, AQIS protects Australia from foreign agriculture and the phobia towards boat arrivals borders on racism.  This all fits into the anti-foreign bias that Bryan Caplan talks about in his book The myth of the rational voter:  Why democracies choose bad policies.  People tend to systematically underestimate the benefits of dealing with foreigners.

This phenomenon goes all the way back to the White Australia Policy and should be seen in the same light.  There are many more visa over stayers in Australia than there are boat people, yet it is the latter who cause all the kerfuffle.  "Illegals" are more likely to have arrived in Australia through Sydney airport from Europe than by boat.  There is almost no discussion of those people -- after all, they are probably good for tourism and picking fruit.

Accepting more refugees and boat people into the country is one of the greatest contributions Australia can make to improving the world around us and enhancing our own living standards.  Rather than accepting people because we have an "obligation" under international law, why not accept people because we have an opportunity to improve living standards?

Most of our foreign aid dollar is probably wasted.  Remittances back home are going to do a lot more for the region (and even beyond) than tax-dollars will ever do.  Allowing more people into Australia to work and improve their lives will have massive spillovers on the lives of their families and friends back home.  Why let Canberra waste our tax-dollars on foreign aid, when people can and want to help themselves?

Perhaps the greatest furphy is the argument about the welfare state.  The notion that refugees come here simply because they want to get on to welfare is often heard.  Milton Friedman once argued that an open borders policy was inconsistent with a welfare state.  Perhaps.  But why define ourselves by welfare;  what about the rule of law, freedom of contract, freedom from persecution and so on?  Our welfare policies have not made us comfortable, rich and prosperous, rather our work-ethic and our "propensity to truck, barter, and exchange one thing for another".

We also hear that terrorists may enter Australia via boat arrivals.  To be sure that is true, by definition.  Many refugees will have opposed their own government and lost; these people are almost always labelled "terrorist".  Had they won, these "freedom fighters" would then not be refugees.  To the extent these people are a menace to Australia that is a matter for the police and criminal justice system.

Fundamentally, the acceptance of refugees is good for Australia.  How often do we hear "We should only take in people who would benefit Australia?"  This simply begs the question, how does accepting people into the country who want to work and make a better life for themselves and their children not benefit Australia?

The great Austrian economists Ludwig von Mises described the market economy as cooperation under the division of labour.  By having more people in Australia there are more people to cooperate with, more people to trade with and more people to grow the market.  As our wealth and economy grows there is more money for the finer things in life.

Of course, we might hear that immigration brings unemployment and infrastructure stress.  But the unemployment argument rests on the lump of labour fallacy.  There isn't a finite amount of work that needs to be shared out amongst more and more people.  The infrastructure argument is just lazy government making excuses for their lack of service provision.  They levy the tax every year, they can provide the services.

The bottom line is this; rather than trying to keep people out, we should be looking to bring people in.  The need for some or other orderly process (we will always have customs) is being hijacked by an anti-migrant and anti-refugee debate.  It is also being morphed into an anti-Muslim debate.  There needs to be leadership on this issue.  All worthwhile reforms are difficult and often require leadership in changing public attitudes.


ADVERTISEMENT

Ultimate civic nonsense

Kevin Rudd announced on Tuesday that he wanted the federal government to be involved in the urban planning for Australia's cities.  Presumably, he thinks he'll succeed where Nathan Rees, John Brumby and Anna Bligh have failed.

Admittedly, any planning he does for Sydney couldn't be worse than what the NSW government has done.  But before our nation's leader takes responsibility for fixing overcrowded trains, mending pot-holed roads and granting building approvals for multi-storey car parks in residential neighbourhoods there are a few issues to be resolved.

For one thing, it's not as though the PM doesn't have enough to-do already.

Maybe he should finish what he's already started before beginning something new.  Maybe he should concentrate on fixing the health system, as he promised to do.  Or completing his "education revolution".  Or solving the problems of the Murray-Darling Basin.

Then there's the question of what the federal government knows about planning anyway.  You only have to go to Canberra to get an idea of what a city planned by federal bureaucrats looks like.

Suburbs such as Woden, Belconnen and Tuggeranong, with their rows of parallel streets with identical-looking houses, have been streetscaped to conform to the most exacting standards of 1960s Scandinavian social engineering.  The result is a national capital devoid of any sense of energy, vitality or community.  And it isn't just because Canberra is where the public servants live.

Planning, federal government-style, doesn't allow for choice or diversity, let alone spontaneity.  And you don't have to go back to the Whitlam government for the evidence.  The so-called education revolution has given the country dozens of school halls of the same size, shape and colour regardless of what school communities want and regardless of whether students' most pressing educational needs are new buildings in which to have morning assembly.

When announcing this new role for the federal government, Rudd said he didn't want federal ministers to have a direct role in the day-to-day decisions of state and local governments.  But there's no such thing as just a little bit of involvement in planning.  Inevitably and eventually, a federal infrastructure planning minister will be approving how and where shopping centres can be built in exactly the same way as the federal environment minister now appr9ves how and where a paper mill in Tasmania or a wind farm in Victoria can be built.

The federal government is, in effect, already making planning decisions:  the school halls of the education revolution are exempt from local council planning regulations.  Which is what the residents of Unley in Adelaide discovered a few months ago when they found out that the heritage restrictions imposed on their homes didn't apply to the new $3 million hall for the local primary school we now have one planning law for residents who want to build a carport in their driveway, and another planning law for the federal government.

Rudd's foray into urban planning is underpinned by one central assumption:  that federal politicians and bureaucrats are less susceptible to parochial and political pressure than their state colleagues, and that's why infrastructure decisions are better made at the national level This assumption is patently false.  And of all people, Rudd should know it.

It's ironic that on Tuesday he spoke about the need for "efficient transport and communication networks" and the importance of capital-city airports.  In 1998 his maiden speech in parliament attacked a proposal for Brisbane airport to increase its passenger capacity by building a new runway.

Kevin Rudd and the Brisbane airport saga is a perfect example of the "not in my backyard" attitude stopping infrastructure development.

It's also ironic that Rudd wants state governments to submit their planning systems "to independent, expert advice".

Yet the federal government refuses to allow any sort of similar cost-benefit analysis of its $43 billion national broadband network extravaganza.

Federal MPs are just as good, if not better, at building roads to nowhere than state MPs.  And federal MPs are just as adept as state MPs at manipulating infrastructure projects for political purposes.  At least at the moment state and local government planning decisions are subject to a degree of democratic control If ever Canberra did get the power to plan our cities, whatever political accountability now exists for planning decisions would disappear.

Our planning system is not perfect, but it's not so bad as to justify the federal government taking it over.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, October 27, 2009

My shovel's better than yours

According to the report for the Business Council, Groundwork for Growth, by Port Jackson Partners, only 14 per cent of the $76 billion it regards as stimulus spending was on infrastructure.  That actually overstates the real amount since it includes all those unnecessary school assembly halls, welfare housing, pink batts, "clean" energy and other expensive low productivity expenditures that are oriented towards the ballot box rather than economic efficiency.

Meanwhile, in keeping with political tradition, Infrastructure Minister Albanese and Nationals leader Warren Truss are falling over each other to claim the credit for spending the taxpayers' money.  Mr Truss says the Howard Government identified the spending priorities for which Mr Albanese is busily cutting the ribbons.

Although Mr Albanese claims to have completed 32 major road and rail projects, the "successes" trumpeted most loudly are community centres and bike paths with his press releases over the past fortnight alone listing 20 new cycling initiatives.  Perhaps he is preparing us for the bleak low-carbon future when, other than for the political elites, tax induced fuel price increases will replace the car trip with peddle power and air travel vacations with freewheeling along local roads.

Mr Albanese hits at a plummeting level of "public" infrastructure spending in the Howard years.  Misleadingly this neglects the vast increase in private infrastructure provision as a result of the privatisation reforms that Mr Albanese bitterly opposed.  According to the Port Jackson Partners report, overall economic infrastructure spending averaged about 4 per cent of GDP in the 15 years to 2004 and has since risen, hitting 5 per cent in 2008.  Within that total spending, the private share of infrastructure increased to one half from under a fifth.  In real dollars, engineering construction work over the past three years was threefold its level of the late-1980s/early-1990s.

This shift of infrastructure spending towards the private sector during the past 20 years provided a productivity bonus.  This is because private investment spending must pass a true test of economic necessity, shorn of the political dividends that offer the main justification for bike paths and most public investment.

Even though it identifies an increase in capital expenditure, the Port Jackson Partners report considers we have missed an opportunity to use the global financial crisis to bring increased infrastructure investment.  The report may be correct in its judgement that had we had the "shovel ready" projects, this would have made far better use of public money than the give-aways that it claims accounted for 86 per cent of the stimulus package.  But in discussing broadband it notes a major deficiency of government infrastructure provision.  The National Broadband Network is being planned without proper costing, with unclear objectives and with a likely potential to create an artificial monopoly by shutting out rival technologies like wireless.

This typifies a wider problem with public or subsidised projects.  Those projects are rarely judged with the same rigor as private measures and are always likely to be geared towards less than optimal populist measures.  They will comprise under-patronised regional rail services rather than roads, high priced desalination plants rather than dams, costly and poorly performing windfarms rather than base load power plants.

Instead of having the government identify "shovel ready" projects it is better that the regulatory impediments to private provisions of infrastructure are removed.  The Port Jackson report identifies some of these but fails to recognise the "chilling" effect on new infrastructure provision caused by regulatory controls of agencies like the ACCC and the NCC.  Indeed, the report calls for rather more government intrusion into the management of freight, electricity and water provision.

And this is especially hazardous when the lights are flashing green on government spending increases.


ADVERTISEMENT

Monday, October 26, 2009

Obama seeks to silence a critic

The Obama administration has declared war on Fox News.  In the past week, senior White House aides have slammed Rupert Murdoch's popular cable channel, insisting that Fox is a stooge of the Republican Party and that other media outlets should not follow its stories.

Recently, Barack Obama went on every Sunday news show in the US -- except Fox News.  And last week, his Treasury Department tried to exclude Fox reporters from covering a press conference.

Of course, feuds between presidents and journalists are nothing new.

In 1942, Franklin D. Roosevelt was so upset by an isolationist reporter's coverage of World War II that he "awarded" him a Nazi Iron Cross at a press conference.  In 1963, John F. Kennedy called on the publisher of The New York Times to pull war correspondent (and future Pulitzer-prize winning journalist) David Halberstam from Vietnam after he wrote increasingly bad news reports.

In 1970, Richard Nixon's vice-president, Spiro Agnew, lambasted the press as a bunch of "nattering nabobs of negativism".  And during the 1992 election campaign, George H.W. Bush famously showed a placard reading:  "Annoy the media:  re-elect Bush".

What makes the latest stoush different is that Mr Obama wants to not only delegitimise any significant dissent, but isolate a media network that represents the thoughts and attitudes of a significant segment of the American community.

White House communications director Anita Dunn, who rates Mao Zedong as one of her favourite philosophers, said of Fox:  "We're going to treat them the way we would treat an opponent."

That is not how democracies are supposed to work.  It would be akin to John Howard launching a vendetta against The Age, simply because he did not agree with its editorial positions.

Now, there is no question that Fox News is far more conservative than other networks.  Its prime-time voices are perpetually angry right-wingers such as Sean Hannity, Bill O'Reilly and Glenn Beck.  And chief executive and chairman Roger Ailes has consistently said programming reflects a mission to balance a left-wing bias of the elite media.

But this also explains why Fox News has grown dramatically since its creation in 1996 and why it drives Democratic partisans right off the deep end.  Rightly or wrongly, it is seen by an increasingly large viewership as a welcome corrective to a mainstream media (ABC, CBS, NBC, PBS, NPR, CNN, MSNBC, New York Times, Washington Post, Los Angeles Times) which leans left in a nation where conservatives, according to polls, remain the largest ideological group.

All the available evidence indicates the major US networks and newspapers reflect a left-liberal consensus.  In 1992, for example, a large sample (Roper poll) of top Washington reporters, editors and bureau chiefs voted 89 per cent to 7 per cent for Bill Clinton over George H.W. Bush, even though regular Americans had voted for the Democrat over the Republican by 43 to 38 per cent.

In recent years, Fox has been called a right-wing "fifth column" (Al Gore), a "propaganda mill" (Washington Post) and "the most blatantly biased major American news organisation since the era of yellow journalism" (Los Angeles Times) that has "eliminated journalism" (legendary journalist Walter Cronkite).

The problem here is that Fox's news coverage is confused with its highly opinionated and entertaining brand of political debate.

Yet Fox's news and current affairs output and the opinions stated on Hannity, Glenn Beck and The O'Reilly Factor are kept separate in what the Americans irreverently refer to as "the separation between church and state".  Fox, moreover, breaks many news stories that shame the major networks and newspapers.  In 2000, it broke the story of George Bush's youthful DUI, which many Republicans believe nearly cost him the election.

In 2002, whereas much of the media hastily reported an alleged Israeli massacre of Palestinian civilians in a refugee camp in the West Bank city of Jenin, Fox -- correctly, it turned out -- treated the massacre charge with absolute scepticism.

In 2005, it helped reveal the corruption of the UN's multi-billion-dollar oil-for-food program in Iraq, in which top UN officials accepted bribes.  Much of the US media did not push the news story.

Earlier this year, it exposed White House tsar Van Jones as a September 11 conspiracy theorist.

As The Economist's editors and American watchers John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge argue:  "For all (Fox's) partisanship, much of its political reporting is first-rate."  In the present context, this merely means subjecting the Obama administration and Democratic congress to some tough scrutiny.

The result is that the White House is trying to silence a network that resonates with Middle America.  Those attacks hurt Obama.

And they help Fox win more viewers.  As Washington media insider Jeff Greenfield put it:  "If Fox is feeling any pain from the White House's stance, it is crying all the way to the bank."


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, October 24, 2009

The media bombards us with ETS coverage.  So why are we still in the dark?

"One of the leading journalists who writes about politics in Canberra rang me the other day and wanted to talk about some of this party room gossip [about leadership]," a besieged Malcolm Turnbull told the ABC1's Insiders last week.  "And I said:  'Why don't you write a serious piece comparing the way in which the Labor ETS in Australia fails to protect Australian jobs and Waxman-Markey protects American jobs?'  This is the legislation in the US House of Representatives.  And his answer to me was:  'What's Waxman-Markey?'.  No idea.  No interest.  No knowledge of the real issue."  The opposition leader is hardly alone in lamenting the Australian media's sparse coverage of Labor's proposed emissions trading legislation.

"I could count on one hand the number of journalists who are across the details of the government's Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme," revealed George Megalogenis in the Australian Literary Review this month.  "I can't think of a bigger reform that has generated so little public demand for scrutiny."

Both Liberal leader and esteemed political journalist are right:  for all the reams of newspaper copy and endless airtime devoted to the climate change debate, the Australian people are none the wiser about what the Rudd government claims is the most important economic reform in a generation.  This week's obsessive coverage of the Coalition party room's deliberations over whether or not to back pro-industry amendments to the CPRS was more of the same.

There are, of course, some rare exceptions.  Two months ago, for example, The Australian ran a lead front-page story on how the ETS would make household grocery prices rise by 5 per cent, costing some households hundreds of dollars a month.  The following day, the Fairfax press followed up the report, but not, alas, the public broadcaster's AM, PM or Lateline programmes.

For the most part, the so-called quality press, radio and television programmes champion this scheme, without examining how it would work and what it would cost.  The logic goes like this:  if you're really sincere about combating climate change, you must give unconditional support to Labor's ETS.

To the extent that the Canberra press gallery subjects the ETS to any scrutiny, it is the federal Coalition's policy.  Never mind that it is the Rudd government, not the opposition, which plans to impose potentially crushing costs on business and consumers.  The ETS is the tax that dare not speak its name, and Kevin Rudd is hoping that no one notices.

The irony here is that, measured in terms of print copy and air time, there is much more media coverage of the climate change debate in Australia than in the US.  A comprehensive search of newspaper articles on emissions trading (or cap and trade, as the Americans call it) from 1 January to this week reveals a yawning gap between the two nations.  The Australian, The Australian Financial Review, The Age and The Sydney Morning Herald have altogether published 1,030 news articles, editorials and opinion pieces on the ETS this year.  By contrast, the New York Times, Wall Street Journal, Washington Post and Los Angeles Times have altogether published only 266 news articles, editorials and opinion pieces on cap and trade.  That is a ratio of almost four to one.  Type in "climate change", and the disparity between Australian and American press coverage is just as clear.

It's the same story with respect to television.  Hardly a day goes by without an ABC nightly news or current affairs segment airing an item on the ETS.  But the major networks in the US -- PBS, ABC, CBS, NBC and Fox - hardly touch the subject.

And yet, as Turnbull and Megalogenis recognise, the Australian debate has so far been conducted in a reality vacuum.  Emissions trading, it seems, is seen simply through the prism of the Liberal leadership and not in the context of crucial international developments that will set a framework at the Copenhagen conference in December.

The US debate is especially important to Australians.  Take the climate and energy bill, commonly referred to as Waxman-Markey (named after two leading Democrat congressional co-sponsors, Henry Waxman and Ed Markey), about which Turnbull claims most Australian journalists know nothing and to which the Senate will make significant pro-business amendments.  It offers far more protection and incentives to industry and jobs, especially in the power-generating firms and trade-exposed industries such as mining and manufacturing, than does the proposed Australian system.  Indeed, the bill passed the US House precisely because of what the Wall Street Journal identified as "the extravaganza of log-rolling, votebuying, outright corporate bribes, side deals, subsidies and policy loopholes".  The CPRS is not prone to such corporate welfare.

The US bill, further, would auction 15 per cent of allowances while the rest would be given away;  the CPRS does not hand out so many free permits.

All of this matters.  Why?  Because if Canberra's final legislation differs dramatically from Washington's version, our exports would cop a carbon cost not borne by our competitors.  Australian industry would be internationally uncompetitive.

The second reason why the US debate is so important to Australians is this:  the UN talks slated for December will flounder without a clear plan from Washington.  And in the absence of US leadership, unilateral action could inflict collateral damage on our economy and way of life.  Yet all the available evidence indicates that a final Senate bill won't be signed by the President before Copenhagen.

It was not supposed to be like this.  During last year's presidential election campaign, Barack Obama and John McCain supported tough action to reduce carbon emissions.  But although Waxman-Markey passed the House of Representatives narrowly by 219 to 212 in June, the ETS bill is now stalled in legislative limbo.

There are many reasons for the changing political atmosphere in the US.  The global financial crisis has pushed green policies further down the political agenda.  Saving the economy and creating jobs takes priority in a nation with double-digit unemployment.  Meanwhile, healthcare is dominating the Senate's agenda, while the issue of troop increases to Afghanistan preoccupies the White House.  Moreover, just as this week's Lowy poll highlighted shifting Australian attitudes towards climate change, US polls are increasingly showing more American scepticism of man-made global warming.

So spare a thought for Malcolm Turnbull.  The Fourth Estate devotes more effort to emissions trading than the US media.  But, as we witnessed again this week, it subjects the Liberal leader and his colleagues to far more scrutiny than it does to the Prime Minister, whose legislation is what really matters.  And its treatment of the proposed all-important US laws, upon which any prudent Australian government should base its climate change response, is virtually non-existent.


ADVERTISEMENT

Wednesday, October 21, 2009

What's the problem with a little logo when you're helping a child learn?

Should the corporate sector be involved in supporting childhood education?  It seems that some are more fearful of company logos than improving our schooling system.

The latest furore over big corporate getting involved in schools centres around a free maths online tutoring program sponsored by McDonald's.  With a membership of half a million Australian students, the program provides students with a range of numeracy exercises.

The number of students in advanced maths is falling, and more young people are arriving at universities mathematically challenged.

The latest NAPLAN testing results show a mixed performance across the states and territories for students achieving agreed numeracy benchmarks.

Yet the concern somehow is focused on company logos and the impact of them on children.  These concerns overlook the role that the private sector and non-government organisations play daily in helping our young people to learn.

In fact, one of the great strengths of Australian education is its diverse mix of service delivery and funding.  About 34 per cent of students are educated by not-for-profit Catholic and independent schools.

With the cost of public education growing over time, the availability of a non-government alternative lifts a potentially great fiscal weight off the shoulders of taxpayers.

From feeding the students their daily bread right through to providing the latest laptop technology on their desks, corporations provide a vast array of ancillary products and services.

The proponents of public education at best routinely ignore this beneficial corporate role.

McDonald's and many other private enterprises have taken an interest in children because it is an effective way of being good corporate citizens.

For instance, the Ronald McDonald house provides free accommodation for families with sick children in hospitals and also provides tailored tuition for children who have missed school owing to illness.

The critics argue companies like McDonald's should not be permitted to provide a free maths online tutoring program because they sell cheeseburgers, French fries and fizzy drinks.

From this perspective, the concern is about what the corporate is selling rather than what they are giving.

The difficulty with this is how far should one take the argument?  For example, should all participants in the food industry be banned from sponsoring school education?

If the company that made the wrappers for the Big Mac offered to provide our children with free online education in exchange for advertisement would we also turn them away?

For decades various advocates have pressured companies to become more socially responsible entities.  Yet at the first instance they attempt to do just that they get pilloried from all comers.

The risk is that such criticism will lead potential corporate sponsors to become less inclined to fund education or other community initiatives.  This is not in the best interests of the community.

A cursory glance at the maths online website shows that it is not a free-for-all in terms of access.  Parents play the gatekeeping role of registering their children at the outset.

Nor is the site an advertising blitz.  The corporate logo is inconspicuous compared to the wealth of mathematical instruction provided by the site.

If anything there's a trade-off between students seeing a small pithy logo on the login page for a matter of seconds in exchange for entire sessions of maths tutoring with the prospect of providing years of benefits.

Even if the site was plastered with food advertisements, there is no guarantee that users would switch off their PCs and buy Big Macs.  After all, a burgeoning literature in economic psychology suggests that children are economic sophisticates who discriminate against brands and products repeatedly.

The notion that corporate involvement in education is nothing but a ruse to sell products also gives parents insufficient credit for their role in determining what products land on the kitchen table or in their homes.

Corporate sponsorship provides funding and support for programs in flexible ways that governments cannot.  Governments have been notoriously slow at reversing the decline in mathematics education in schools, and so other players creatively step in to fill the breach.

In these times of deficit budgets, governments find themselves in a position where they cannot fund everything.

It is for these reasons that we should welcome company sponsorship that leverages taxpayer funds for a better education for young Australians.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, October 20, 2009

Forecast against plain sailing

Climate change dominates Australian politics.  So much so that, to avoid the prospect of an early election, Malcolm Turnbull has convinced his Coalition colleagues to back amendments to Labor's Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme.

In the US, however, climate change is not such a high priority.

A bill to implement an emissions trading scheme is stalled in legislative limbo, with Democrat and Republican senators from industrial states concerned about the likelihood of higher energy prices, and lost coal and manufacturing jobs.

The media coverage of climate change reflects the different political priorities of Canberra and Washington.  Measured by print copy and air time, there is much more reporting and commentary about what Kevin Rudd calls "the great economic, environmental and moral challenge of our time" in Australia than in the US.  A comprehensive search of newspaper articles on emissions trading (or "cap and trade", as the Americans call it) from January 1 to last week reveals a yawning gap between the two nations.

The Australian, The Australian Financial Review, The Age and The Sydney Morning Herald have altogether published 1030 news articles, editorials and opinion pieces on the ETS this year.  By contrast, The New York Times, Wall Street Journal, Washington Post and Los Angeles Times have altogether published only 266 news articles, editorials and opinion pieces.  That is a proportion of almost four to one.

Type in climate change and the disparity between the Australian and American press coverage is just as wide.  This year, The Australian has published 20 editorials on emissions trading;  The New York Times has editorialised on the subject only five times.  It's the same story with respect to radio and television.

Hardly a day goes by without the ABC or Sky News airing a news or current affairs segment on the ETS.  The major networks in the US hardly touch the subject.

Why is the political atmosphere in the two nations so different?  And why is the Canberra press gallery far more focused on climate change than the Washington press corps?  After all, as last week's Lowy Institute poll showed, less than half of Australians consider global warming a serious and pressing problem, and climate change ranked seventh in a list of 10 "most important" foreign policy priorities, down from first only two years ago.

In Australia, the political battle over the ETS is such headline-grabbing copy because of its impact on the opposition leadership and election prospects.  Coalition disunity has dogged the leaderships of Brendan Nelson and Turnbull over the past 18 months.  And the trigger for an early election in the form of a double dissolution depends on whether the opposition rejects Labor's CPRS next month.

Not surprisingly, most of the Australian media coverage of the ETS centres on Coalition divisions, specifically over whether to legislate the scheme before the Copenhagen climate conference in December.

In Washington, the global financial crisis has demoted the environment to a second-order issue.  Saving the economy and creating jobs takes priority in a nation suffering from double-digit unemployment.  Healthcare is dominating the congressional agenda while the issue of troop increases to Afghanistan preoccupies the White House.  Meanwhile, several recent opinion polls show the highest level of public scepticism about man-made global warming in more than a decade.

All of this means that the prospect of a US law to cut carbon emissions before the Copenhagen conference is rapidly approaching zero.  Why is this important for Australia?  Because if there is no clear leadership from Washington, the UN post-Kyoto climate talks in December will flounder and Australia will be out on a limb.  And that is not in our national interest.


ADVERTISEMENT

The nanny state will nag you to death

This week parliament will debate a bill to establish a national Preventive Health Agency, reminding of that classic Mark Twain observation:  nobody is safe while the legislature is in session.

On The Punch Federal health minister Nicola Roxon insisted that she was no nanny statist, and that the purpose of the Agency was about saving lives and reducing health costs.

Most modern governments understand the follies of outright bans, such as the failed US Prohibition movement from 1919 to 1933.  However, the Agency plans what it sees as the next best thing.

With a total budget of $133 million over four years, it intends to tax and regulate your booze, ciggies and fast food that it's more expensive or harder to get.

Minister Roxon denies that the Agency will embark on a nagging agenda.  However it plans to spend $2 million this financial year on marketing campaigns about stuff you know already.  (Really?  Over-indulging in junk food has health consequences?)

So if that's not nagging, then exactly what is it?

The following year, in 2010-11, the proposed Agency intends to go into a healthy living ad campaign overdrive with the marketing budget lifted to $33.8 million.

That would represent a seventeen-fold increase in taxpayer-financed spending devoted to hectoring and cajoling you to skip your Friday night pizza and Tim Tams with coffee.

The other element of the Preventive Health Agency is more money, or $13 million over four years, thrown at what the Minister describes as translating research into practice.

What that essentially means is new opportunities for public health boffins to get out of universities and into plush government secondments.

Once this occurs, they will be set the task of writing a stack of papers about ingenious ways to nudge people into a ciggie-free, teetotalling life with no hamburgers or Mars Bars.

Those tasks pretty much amount to what the public health lobby do already, except that poor Joe (or Joanne) Average get slugged with a tax bill for the privilege.

It can also be argued that there are more effective research paths to help improve our health and life expectancy.

Think of the serious, cutting-edge research and development into new drugs by pharmaceutical companies that often require billions of dollars but promise massive payoffs.

One should take the assurances of the Minister and the public health lobby that the costs of the Preventive Health Agency are small, and will always be small, with grains if not buckets of salt.

The Bill being debated in parliament states that the Agency must develop triennial year strategic plans for health improvement, backed by annual plans relating to the strategic plan.

These plans present an open-ended recipe for a fiscal cost blowout.  They rely, in part, on state governments and other entities being able to deliver desired preventive health outcomes on behalf of the federal government.

If the Minister or her senior bureaucrats feel that the plans are ineffective, or that the pace of health improvement is too slow for their liking, then even more dollops of funding will likely go to the Agency.

Minister Roxon likes to portray her critics as a hysterical bunch that cares little about the desirability of good health.  The Minister can continue to trumpet this line at her political peril.

A recent analysis of media coverage of the Preventative Health Taskforce, which will surely inspire the activities of the proposed Agency, shows that public opinion was overwhelmingly against greater paternalism in health.

Average Australians that responded to the Taskforce report expressed concern about potential increases in taxes and regulations, as well as infringement on civil liberties.

The Minister may protest that the Agency will not ban goods seen as unhealthy, but will instead seek to nudge people towards a healthier path to living.

Assuming that no Australian listens to the braying of the proposed nanny health agency, and goes on eating, drinking and smoking as before, there will still be significant costs imposed.

This is because, no matter what we do, we won't be able to avoid increased taxes on alcohol, tobacco and fast foods if they come to light.

We won't be able to avoid the pain of higher prices at the checkout as businesses are forced to pass on the costs of more intrusive regulations.

Australians certainly won't be able to bypass the fiscal burden of paying for Preventive Health Agency administration.

Whichever way one looks at it, Nanny Nicola is coming to a bottle shop, takeaway food bar and tobacco retail outlet near you if the legislation passes.

Monday, October 19, 2009

Fat pay packets for state public employees unsustainable

State and territory governments will surely welcome recent news of a national economic recovery.  A stronger economy will mean additional revenue inflows into treasury coffers, meaning that states might be saved from the fiscal consequences of their spending profligacy.

The risk is that such a revenue-driven reduction in net state budget deficits, standing at $2.9 billion this financial year on the latest projections, may gloss over growing costs that states have found difficult to control.

The largest element of state government operating budgets is their expenditures on public servant wages, superannuation and other entitlements.  In 2008-09, states allocated more than $78bn towards gross employee expenses, representing about 46 per cent of total general government sector spending.

By comparison, $43bn was spent for the same purposes in 2000-01.  This implies an increase in spending on state public sector workers of 78 per cent over the period, or an average of 8 per cent a year.

This increase in state spending on labour inputs is driven by two main factors:  changes in the numbers of people employed by state government agencies and other bodies; and changes in salaries and other benefits paid out to these public servants.

After a period of reduction in the number of state government employees during the 1990s, state public services increased substantially during the recent economic boom.  In 2000, there were about 972,000 people on the state government payroll.  By 2008, this had risen to about 1.2 million.

Victoria led the way in expanding the bureaucracy in percentage terms, with an increase in the total number of public servants of 37 per cent.  NSW, South Australia, Tasmania and the Northern Territory each recorded growth of about 25 per cent or more.

The largest increase in state government staffing was in the area of administration, which grew by at least 57 per cent between 2000 and 2007.  There is additional evidence to suggest an increase in the numbers of administrators engaged in service delivery areas such as education, health and policing.

There have been even more dramatic increases in state public sector salaries and entitlements in recent years.

Adjusting for higher education sector staff earnings, it is possible to calculate an implied amount of gross earnings for each state government employee.  From 2000 to 2006, gross earnings per employee grew by 4 per cent a year on average.  This is above the Reserve Bank of Australia's inflation target band of 2 per cent to 3 per cent.  Rising salaries for state public servants, even after accounting for the overall growth in government employment, suggest the increases in overall employee expenses were mainly attributable to public service pay increases during the peak of the previous business cycle.

The seemingly inexorable rise in state government employee expenses proved unsustainable in the light of the combined budget deficit position of the states and territories.  A return to fiscal sustainability by the states will require a discipline in controlling spending on labour costs not witnessed in previous years.

Governments have recently announced restraint measures such as caps on public service numbers, voluntary redundancies, a freeze on non-frontline staff recruitment and wage growth targets.

These measures constitute an implicit acknowledgment by the states that action needs to be taken to control bureaucratic costs.  The big question is whether existing initiatives will be sufficient for the task.

It is possible to derive estimates of the additional revenue needed by the states to fund their public service costs, over and above that implied by their publicly stated wages policies.  During the next four years, it is estimated that taxpayers will need to pay an additional $15.6bn to cover state government employee expenses above wage policy benchmarks.  To put this figure into perspective, the aggregate amount of payroll tax revenue collected by state governments last financial year was about $16.5bn.  In effect, the states will be approaching taxpayers seeking another payroll tax to subsidise extra public servants and their salary costs.

With signs of life evident in the Australian economy, state governments may be tempted to pull back on the need to pare back their labour costs.  Public sector unions are more likely to pursue inflationary wage claims if they perceive state revenue growth to be on the increase.

The obvious problem with this "business as usual" scenario is that it would not address the underlying causes of expenditure growth that contributed to the state fiscal crisis in the first place.

Additional measures could be pursued by governments to reduce the likelihood that public sector employment costs would erode state budgets in the future.

State governments should consider a mechanism enshrined in certified agreements whereby public servant salary growth is paused when budgets are in deficit.  Wages policies could also be legislated.  Governments that intend to relax the policy should be obliged to publicly report on productivity improvements attained by their workers.

Public sector caps are an appropriate mechanism to help restrain the overall costs of government employment, provided they are backed by appropriate enforcement mechanisms.  Ministers and senior officials that oversee breaches in a cap should be liable to some form of sanction.

A return to the reforming spirit of the 90s at the state level, through the devolution of key service delivery functions to private or non-profit organisations, would save taxpayers the burden of supporting a large public sector.

It is important that a recovering economy not lull states into a false sense of fiscal security.  The price of a lack of reform putting government employment on a sustainable footing is an eventual re-run of the difficulties that jurisdictions are facing at present.


ADVERTISEMENT

A growing risk:  The impacts and consequences of rising state government employment

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  • An inability to manage expenses, particularly with regard to labour inputs, is a key cause of the budgetary straightjacket now being worn by state and territory governments.
  • In fact, the largest single element of operating expenditure by states relates to the employment and remuneration of public sector employees.
  • Since the economic reforms of the 1990s, state governments have significantly increased their workforces.  The total number of workers employed by the states has jumped from 972,300 in 2000 to 1.2 million in 2008 -- an increase of about 28 per cent over the period.
  • The greatest increase in total state public sector staffing has been in the area of government administration.  There is also evidence of growth in "back office" staff in the key service delivery areas of education, health and policing.
  • State government public servants have been the beneficiaries of increasing salaries and other pecuniary benefits.
  • Gross earnings per state employee have grown strongly during the recent economic boom, with average pay increases exceeding those enjoyed by private sector workers.
  • There is insufficient evidence that the growth in state bureaucracies have yielded commensurate improvements in service delivery outcomes.
  • Taxpayers have borne the financial brunt of these unsustainable trends, with state general government sector employee expenses rising from $43.3 billion in 2000-01 to $77.1 billion in 2007-08 -- an average annual increase of almost nine per cent over the period.
  • Continuing growth in state government bills for bureaucrats and public servants has significant national economic implications.
  • Individuals and businesses will have to pay additional state revenues supporting extra government employment and wages, crippling the capacity of the private sector to employ, invest and grow in the short to medium term.
  • State taxpayers will be forced to pay at least an additional $15.6 billion over the forward estimates period to fund public service costs, over and above that implied by existing state wages policies.  This additional fiscal burden is broadly equivalent to the entire state payroll tax revenue take in 2008-09.
  • A more regulated national industrial relations system is likely to increase the risk of public sector wage rises spilling over into the private sector, putting upwards pressure on interest rates and curbing economic growth.
  • States face a significant credibility problem in repairing their budgets, as announced measures to curb government employment and labour costs are unlikely to be effective.
  • Stronger policy measures need to be put in place to restrain the fiscal costs of state government employment.
  • Suggested policies include:  a statutory wage pause during budget deficit periods;  stronger wages policies backed by legislation and public reporting of public sector productivity improvements;  ceilings on the size of government employment backed by appropriate enforcement;  and a public sector reform agenda focussed on core service provision.

1. BUDGET BREAKERS:  WHAT ARE THE
RISKS OF GREATER PUBLIC EMPLOYMENT
AND HIGHER WAGES FOR STATE BUDGETS?

Despite signs of a national economic recovery, the budget position of the states and territories remain in dire straits.  Their inability to manage their own expenses is a key cause of the problem.

At the time of writing, the states expect to post a net $2.9 billion general government budget deficit this financial year.  Queensland's deficit of over $1.9 billion alone accounts for the bulk of the total.  The states are also projecting general government net debt totalling $13.2 billion in 2009-10, compared to an overall negative net debt position during the previous year.

Despite the claims of state treasurers that recent declines in revenue growth driven by the Wall Street meltdown are the cause of their parlous budgetary position, the unprecedented and continuous growth in expenses has played the pivotal role in the recent fiscal deterioration.

According to figures published in state budget papers, annual general government sector expenditure growth began to outstrip growth in state revenues (including commonwealth grants) through the recent commodity boom (Figure 1).  When this trend occurs on a consistent basis -- as it has for the states and territories -- budget deficits surely follow.

In 2008-09, state expenses grew by nine per cent compared to a six per cent rise in total general government revenue.  Spending growth is expected to outstrip revenue growth again this financial year, aggravating the combined budget deficit position of the states and territories.

Figure 1:  Annual growth in state and territory general government sector revenues and expenses

Figures are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  State and territory government budget papers.


The largest single element of expenditure at the state level are those associated with the employment and remuneration of public sector employees.  In 2008-09, states and territories allocated over $78 billion towards gross employee expenses representing about 46 per cent of total general government budget expenditure.

By comparison, $43 billion was spent for the same purposes in 2000-01 (44 per cent of spending).  This represents an increase in expenditure of 78 per cent over the period, or an average of eight per cent per annum.

Most jurisdictions have enunciated a path back to budget sustainability over the period to 2012-13.  By the end of the forward estimates, all states and territories except Queensland, Western Australia and the ACT are expecting a return to budget surplus.

However, the states' ability to return budgets into the black will crucially depend upon them successfully restraining their own spending.  This will require a discipline not witnessed in recent years to contain the growth of spending on public sector employees.

There are already signs to suggest that jurisdictions will face significant difficulties in meeting this important fiscal consolidation objective.

Public sector unions are vigorously campaigning to lift wages for their members well in excess of expected inflation outcomes and formal government wages policies.  This means a substantial redistribution of income from state taxpayers to state government employees.

For example, proceedings in the South Australian Industrial Relations Commission are underway regarding a pay dispute between the Rann government and teachers and TAFE lecturers.

The Australian Education Union has called for a 21 per cent pay rise over three years in that state, a claim significantly greater than the government's 14 per cent offer for classroom teachers. (1)

The Queensland Industrial Relations Commission recently granted government school teachers an interim four per cent pay increase, an outcome claimed by the Queensland Teachers' Union (QTU) as being insufficient. (2)

The Bligh government and the QTU remain in arbitration over a long-running pay dispute, after the QTU rejected a 12.5 per cent pay offer over three years. (3)  The union has engaged in a rolling campaign of strike action and work bans that have impeded the flow of federal funding to school students in disadvantaged communities. (4)

In New South Wales, pay negotiations between the Police Association and the Rees government delivered an eight per cent pay rise over two years for the state's police force.  This is in excess of the government's wages policy of an increase of only 2.5 per cent per annum. (5)

The larger states are effectively conceding that growth in general government sector salary payments (including for existing agreements) will exceed their enunciated wages targets (Figure 2).

With elections due in South Australia, Victoria and Tasmania next year, and NSW in 2011, wages are likely to rise over and beyond that forecast for those states as governments seek to placate union pay demands across key areas of services delivery. (6)

Figure 2:  Expected average growth in state general government sector employee expenses,
2009-10 to 2012-13

Excluding superannuation expenses.  It is assumed that the 2009-10 wages policy for NSW, Victoria, Queensland and South Australia will remain constant over the forward estimates period.  Data for Western Australia is based on figures applicable for the three-year period 2009-10 to 2011-12.  Data for employee expenses includes the effect of wage increases under existing agreements as at the time of 2009-10 state budgets.  Figures are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  State and territory government budget papers.


In South Australia and Tasmania, public sector unions have criticised moves by their respective governments to reduce numbers of agency staff in non-core services.  In Queensland, unions are resisting initiatives by the Bligh government to privatise some existing government trading enterprises, with similar protests occurring in New South Wales.

Actions by state governments have important consequences for the national economy.  For example, state government employee expenses have to be financed by state taxes and other revenue sources which impose significant efficiency costs on individuals and businesses.

State efforts to acquire additional revenues to fund more, and better paid, public servants will come at the significant risk of dampening investment, employment and other productive activities at a time of weakness in the private sector.

It is possible to derive indicative estimates of the additional revenue to be taken by the states to fund their public service costs, over and above those implied under stated wages policies (Figure 3).

Over the next four years, taxpayers will be expected to pay state treasuries an additional $15.6 billion to cover these expenses.  To put this amount into perspective, the aggregate amount of payroll tax revenue collected by state governments was in the order of $16.5 billion in 2008-09.

Figure 3:  Expected cumulative growth in state general government sector employee expenses,
2009-10 to 2012-13

Excluding superannuation expenses.  Excluding the Australian Capital Territory and Northern Territory.  It is assumed that the 2009-10 wages policy for NSW, Victoria, Queensland and South Australia will remain constant over the forward estimates period.  Data for Western Australia is based on figures applicable for the three-year period 2009-10 to 2011-12.  Data for employee expenses include the effect of wage increases under existing agreements as at the time of 2009-10 state budgets.  Figures are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  State government budget papers.


Further, significant wage increases granted to workers in the state public sector could spark similar claims for compensation in the private sector.  This is a more likely prospect in a national industrial relations system more conducive to pattern bargaining across sectors.

Private sector wage rises that follow those in the public sector could stoke inflationary pressures in the economy, leading to interest rate hikes that increase the cost of home-lending and of capital more generally.

Risk statements published in most state and territory budgets highlight the potential of rising expenses due to growing public sector employment.  However, watching and writing about the problem is an insufficient substitute for real action to keep these costs in check.

To ensure that public service costs do not become the budget breaker of state governments, a range of complementary reforms should be implemented:

  • State governments in deficit positions should institute a wage pause until their budgets return to balance or surplus.
  • Governments could legislate to maintain a formal wages policy.  Any relaxation of the remuneration growth cap should be justified by governments publicly reporting on productivity improvements attained by their workers.
  • Governments should pursue upper limit ceilings on the number of workers to be employed in the public sector.  Ministers and senior officials that oversee breaches in the ceiling by a given agency should be liable for sanction.
  • Measures should be undertaken to restrict the scope of state governments to core services only -- such as funding education and health care, keeping streets and communities safe, and contributing toward infrastructure development -- and commensurately cutting taxes to boost private sector employment opportunities.  Any upper limit public sector cap should be amended downwards to take account of the reform process.

It should be emphasised that these measures, necessarily of a transitional nature, would help ensure that the private sector has the capacity to absorb more employees that would otherwise be hired by state governments.

The recent growth of the state public sectors proved to be unsustainable in light of the recent economic downturn.  The need for states to now take a more disciplined approach toward public sector employment and remuneration will be vital to Australia's chances of a strong economic recovery.

Rather than wait for the cavalry of economic growth to arrive, the states need to take real policy action that relieves the community of the toxic mix of budget deficits and public sector debt.  To help achieve this, governments must now reduce the overhang of recurrent expenditure.

Ensuring that the size of state public employment, and the remuneration and other benefits paid out to government workers become sustainable is essential to the task which lies ahead.


2. EMPIRE BUILDING:  HOW HAS STATE AND TERRITORY
PUBLIC EMPLOYMENT GROWN OVER THE YEARS?

State and territory governments employ workers to deliver certain services.  They include police officers, fire fighters and paramedics, judges for local and state-wide courts, teachers in government schools, and doctors and nurses in public hospitals.

States also employ bureaucrats in central and regional offices to administer the varied operations of, and to enforce rules set down by, governments.


2.1 WHAT HAVE BEEN THE LONG TERM TRENDS IN STATE PUBLIC SERVANT NUMBERS?

Until the publication of a new statistical series for 2007-08, the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) provided a historical time series on the total number of wage and salary earners engaged by the states.  This headcount data included information applicable to the general government sector, government trading enterprises and other instrumentalities. (7)

Figure 3 illustrates the level of state public sector employment in each jurisdiction from 1990, after adjusting for the number of workers in the higher education sector. (8)

Figure 3:  Number of state and territory total public sector employees

Data for state public sector workers as at February of each year, less tertiary education sector employees (data as at March of each year).  The data used in this figure are of an indicative nature.

Source:  ABS, Wage and Salary Earners, Public Sector, Australia;
DEEWR, Selected Higher Education Statistics.


The first half of the time series presented in figure 3 is exemplified by a policy trend whereby all states (except Queensland) reduced their employee numbers, as part of a broader program of fiscal consolidation and economic reform.

The number of state public servants across Australia declined from a peak of about 1.08 million in 1990 to about 941,500 in 1997.  Victoria reduced the number of its public sector employees by about 97,800 over the period, followed by South Australia (22,600), NSW (15,700), WA (10,600) and Tasmania (6,100).

A breakdown of state government employment by industry classification over that period shows that the employment reduction primarily occurred in either privatised industries, such as electricity, gas and water and transport, or in those with relatively close market substitutes such as property and business services and construction (Figure 4).

However, the breadth of rationalisation of state public sector employment during the 1990s was uneven with the numbers of staff in areas such as health, education and government administration trending upwards.

Figure 4:  Number of state and territory total public sector employees, industry classification

Data for state public sector workers as at February of each year.  Staff employed in education sector adjusted for numbers of tertiary education sector employees (data as at March of each year).  Data for each industry classification, except government administration, includes service delivery and administrative staff relevant to given industry.  The data used in this figure are of an indicative nature.

Source:  ABS, Wage and Salary Earners, Public Sector, Australia;
DEEWR, Selected Higher Education Statistics.


2.2 HOW HAS STATE PUBLIC SERVICE NUMBERS CHANGED IN RECENT YEARS?

Since that reform period, state governments have sought to increase their workforces.  The total number of workers employed by jurisdictions rose from about 972,300 in 2000 to about 1.2 million in 2008 -- the highest level for almost two decades.

In contrast to its workforce management stance during the 1990s, Victoria has undertaken the largest percentage increase in state government employment over the past eight years (Figure 5).  The total number of public servants in that state alone increased from about 197,400 in 2000 to about 270,000 in 2008 -- or 36.8 per cent over the period.

The Northern Territory (36.7 per cent), Western Australia (30.9 per cent), Tasmania (28.6 per cent) and South Australia (27.7 per cent) have also significantly increased their state government workforces.  Levels of state public sector employment have risen by at least 16 per cent over the past eight years.

Figure 5:  Number of state and territory total public sector employees, index values

Index values derived from data for state public sector workers as at February of each year, less tertiary education sector employees (data as at March of each year).  Index value for 2000 set at 100.  The data used in this figure are of an indicative nature.

Source:  ABS, Wage and Salary Earners, Public Sector, Australia;
DEEWR, Selected Higher Education Statistics.


The recent growth trend highlighted by the ABS is confirmed by self-enumerated employment data published by states for their general government sectors (Figure 6). (9)  The greatest increases occurred in the larger jurisdictions, with Victoria increasing its state public sector staff numbers by about 60,400 between 2000 and 2008, followed by NSW (54,300) and Queensland (45,200).

Figure 6:  Number of state and territory general government sector employees

Data for New South Wales in 2000 derived by applying FTE share of budget dependent agency staffing to total headcount statistic as at June 2000.  Employment data for South Australia in 2008 not publicly available at the time of writing.  The data used in this figure are of an indicative nature.

Source:  State and territory commissions/offices of public employment.


According to ABS data, the greatest increase in total state staffing has been in the area of government administration (Figure 7).  As at February 2007, 156,800 people worked in state and territory administration compared to 99,700 in 2000 -- an increase of 57 per cent over the period. (10)

State government administration personnel grew from 9.5 per cent of the total number of public sector employees to 13 per cent over the period.

Figure 7:  Change in the number of state and territory total public sector employees,
2000 to 2007

Data for state public sector workers as at February of each year.  Numbers employed in education sector adjusted for numbers of tertiary education sector employees (data as at March of each year).  Data for each industry classification, except government administration, includes service delivery and administrative staff relevant to given industry.  The data used in this figure are of an indicative nature.

Source:  ABS, Wage and Salary Earners, Public Sector, Australia;
DEEWR, Selected Higher Education Statistics.


There is some evidence to suggest that the share of administrative staff have increased in the key service delivery areas of education, health and policing (Box 1).

Box 1:  Growing administration in key state government service delivery areas

The employment of administrative staff, commonly known as bureaucrats, is important for a functioning system of government under the rule of law.  Indeed, a competent and professional bureaucracy is necessary to ensure provision of a limited set of pure public goods by government, which cannot be provided through competitive markets as guided by the profit-and-loss mechanism.

However, it is entirely possible that bureaucracy can, and often does, grow beyond its useful minimum size.  The American public choice scholar Gordon Tullock described the situation where government administration grows outside of limited bounds as "bureaucratic free enterprise."

This is a situation whereby "the bureaucracy will do things, will take actions, not because such actions are desired by the ultimate authority, the centre of power, in the organization, but because such things, such actions, develop as an outgrowth of the bureaucracy's own processes."

The British historian and essayist C. Northcote Parkinson explained in 1955 that there exist inherent incentives for bureaucracies to expand without necessity over time.  Drawing upon the experience of the British defence system, Parkinson outlined a law whereby "work expands so as to fill the time available for its completion" together with growth in the number of employed administrators.

Similarly, in the specific context of health care, British physician Max Gammon described a process whereby administrative effort tends to displace frontline service provision as funding increases:  in "a bureaucratic system ... increase in expenditure will be matched by fall in production. ... Such systems will act rather like 'black holes' in the economic universe, simultaneously sucking in resources, and shrinking in terms of 'emitted' production."

Importantly, Gammon also explained that "bureaucratic displacement is a disorder which is not confined to designated administrative staff;  it involves all members of the organisation."  This occurs when time that could be otherwise used by service delivery staff to directly address client needs is displaced by red tape and administrative tasks.

Putting aside Gammon's red tape displacement effect affecting service delivery personnel, there is some evidence of an increase in the relative share of administrative staff in areas such as education, health and policing in recent years.

Education

According to the MCEECDYA National Report on Schooling, the proportion of non-teaching positions in government schools across Australia has increased from 27 per cent in 2000 to 30 per cent in 2007.  This trend occurred in every jurisdiction except Queensland.  Over the same period, the number of government schools nationally declined by two per cent.

There is evidence of similar trends presented in self-enumerated data by some jurisdictions.  In Western Australia, the proportion of administrative and clerical staff in the Department of Education and Training increased between 2000-01 and 2007-08.

In Tasmania, the absolute number of teachers declined from 5,023 FTE (as at 30 June 2000) to 4,871 FTE (30 June 2008) while the overall number of staff in the Education Department increased over the same period.

Health

The AIHW National Hospital Statistics series shows that the share of administrative and clerical staff in public hospitals nationally has increased slightly between 2000-01 and 2007-08.  This trend coincides with a reduction in the number of public acute hospital beds (per 1,000 population) between 1996 and 2006.

Information on health district staffing provided by Queensland Health shows an increase in the proportion of managerial and clerical staff in that state over the course of this decade.  Similar trends are revealed in departmental annual reports over the past few years.

The former head of the Bundaberg Hospital Commission of Inquiry, Anthony Morris QC, submitted to a federal parliamentary inquiry in 2005 that "only 20% of the Department's employees (totalling some 64,000) are doctors or nurses:  for every clinician who actually deals with patients, there are four other employees who have to justify their existence within Queensland Health."

Similar trends were also recorded in recent years for Western Australia, Tasmania and the Northern Territory.

Policing

The Productivity Commission's Report on Government Service Provision provides information on the share of operational and non-operational staff in state and territory police forces.

According to data published by the commission, the proportion of non-operational staff has increased since 2000-01 for Western Australia, South Australia and the ACT, and since 2001-02 for Victoria and Queensland.

In NSW the proportion of administrative staff in the police department, plus supporting ministerial officers, has increased slightly from 2003-04 to 2007-08.  In Victoria, the proportion of police and recruits in the total police department workforce has declined since 2004.  Similar trends were also recorded in Western Australia and South Australia.


Sources:

Australian Doctors Fund, 2005, " 'Gammon's Law of Bureaucratic Displacement' A note from Dr Max Gammon with some quotes from Milton Friedman", (accessed 23 September 2009);

Sinclair Davidson and Julie Novak, 2008, Sustaining Growth:  Reforms for Tasmanian Prosperity, Report for Tasmanian Chamber of Commerce and Industry (TCCI);

Milton and Rose Friedman, 1980, Free to Choose:  A Personal Statement, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York;

Anthony J.H. Morris QC, 2005, Submission to House of Representatives Standing Committee on Health and Ageing Inquiry into Health Funding;  C. Northcote Parkinson, "Parkinson's Law", (accessed 23 September 2009);

Jeremy Sammut, 2009, Why Public Hospitals are Overcrowded:  Ten Points for Policymakers, CIS Policy Monograph;

State and territory Departments of Education, Health and Police Annual Reports;  Gordon Tullock, 1965 (2005), The Politics of Bureaucracy, Liberty Fund Edition.


The significant expansion in public sector employment this decade has been the by-product of efforts by state administrations to overcome the expenditure "neglect" that allegedly took place during the 1990s.

However, as illustrated by figure 1 in the previous section, the spending approach by governments eventually led to significant budget shortfalls as expenditure growth outpaced the growth of revenue proceeds.


2.3 WHAT ARE STATES PLANNING TO DO TO REDUCE PUBLIC SERVICE GROWTH?

Now faced with the urgent need to restrain costs, a number of jurisdictions have announced measures to slow or reverse the growth of their public services:

  • In its 2008-09 mini-budget, the NSW government announced a 20 per cent reduction in the size of its senior executive service.  The government is also pursuing a staffing freeze for "non-frontline" services.
  • The Queensland government has indicated it intends to limit growth in its public sector workforce to "front line service delivery areas and targeted policy commitments", (11)
  • The Western Australian government introduced a full-time equivalent (FTE) ceiling across the general government sector, originally capped at 99,155 FTE staff for 2008-09.  It is also supporting the voluntary redundancies of up to 500 staff, as well as rationalising the existing number of government boards and committees.
  • In South Australia, the state government announced a reduction of 1,600 public service positions not directly involved in frontline service delivery from 2009-10 to 2011-12.  The government is also offering a targeted regime of voluntary separations from the public sector for a limited period.
  • The Tasmanian government is seeking a range of cost savings, such as a reduction in the number of senior executive officers and a review of middle management.  It has also introduced an "agency cost reduction requirement" policy entailing vacancy controls, early or phased-in retirements and targeted voluntary redundancies of 800 positions. (12)

Most jurisdictions have also announced a combination of whole-of-government efficiency dividends and discretionary expenditure savings.  Some states -- such as New South Wales, Queensland and Tasmania -- have outlined privatisation plans in areas such as electricity retail, forestry, lotteries, ports, rail networks and toll road operations.

These measures are already being met with strong opposition from public sector and other trade unions (Box 2).

Box 2:  Union reactions to state public sector rationalisation initiatives

With 42 per cent of (federal and state) public sector employees retaining union membership in 2008, compared to 14 per cent of private sector employees, public sector and other unions have a strong vested interest in the maintenance and expansion of state governments.  As stated in June 2009 by former NSW Treasurer Michael Costa, "unions scarcely exist in the private sector and rely on the expansion of public sector employment in key growth areas such as health and education to maintain any new membership."

This interest is typically invariant to the condition of state budgets prevailing at any given time.  Therefore, it is unsurprising that current initiatives by state governments to freeze or reduce the size of their public sectors have been almost universally opposed by the union movement.

NSW labour unions have voiced their strong opposition to a number of privatisation proposals.  For example, the Maritime Union has opposed the sale of Sydney Ferries arguing, without supporting evidence, that "a sale would result in inevitable ticket price rises and safety cut backs."

The Australian Manufacturing Workers Union secretary, Paul Bastian, warned the government that his union would be prepared "to go to the wall" on the Sydney ferries privatisation similar to its oppositional stance against electricity privatisation.

The NSW Public Service Association recently engaged Access Economics to help argue its case against reductions in state government operational spending, even in light of a NSW budget deficit of over $700 million.

In Queensland, the Council of Unions is coordinating a $400,000 campaign opposing the sale of public sector assets.  Complementing this are efforts by the Queensland Public Sector Union to force the state government to allow all workers in entities earmarked for privatisation to return to the public sector within a twelve month period, and at their existing operating level.

The Bligh government has responded to these pressures by appointing ex-Reserve Bank governor Bernie Fraser on a $2,500 per day retainer to negotiate asset sales with unions.

The Western Australian branch of the Community & Public Sector Union (CPSU) has argued that the state government's FTE ceiling and efficiency dividend policies will "massively" disrupt services.

It recently cited a reduction in the WA public service share of the total state labour force to support its case against government policy of expenditure restraint.  However, the total public sector grew by about 19 per cent from 1997 to 2007 compared to growth of the state population of about 17 per cent.


Sources:

ABS, Employee Earnings, Benefits and Trade Union Membership, Australia, cat. no. 6310.0;

Access Economics, 2009, New South Wales government services in the global financial crisis, Report for NSW Public Service Association, May;

Andrew Clennell and Brian Robins, 2009, "Pay rise delay to save Rees budget", The Sydney Morning Herald, 1 June;

Michael Costa, 2009, "Unions putting ALP into reverse", The Australian, 5 June;

Patrick Lion, 2009, "Bligh's $2500 a day peacemaker is Bernie Fraser", The Courier Mail, 26 September;

Maritime Union of Australia, 2009, "Sydney Ferry claims pure fiction", Media release, 22 May;

Imre Salusinszky, 2009, "Nathan Rees privatises NSW state lotteries", The Australian, 9 September;

Andrew West, 2009, "Business fears ALP deal to scupper ferry plan", The Sydney Morning Herald, 7 September.


How state governments respond to political pressures generated by unions and other vested interests, including the bureaucracy itself, will be critical in determining the overall success of current fiscal consolidation objectives.

However, there are some signs that governments are softening their initial positions regarding the need to reduce public sector staffing.

Pressure from public sector unions contributed to forcing NSW and Queensland to protect public sector positions during their respective processes of forming "mega-departments", (13) despite the clear opportunities presented by such reforms to secure meaningful efficiencies in the size and composition of staffing.

Trade unions in Queensland claim to have played a decisive role in the Bligh government's reversal of its intention to sell non-coal and non-suburban rail networks. (14)

Apart from political pressure exerted by special interests with a stake in rising state public sector employment, the present capacity of states to rationalise their employments are also being constrained by the need to adhere to joint federal and state agreements on services delivery. (15)

Given the parlous condition of state public finances, it is essential that states and territories at the very least deliver on their previously announced commitments and, as discussed below, explore additional avenues to rein in the size of public sector employment into the future.


3 PAY BOOM:  HOW HAVE STATE AND TERRITORY
GOVERNMENT EMPLOYEE WAGES AND ENTITLEMENTS
GROWN OVER THE YEARS?

The payment of wages and salaries, plus expenses associated with entitlements such as accrued leave and superannuation, also contributes to the recurrent costs incurred by state governments.


3.1 WHAT HAVE BEEN THE LONG TERM TRENDS IN STATE PUBLIC SERVICE WAGES AND ENTITLEMENTS?

The ABS series on public sector wage and salary earners, as used above, also provided consistent information on the gross earnings of state and territory government employees.

Adjusting for higher education sector staff earnings, it is possible to roughly calculate an implied average amount of gross earnings for each state employee.  From 1990 to 2006, gross earnings per state public servant across Australia increased at an average annual rate of about four per cent (Figure 8).

Figure 8:  Gross earnings per state and territory total public sector employee

Data for gross earnings for state public sector workers as of each calendar year, less gross earnings of workers employed in higher education sector.  Gross earnings data adjusted for numbers of state public sector workers (less higher education workers) as at February (March) of each year respectively.  The data used in this figure are of an indicative nature, and are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  ABS, Wage and Salary Earners, Public Sector, Australia;
DEEWR, Selected Higher Education Statistics.


Since 2000, Queensland has recorded the strongest growth in gross earnings per state public sector employee -- increasing from about $39,000 in 2000 to about $53,300 (or an average five per cent per annum).  This was followed by Tasmania (4.7 per cent), NSW (4.2 per cent), WA (four per cent) and the ACT (3.8 per cent).


3.2 HOW DO STATE PUBLIC SERVANT WAGES COMPARE WITH THE PRIVATE SECTOR?

ABS data on average weekly earnings allows some indirect comparisons to be made with regards to the growth in remuneration between the private and public sectors.  The available evidence suggests that government workers on average receive significantly greater remuneration, compared to their private sector counterparts. (16)

Excluding the territories, where commonwealth government employment predominate the public sector data in those jurisdictions, the available data reveals that public sector workers receive substantially more in earnings per week (up to 37 per cent in Tasmania) than their private sector counterparts except in the resources state of Western Australia (Figure 9).

Figure 9:  Private and public sector average total weekly earnings,
2007-08

Public sector includes workers in commonwealth and local governments.  The data used in this figure are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  ABS, Average Weekly Earnings, Australia, cat. no. 6302.0.


Changes in the ABS labour price index confirm that public sector remuneration in the states has risen at a faster pace than in the private sector over the course of this decade (Figure 10).

Figure 10:  Labour price index for private and public sectors

Public sector includes workers in commonwealth and local governments.  Index value for 2000-01 set at 100.

Source:  ABS, Labour Price Index, Australia, cat. no. 6345.0.


There is a considerable range in remuneration within state public sectors, with chief and senior executive officers receiving benefits typically well in excess of average earnings attained in the private sector (Box 3).

Box 3:  Profile of selected state government chief and senior executive services

One of the unintended consequences of recent accusations that private sector remuneration packages are "excessive" is that increasing public scrutiny has extended to issues surrounding benefits received by public sector employees.  Given the benefits of state government chief and senior executive officers are subsidised by taxpayers, including those on low incomes, such scrutiny can be reasonably justified on public interest grounds.

The NSW government employed 853 chief and senior executive officers as at 30 June 2008.  In its 2008-09 mini-budget the government announced a reduction in the number of senior executive service positions in the order of 20 per cent.  While this reduction target was achieved by mid-2009, the Department of Premier and Cabinet has stated that ten new SES positions will be created in 2009-10 due to the federal government stimulus program.

In its latest determination of CEO and senior executive salaries, the NSW Remuneration Tribunal recommended that the remuneration package for these public servants should be fixed in a range from $144,800 to $423,150.

In Victoria there were 635 contracted executive officers in the Victorian Public Service.  There are an additional 890 executives across government portfolio areas.  Chief executive officers of Victorian government agencies mainly earn from $100,000 to $260,000 per annum, excluding end of contract payments or bonuses.

According to media reports, Victorian senior executive staff received $6.2 million in bonuses during 2007-08.  Department of Human Services executives were reportedly paid about $1.02 million, followed by about $1 million to Treasury and Finance officials and $650,000 to officers in the Department of Transport.

In October 2009, the chief executive of the Western Australian Government Employees Superannuation Board (GESB) was reportedly granted a pay rise of $160,000 by the GESB board last year, increasing the CEO's salary from $370,000 to $530,000.  This is despite GESB posting a negative 11.4 per cent return on its investments last financial year.

In South Australia it has been estimated that the number of state public servants earning more than $100,000 per annum has increased from about 780 in 2002 to about 4,000 in 2007-08.  It has been reported that the chief executive of the Department of Premier and Cabinet earns approximately $130,000 more than Premier Mike Rann.

According to the 2007-08 Annual Report of the Tasmanian State Service Commissioner, there were 285 senior executive officers in the State Service including agency heads, senior executives, equivalent specialists and prescribed office holders.

In an examination of severance payments to senior public servants in Tasmania, the Auditor General found that payouts averaged $100,000 for departmental executives while those managing government business enterprises received an average of $500,000 in termination payouts.  The Auditor General expressed concern that "many severance payments did not have adequate documentation to determine which party had initiated termination of the employment contract, on what basis payments had been made or who had authorised them."

In the ACT it was estimated that there were 175 executive employees in the ACT Public Service at June 2008.  Male executives received an average salary of $154,238 while the average salary for female executives was $151,961.


Sources:

ACT Commissioner for Public Administration, 2008, 2007-08 ACT Public Service Workforce Profile;

Auditor-General Tasmania, 2008, Executive Termination Payments, Special Report No. 75;

Peter Kerr, 2009, "Super chief gets 23pc pay rise despite losses", The West Australian, 29 September;

Geraldine Mitchell and Stephen McMahon, 2009, "Huge payouts to bureaucrats running down Department of Human Services", The Herald-Sun, 3 July;

New South Wales Department of Premier and Cabinet, SES Reductions -- Progress Report (accessed 23 September 2009);

New South Wales Remuneration Tribunal, SES Determination November 2008 (accessed 23 September 2009);

Office of the State Service Commissioner Tasmania, 2008, Annual Report 2007-08;

Chris Pepper, 2009, "1000 more in PS top $100,000", Adelaide Advertiser, 22 February;

State Services Authority Victoria, 2009, The State of the Public Sector in Victoria 2007-08.


3.3 HOW HAVE STATE PUBLIC SERVICE WAGES AND ENTITLEMENTS CHANGED IN RECENT YEARS?

Drawing upon state government documentation, it is possible to consider the budgetary impact of changes in employee expenses over time.

Incorporating superannuation expenses, the costs of employing workers in the state and territory general government sector rose from $43.3 billion in 2000-01 to $77.1 billion in 2007-08 (figure 11).  This represented an average annual percentage increase of 8.6 per cent over the period -- well in excess of the average inflation rate of 4.6 per cent over the period.

Figure 11:  State and territory general government sector employee expenses

Figures are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  ABS;  state and territory government budget papers.


An analysis of state budget data reveals that governments expended an additional $74.7 billion on general government sector employee wages and other entitlements, over and above initial forecasts outlined in the budget documents (Figure 12).

Figure 12:  Actual versus forecast state and territory general
government sector employee expenses, 2000-01 to 2008-09

Figures are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  ABS;  State and territory budget papers.


This trend is illustrative of the states' failure to contain their own employment costs in key areas of service delivery, such as education (Box 4), health and policing, as they approve "catch up" wage deals for their public servants.  One explanation for this is provided by public choice theorists James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock:

The votes of bureaucrats would be partially directed toward expanding the size of their agencies and partially toward raising their own salaries. ... As agencies become larger, however, and the bureaucracy members come to make up a larger and larger share of the total voting constituency, the possibility of the usage of civil servant voting power to expand salaries directly becomes real. ... most democracies have passed the phase of expansion in the sheer size of bureaus and have now moved into the phase of expansion of bureaucratic salaries. (17)

As noted above, these actions have directly contributed to the significant growth in expenses precipitating the existing state budget crisis.

Box 4:  Recent state government pay deals with teacher unions

Teacher unions have engaged in rolling campaigns across the country to win inflationary pay rises from their respective state governments.

The latest round of teacher pay increases started in Victoria.  After a fourteen month campaign of pickets and stop-work periods, the Victorian government relented by providing an average 18 per cent pay increase over four years.  In return, the unions agreed to have teaching staff work an extra ten minutes per working day.

This decision, motivated by the desire to make Victoria's government school teachers the "best paid" in the country, sparked a zero-sum game bidding war by teacher unions in other states.

In one of its first decisions since attaining office, the Barnett government in Western Australia granted an immediate six per cent pay increase for teachers and school administrators.  In September 2008, Premier Colin Barnett stated that "the increase would make Western Australian teachers the highest paid in Australia."

This was on top of a record pay deal for teachers approved in July 2008 incorporating pay increases of between 16 and 22 per cent over three years.

The WA pay decision was followed by an agreement reached in NSW, where teachers received a 12 per cent pay increase over three years from the state government.

In two other states, governments and teachers unions are currently locked in arbitration over disputed pay increases.

The Queensland Teachers' Union (QTU) have rejected a 12.5 per cent pay offer from the Bligh government, on the basis that it will not enable its members to achieve pay parity with other jurisdictions.  QTU members have engaged in strike action, and imposed work bans on the implementation of the federal National Partnership agreement for low SES community schools.

The South Australian government and teacher unions are also engaged in an arbitration process.  The Australian Education Union (AEU) has sought a 21 per cent increase in pay over a three year period, compared to the Rann government's offer of 14 per cent for classroom teachers.  The union has sought an interim seven per cent pay rise.

While teacher unions across the states are coordinating campaigns in order to secure standardisation of wage conditions, irrespective of the differing cost-of-living circumstances in different states, they have represented a key stumbling block over the years against the merit pay schemes to attract and reward successful teachers.

In an opinion piece published in 2006, John McCollow of the AEU suggested that "there are ... a number of ways of increasing the financial attractiveness of teaching as a career.  One is a general increase in average teacher salaries."  It is also suggested, without support from survey or similar evidence, that teachers would prefer changes such as smaller class sizes or infrastructure improvements.

While settling wage disputes with public sector unions may win state politicians some temporary relief from otherwise politically damaging images of union discord, state taxpayers remain left to subsidise the pay increases while reform of the education system remains on the backburner.


Sources:

Andrew Burrell, 2008, "WA teachers get 6pc pay rise", The Australian Financial Review, 7 October;

John McCollow, 2006, Has Teacher Quality Declined and is "Merit Pay" the Answer? (accessed 23 September 2009);

Brad Norington and Milanda Rout, 2008, "Teachers' rise a risk to inflation", The Australian, 6 May;

Tracy Ong, 2008, "South Australian teachers want seven per cent interim pay rise", The Adelaide Advertiser, 2 October;

"States face $2.8bn jump in wage bill", The Australian Financial Review, 25 July.


3.3 WHAT ARE STATES PLANNING TO DO TO REDUCE PUBLIC SERVICE WAGES GROWTH?

States have outlined measures in an attempt to stem the fiscal haemorrhaging caused by continuous growth in employee expenses:

  • From September 2007, the NSW government has maintained a wages policy of 2.5 per cent (with wage rises above that amount to be offset by employee-related cost savings).
  • The Victorian government has revised down its wages policy from 3.25 per cent per annum increases to 2.5 per cent, with further increases in line with productivity improvements.
  • In Queensland, a new wages policy of 2.5 per cent per annum will apply until the state budget returns to surplus.  This policy applies to general agreements expiring after 31 December 2009, and from 1 July 2009 for chief and senior executives and senior officers. (18)
  • In Western Australia, a wages policy has been set for base wage increases of 2.5 per cent in 2009-10 and 2010-11, and three per cent in 2011-12.  Increases in wages above baseline growth to be justified by improved efficiency and work practice reforms.  The government has also closed its superannuation scheme defined benefit account to new members.
  • The South Australian government will implement a wages policy allowing for increases of up to 2.5 per cent each year.
  • The Tasmanian 2009-10 budget outlined a wage restraint policy for new agreements set at one per cent per annum in 2009-10 and 2010-11, and 2.5 per cent in 2011-12 and 2012-13.  It has also introduced a wages freeze limited to senior public service executives for a twelve month period. (19)

The ACT has a wages restraint policy that aims to achieve expenditure savings of up to $37 million by 2012-13, while in September 2009 the Northern Territory government recently announced a wages policy limiting increases to 2.5 per cent per annum.

Despite these announcements, information provided by the states and territories suggests that further action will be needed to appropriately restrain employee expenses.

While there are variations across the states and territories, the overall ratio of employee expenses to operating expenses is expected to continually increase over the forward estimates from 46 per cent to 48 per cent. (20)

Further, the larger states are effectively conceding that growth in general government employee expenses (including for existing agreements that were locked in during a more prosperous period) will exceed their enunciated baseline wages targets (Figure 13).

Figure 13:  Expected average growth in state general government sector employee expenses,
2009-10 to 2012-13

Excluding superannuation expenses.  It is assumed that the 2009-10 wages policy for NSW, Victoria, Queensland and South Australia will remain constant over the forward estimates period.  Data for Western Australia are based on figures applicable for the three-year period 2009-10 to 2011-12 only.  Data for employee expenses include the effect of wage increases under existing agreements as at the time of 2009-10 state budgets.  Figures are expressed in nominal terms.

Source:  State and territory government budget papers.


With elections due in South Australia and Tasmania next year wages are likely to rise over and beyond those ambitiously forecast by those states, as governments seek to placate union pay demands across key areas of services delivery. (21)

In South Australia, there are a number of pressure points for future public sector pay increases threatening the integrity of the stated wages policy.  As noted above, proceedings are continuing in the Industrial Relations Commission regarding an arbitrated award for teachers and TAFE lecturers.

According to the latest budget papers, pay negotiations in South Australia have also commenced with medical specialists and new agreements are expected this financial year for salaried employees, ambulance service employees and support staff for parliamentarians. (22)

The Tasmanian government has indicated that it may loosen its purse strings in the medium term by "restoring wage parity with comparable interstate occupational groups as a key objective when the Government has achieved its Interim Fiscal Strategy targets and the Budget has been returned to a sustainable position." (23)

Overall, salaries and other entitlements for state public servants have increased significantly even after accounting for the overall growth in state public sector employment.  In other words, the states' budget pressures are mainly attributable to the public service pay boom as governments exercised lax cost controls over salary and benefit growth.

The lamentable recent history of the states on the employee cost control front points to the need for the states to consider strong policy approaches managing public service costs, not to mention alternative strategies for enforcement of publicly stated commitments in this area.


4 MEAGRE RETURN:  ARE STATE TAXPAYERS
GETTING VALUE FOR MONEY FROM MORE
AND BETTER-PAID PUBLIC SERVANTS?

During the course of this decade governments have devoted significantly more taxpayer resources to a wide variety of services. (24)  From 2000-01 to 2007-08, states and territories spent $57.4 billion on service provision. (25)  About 58 per cent of the additional expenditure on services was directed towards education and health.  There were also significant increases in welfare and housing expenditure.

However, about $42.9 billion of the $57.4 billion increased spending on state services provision was used to cover higher operating expenses.  Increased labour costs accounted for two thirds or $28.3 billion of this rise in operating costs.

The key question that needs to be asked about the states' expenditure activities is whether or not it has delivered better performance and results?

It is difficult to estimate the productivity of government services, and caution should be applied when interpreting trends over time, however the available evidence suggests that the dramatic increase in state government spending has not been accompanied by equally dramatic performance improvements -- at least when it comes to two big-spending areas of education and health.


4.1 HOW ARE THE STATES PERFORMING IN THE DELIVERY OF SCHOOL EDUCATION?

Despite a significant increase in funding by the states towards school education, which in part has contributed to a marked reduction in student-staff ratios in schools, there is little evidence to suggest a sustained improvement in educational outcomes attained by students over the past few years.

Prior to 2008, states and territories conducted reading, writing and numeracy achievement benchmarking tests of students in Years 3, 5 and 7 under a national agreement.  Taking the results of Year 7 students as an example, it is evident that noticeable improvements were only recorded against tests of reading skills in NSW, writing skills in South Australia and numeracy skills in Victoria. (26)

Other test results show a decline in performance by students against agreed national test benchmarks over time.  Student numeracy skill test results were particularly concerning, with the proportion of Year 7 students meeting the national numeracy benchmark falling in Queensland (by 6.4 percentage points), NSW (5.8 per cent), the ACT (2.2 per cent) and Western Australia (0.3 per cent).

Since 2008, student tests for Years 3, 5, 7 and 9 have been conducted on the basis of the same test items in reading, writing, language conventions (spelling, grammar and punctuation) and numeracy.

According to the results of this National Assessment Program for Literacy and Numeracy (NAPLAN) methodology, test results for students have been mixed over the past two years.

New South Wales, Tasmania and the ACT (which has the highest educational expenditure per government school student in Australia) recorded reductions in the proportion of students achieving minimum standard benchmarks in at least half of the tests conducted in 2009, compared to the previous year.

Declines in the proportions of students achieving minimum national standards in Year 3 spelling and numeracy, Year 5 grammar and punctuation, Year 7 reading, spelling and numeracy and Year 9 reading and spelling were recorded in at least half of the eight jurisdictions in 2009, compared to 2008.

The results of other student testing methodologies are available on an internationally comparable basis.  The Trends in International Mathematics and Science Study (TIMSS) collects Years 4 and 8 achievement data in maths and science testing.

The 2007 results from TIMSS showed mixed results for Australia.  Year 4 students show some improvements in maths achievement, however Australia's ranking for Year 4 mathematics was below countries such as Hong Kong, Singapore, Japan, Kazakhstan, Russia, England, Latvia, Netherlands, Lithuania, United States and Germany. (27)  In addition, Australian Year 8 maths and Year 4 science achievement levels remained static yet there was a significant decline in science achievement for Year 8 students.

The OECD Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) also provides internationally comparable test results for scientific, reading and mathematical literacy.  The 2006 results indicate that there was still considerable scope to close the learning outcomes gap between individual states and the leading country in each test category (Table 2).

Table 2:  State and territory PISA mean test scores, 2006

ScienceMean
score
gap
ReadingMean
score
gap
MathematicsMean
score
gap
NSW535285193752326
Vic513505045251336
Qld522415094751930
WA543205243253118
SA532315144252029
Tas507564966050247
ACT549145352153910
NT490734609648168

The "mean score gap" is the difference between the mean test score for a given state and the mean test score for the leading country in each test category.  Countries with the highest mean scores in 2006 for each category were as follows:  science (Finland, 563);  reading (Korea, 556);  and mathematics (Taiwan, 549).

Source:  Sue Thomson and Lisa De Bortoli, 2008, Exploring scientific literacy:  how Australia measures up:  the PISA 2006 survey of students' scientific, reading and mathematical literacy skills, Australian Council for Educational Research (ACER).


A number of independent reports have found that student academic performance has remained stagnant, or has declined, despite significant increases in government funding.

According to the NSW Auditor-General, Peter Achterstraat, "compared to ten years ago, the New South Wales government has spent over three times more money on improving literacy and numeracy yet there has been little real improvement with our children." (28)  Similarly, the Victorian Auditor-General found that improvements in literacy and numeracy by students in the early years of schooling were not sustained over time despite funding increases. (29)

A 2006 study by ANU economists Andrew Leigh and Chris Ryan found that statistically significant reductions in literacy and numeracy test scores have been recorded since the 1960s.  This has occurred despite real school expenditure per student increasing dramatically during that period. (30)

Figure 14 provides a scatter plot of the assessed level of service provision for government schools against the proportion of teachers as a share of total government school staffing. (31)  It illustrates that a number of jurisdictions are able to achieve relatively higher levels of educational service provision with fewer teachers in the overall government school staff mix.

Figure 14:  Value for money in government school education services,
2007-08

Source:  Commonwealth Grants Commission, 2009 Update Report Supporting Tables;
MCEECDYA, National Report on Schooling in Australia 2008.


4.2 HOW ARE THE STATES PERFORMING IN THE DELIVERY OF HEALTH CARE IN PUBLIC HOSPITALS?

Key performance indicators for public hospitals -- those owned and managed by state and territory governments -- suggests that taxpayers are receiving an insufficient return on the substantial amounts spent on the provision of health services.

Results for the number of licensed or available public hospital beds per 1,000 people -- a basic indicator of service provision -- are decidedly mixed across the states.  Whilst NSW, Tasmania and the ACT have increased the number of beds for patient use, the number of available public hospital beds in other states has declined in the face of a rising population (Figure 15).

These mixed trends of service provision have coincided with growth in the rate of public hospital separations nationally of three per cent per annum.

Figure 15:  Number of licensed or available public hospital beds per 1,000 people,
2000-01 to 2007-08

Source:  Australian Institute of Health and Welfare (AIHW), Australian Hospital Statistics.


There is also scope for improvement with regard to the timely treatment of patients presenting themselves at public hospital emergency departments.  According to the Australian Institute of Health and Welfare (AIHW), the percentage of emergency department visits seen on time has improved only in NSW, Queensland and South Australia since 2003-04.

In most jurisdictions, there is a less than 70 per cent chance that public hospital emergency patients will be seen in a timely manner.

With the public hospital sector obliged under the state-federal Australian Health Care Agreement to provide services to patients free of charge, access to elective treatments are effectively rationed via the maintenance of waiting lists.

While the percentage of elective patients waiting for more than a year for treatment in a public hospital has declined in the larger states since 2000-01, it has increased in South Australia, Tasmania, the ACT and the Northern Territory.

Recent official inquiry reports paint a picture of bureaucratised public hospital systems that are insufficiently flexible to meet the service demands of the population.

The 2008 Garling Report into NSW public hospital acute care assessed problems arising from administrative changes in 2005, leading to the establishment of eight Area Health Services across that state.

It was reported that the change was associated with "a shift from clinical governance of corporate matters, to corporate governance of clinical matters." (32)  A consequence of this is that "clinical managers cannot make routine purchases or decisions, which impedes patient care, particularly where urgent supplies are required." (33)

The 2005 Forster Review into Queensland Health Systems found that bottlenecks in decision making in the Queensland Health Department bureaucracy slowed the capacity of the organisation to respond to service delivery pressures. (34)  Many clinicians also reported that increasing amounts of their time was being consumed in administrative red tape, contributing to a reduction in time for patient care. (35)

There is also a mixed relationship between the share of salaried medical officers and nursing staff working in public hospitals and the level of public hospital inpatient services provision as assessed by the Commonwealth Grants Commission (Figure 16).

Figure 16:  Value for money in public hospital inpatient services,
2007-08

Source:  AIHW, Australian Hospital Statistics 2007-08;
Commonwealth Grants Commission, 2009 Update Report Supporting Tables.


5 BUDGET RESCUE:  WHAT CAN BE DONE TO REDUCE THE
FISCAL RISKS OF STATE PUBLIC SECTOR EMPLOYMENT?

On the basis of current policies, the states and territories face a credibility gap between their avowed desire to rectify their self-induced structural budget deficits and statements about the need to control growth of their labour costs.

Wages are the major component of state government operational spending.  With increases in the number of public sector employees and remuneration packages proving financially unsustainable in response to a mild downturn in economic conditions, there is a need for states to reduce the costs of their public services.

This section outlines four strands of potential policy reform for states to pursue in an effort to regain fiscal sustainability without diluting the prospects of a strong economic recovery.


5.1 STATES IN BUDGET DEFICIT SITUATIONS SHOULD ENACT A WAGE PAUSE UNTIL THEIR BUDGETS RECOVER

Measures announced by most jurisdictions in their most recent budgets to restrain the costs of state public sector employment in line with general inflation appear doomed to failure.  States' total employee expenses are anticipated to rise by almost seven per cent in 2009-10 compared to the previous year, with inflationary increases also anticipated in future years.

The "cost plus" environment that continues to pervade state government employment is in stark contrast to that faced by the private sector.

ABS average weekly earnings data suggests that total earnings have declined since November 2008 (about the time of the Rudd government's initial $10.4 billion fiscal stimulus "cash splash") in manufacturing, electricity, gas and water, wholesale and retail trades, transportation, finance and insurance, and property and business services. (36)

In practice, many businesses have mutually agreed with their workers over the past year to reduce working hours and remuneration as a way to protect jobs in a difficult economic climate. (37)

With states unable to stem the growth in employee expenses through policy discretion, there seems to be merit in exploring ways to adopt rule-based mechanisms for managing such costs during periods of acute budgetary stress.

The specific proposal outlined here is for states to enforce an ex post regime of wage pauses based on a monthly or quarterly report of state finances (prepared by treasury departments and independently audited). (38)

Box 5 illustrates a hypothetical example of how a wages pause mechanism may operate.

A direct consequence of this wage pause mechanism is that, with projected pay increases foregone in the event of a budget deficit situation, taxpayers are relieved of the fiscal burden otherwise imposed.  At the margin at least this could help foster economic activities which would then contribute to a return to state budget balance or surplus.

A desire to maintain wage increases might also discourage the otherwise inherent tendency of bureaucrats, as explained by the public choice theorist William Niskanen, (39) to seek an expansion of agency budgets that might otherwise risk the occurrence of a budget deficit.

Box 5:  A simple state wage pause scenario

In the scenario that follows, suppose that a government negotiated with public servants a two per cent per annum pay increase (effectively a 0.5 per cent pay increase each quarter).  The certified agreement included a provision for a periodic wage pause should the budget be in a deficit position.

The following table illustrates the fiscal situation unfolding in the jurisdiction over the year, and its impact on public sector wages under the certified agreement.

PeriodDeficitWage
growth
t - 3Y
t - 2N0
t - 1N0.5
t?0.5

Three periods ago a budget deficit was recorded for the state.  In response to this, policymakers embarked on a course of public sector reform which quickly reduced expenditure.  This led to the budget returning to a surplus position in subsequent periods t-2 and t-1.

While the wage-pause-during-deficit rule meant that public servants had foregone a 0.5 per cent increase in period t-2, due to the budget deficit recorded in t-3, they still receive wage increases of 0.5 per cent for the final two periods of the fiscal year.


5.2 GOVERNMENT WAGES POLICY COULD BE STRENGTHENED THROUGH A JUDICIOUS MIX OF LEGISLATION AND INFORMATION

A formal wage policy is designed, in part, as a signal to public sector workers, unions and the wider taxpaying community that the government intends to restrain growth of its employee wage expenses up to a certain level.

When the pre-announced commitments are enforced, the reputation of the government as a sound manager of public finances is significantly enhanced.  This could entail important spin-off benefits for a jurisdiction, including the attraction of capital and skilled labour from other regions as well as promoting a healthy government credit rating.

As noted above, the key problem with existing wage policies of states and territories is their subsequent lack of enforcement which, in turn, exacerbates the damaging budgetary consequences of continually rising public sector employment costs. (40)

To effectively increase the political cost of reneging on wage policies, state and territory governments should consider enshrining their existing wage policy parameters through legislation.  This would force governments to explain any proposed moves, via legislative amendment, to relax their wage policy and facilitate an open community debate about the efficacy of loosening public sector wage settings.

To complement the legislative anchoring of state government wage policies, governments would be obliged to report on productivity improvements attained by their workers, in relevant areas of service delivery, should they wish to lift existing wage policy caps.

Since productivity changes in the public sector are largely unobserved, at least by the general public, publicly available information of this nature would shed light on the factors adjudged by governments to justify a relaxation of wages policies. (41)

This information would assist in ameliorating the information asymmetry that bedevils the fiscal relationship between voters and elected legislators, strengthening the hand of citizen-taxpayers to challenge exorbitant pay demands advocated by public sector unions.


5.3 CAPS ON PUBLIC SERVICE NUMBERS COULD BE STRENGTHENED TO ACHIEVE THEIR OBJECTIVES

The policies affecting the growth of public sector wages and benefits suggested above could be augmented by the diffusion of policies across states to implement explicit upper limits on the numbers of government employees to be engaged during a given period of time.

The Western Australian government currently enforces a cap on full-time equivalent (FTE) staff numbers in the general government sector.  The specifications of the original policy as announced in February 2009 included:

  • A ceiling of 99,155 FTEs applied to general government sector agencies in 2008-09, inclusive of additional staff (including in nursing and policing) announced by the state government at the 2008 election
  • The FTE cap excludes staff working in government trading enterprises. (42)

According to the latest budget, the estimated WA general government sector employment outcome in 2008-09 was 100,996 FTEs -- an excess of 1,841 over the initial ceiling.

This outcome was attributable to incorrect employment estimates provided in the 2008-09 budget, as well as the notion that some departments lacked "adequate controls in place to ensure compliance with the ceiling or with expenditure limits. ... we seem to have inherited a culture that has ignored direction from government on budget and head count." (43)

The state government has adjusted its FTE ceiling up to 101,803 for 2009-10, allowing for the employment of additional police, health, education and child protection staff. (44)

In practice, public sector employment ceilings should be augmented by clear and transparent enforcement strategies ensuring that the policy has the greatest potential to meet its objective.  This may include regular reporting requirements by agencies on their progress against meeting ceiling targets, as has been implemented in WA, (45) to help ameliorate potential informational asymmetries that may reduce the effectiveness of such policies.

In addition, agencies that breach the ceiling should be liable to financial penalties and senior officials overseeing such breaches may be sanctioned (for example, through a reduction in salary or dismissal from service).

To be sure, sufficient flexibilities could also be introduced to ensure that the application of a global government employment cap does not detract from the achievement of other policy objectives.  For example, the New Zealand government's policy emphasises the need to reduce numbers of administrative staff in exchange for staff responsible for the delivery of frontline services consistent with an overall employment cap.


5.4 SMALLER BUREAUCRACY CAN BE ACHIEVED IF STATES FOCUS ON ESSENTIAL GOVERNMENT FUNCTIONS ONLY

Any discussion of the growth in state public sector employment ultimately cannot be divorced from changes in the scope of government.

In general terms, governments would tend to be small and circumspect when its bureaucracies deliver the limited suite of public goods in accordance with the rules and regulations accorded to them. (46)  However, over time governments have extended their activities beyond public goods and into the provision of merit goods and, in some cases, purely private goods.

However, over time governments have extended their activities beyond public goods and into the provision of merit goods and, in some cases, purely private goods. (47)

Exacerbating the economic damage caused by public sector expansion is the inherent incentives for public sector employees to lobby their political sponsors or the general public to at least maintain these governmental activities.

The economist William A. Niskanen emphasised that there is a connection between the size of agency budgets and factors that increase the typical bureaucrat's utility such as salary, perquisites of office, public reputation, power, patronage and agency output. (48)  This implies that public sector employees naturally evolve into an activist constituency striving to expand the size and scope of government, at the expense of taxpayers and a robust, vibrant private sector. (49)

In order to systemically reduce the level of public expenditure, including labour costs, governments need to regain their focus on what kinds of services are compatible with the appropriate preserve for collective action.  In the modern context of the Australian states and territories, these would include the following activities to be conducted by government:

  • keeping streets and communities safe through the funding and provision of law and order and justice services, including effective child protection services
  • funding school and vocational education services, preferably through competitively-neutral, portable voucher schemes that facilitate choices amongst an array of education providers
  • funding health services, including through a voucher system adjusted for the case-mix of services provided within hospitals
  • contributing toward infrastructure maintenance and development, with significant financial, construction and logistical support provided by the private sector.

As this schema of appropriate state public sector activities suggests, there exists substantial scope for the delivery of many services currently delivered by governments to be devolved to the for-profit or not-for-profit sectors. (50)  Empirical evidence suggests that this reform agenda would enhance the efficiency by which services are provided, and provide better information on the actual costs of production thereby promoting yardstick comparisons between providers. (51)

From the perspective of this paper, these reforms would mean that state and territory expenditures become more focussed on the core functions of government with the number of public sector employees significantly reduced over a transitional period as a result. (52)


6 CONCLUSION

The above analysis has shown that this decade has been marked by a significant growth in the number of state public sector employees, with a consistent increase in administrative staff within the overall employment mix.

In addition, state governments have proven themselves to be susceptible to calls by public sector unions and other vested interests to raise salaries and other benefits for the growing cohort of public servants.

There is sufficient evidence that the growth in expenses attributable to state government employment have not yielded sustained improvements in service delivery outcomes, at least in education and health.

As explained by leading Australian economist Henry Ergas:  "the increased remuneration per public sector employee observed in recent years appears less related to the achievement of productivity improvements in government service provision than to difficulties faced by state and territory governments in containing wage pressures." (53)

The current budgetary pressures faced by states and territories are the direct result of an unsustained increase in labour costs associated with additional public sector employment and rising remuneration packages.

Despite belated announcements to reverse this trend, the measures proposed by the states are unlikely to stem the tide of increasing employee expenses.  On this score, the states face a significant credibility problem threatening their perceived status by the business, financial markets and the general community as good managers of public finances.

Indeed, if the secular growth trend is left to continue apace, taxpayers will be forced to keep footing the bill reducing their disposable incomes and distorting incentives to expansion by the productive private sector.

There is also the risk that the economy will be hit by a double whammy effect whereby public sector wage increases flow to the rest of the economy, stoking the inflationary fires and creating the momentum for interest rate hikes.

It is only through concerted policy action at the state level that Australia can avoid the gloomy prospect of an economy recovery well below trend.

The primary financial obligation of state and territory governments is to protect the interests of the "silent majority" that is the taxpaying public.  An emphasis on rule-based mechanisms in the short term, such as a wage pause during budget deficit periods and stronger wages policies and employment ceilings, as well as productivity-enhancing deregulation in the longer term will be the critical ingredients to ensure that growing bureaucracies do not become the states' (and, by extension, the taxpayers') budget breakers.



ENDNOTES

1.  Joanna Vaughan, 2009, "Pay dispute 'worsening teacher shortage in South Australia' ", Adelaide Advertiser, 4 August (accessed 25 August 2009).

2"Pay rise 'rips off' Qld teachers", ABC News Online, 17 September 2009 (accessed 23 September 2009).

3.  Daniel Hurst, 2009, "Teachers reject govt's 'nation leading' pay offer", Brisbane Times, 19 May (accessed 25 August 2009).

4.  Jamie Walker, 2009, "Teachers block aid for needy children", The Weekend Australian, 18-19 July.

5"NSW Police strike wage deal with govt", The Sydney Morning Herald, 28 August (accessed 23 September 2009).

6.  Mathew Dunckley and Mark Skulley, 2009, "States battle to contain wages", The Australian Financial Review, 15 July.

7.  Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), Wage and Salary Earners, Public Sector, Australia, cat. no. 6248.0.55.001.

8.  Public universities are legislative entities of state governments providing higher education services that are primarily funded by the commonwealth government.  In recognition of this, higher education statistics separately provided by the commonwealth government are used to deflate the state government employment series published by the ABS.

9.  It is difficult to establish the actual numbers of workers employed by jurisdictions from self-enumerated state data.  This is because jurisdictions do not present information in a consistent fashion, with comparisons over time particularly hampered by definitional and other changes.  There are also discrepancies between state self-enumerated data and data on state government employment published by the ABS, due to differences in statistical coverage and other factors.  Therefore trends in these series should be interpreted with caution.

10.  The increase in staff in the government administration category understates the full extent of the increase in administrative staffing at the state level.  Staff numbers in other industry classifications comprise a mix of administrative and service delivery staff -- for example, the observed increase in health staff may include the additional employment of public hospital nurses as well as hospital managers and other corporate staff.  In addition, some administrative duties may be undertaken by service delivery staff.

11.  The Bligh government has recently indicated that it intends to offer redundancies to 250 senior bureaucrats, allowing for an increase in frontline service workers.  Chris O'Brien, 2009, "Qld to cut senior bureaucrats", ABC Online (accessed 3 October).

12.  Information drawn from state and territory government budget papers.

13.  "Bligh axes 10 Qld government depts", The Sydney Morning Herald, 25 March 2009;  Andrew Clennell, 2009, "Rees' public service overhaul -- with no job losses", The Sydney Morning Herald, 11 June.

14.  The Queensland government officially cited a lack of interest by the federal Australian Rail Track Corporation to purchase Queensland Rail's non-coal below-rail network for its decision to retain rail track.  However, when announcing the government's decision Queensland Premier Anna Bligh was reported as stating that "in many meetings, and in writing, the RTBU [Rail, Tram and Bus Union] has made several points about the need for ongoing public ownership of track. ... I believe those mighty QR [Queensland Rail] pioneers -- dating back to 1865 -- those who built out steel-vein rail network -- would be happy with our decision."  See Natasha Bita, 2009, "Unions threaten revolt over privatisation", The Australian, 3 June;  The Hon Anna Bligh, 2009, "Qld's non-coal below-rail network will remain in State hands:  Bligh", Media release, 19 August;  "Fight against rail sale gathers steam", Brisbane Times, 19 August 2009 (accessed 8 September 2009).

15.  For example, in September 2009 alone the NSW government advertised eight vacancies for managerial, research and clerical staff to administer the Literacy and Numeracy, Teacher Quality and Low SES School Communities National Partnership arrangements.  The total salaries for these positions are valued at over $491,000, with the base salary expected to rise by four per cent in July 2010.  It also advertised a total of 56 positions (permanent full- and part-time, and temporary) to implement the federal government's "digital education revolution."

16.  Public sector employees also generally enjoy high levels of job security by virtue of being shielded from the efficiency-enhancing rigours of market competition.

17.  James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock, "The Expanding Public Sector:  Wagner Squared", Public Choice 31:  147-150.

18.  Prior to the cut-off period, the Queensland government and Queensland Nurses Union agreed to a 12.5 per cent pay increase over three years.  Earlier the government negotiated an agreement with the Queensland Public Sector Union and associated unions providing general state government employees a pay rise of 4.5 per cent in the first year and four per cent in the following two years.  According to a Unions Australia press release dated 15 January 2009, "Working together with their unions, Queensland public sector employees have gained inflation-busting pay rises from the State Government. ... As a result of the union's organizing and negotiating skills, the final agreement ... was a vast improvement on the government's initial offer of 3.25%." (accessed 23 September 2009).

19.  Information drawn from state and territory government budget papers.  According to media reports, governments in NSW, Queensland and Tasmania chose not to pursue more comprehensive efforts to control public sector costs in part because to expected opposition from unions.  See Craig Johnstone, 2009, "Bureaucracy the growth industry in our state", The Courier Mail, 4 June;  Sue Neales, 2009, "Fat cats lose the cream", Hobart Mercury, 22 April;  "Premier refuses to rule out wage freeze laws", ABC News Online, 22 April;  "Rees keen to freeze public service wages", The Age, 1 June;  "Unions, Bligh on collision course over pay cuts", 17 April;  "Unions reject Rees pay freeze plan", 2 June.

20.  Information drawn from state and territory government budget papers.

21.  Mathew Dunckley and Mark Skulley, 2009, "States battle to contain wages", The Australian Financial Review, 15 July.

22.  Government of South Australia, 2009, Budget Statement, 2009-10 Budget Paper No. 3 (accessed 16 September 2009).

23.  Government of Tasmania, 2009, The Budget, 2009-10 Budget Paper No. 1 (accessed 16 September 2009).

24.  This section largely draws upon the work of Henry Ergas (2007, State of the States, The Menzies Research Centre) and Wood (2009, State finances at the crossroads:  The states' budget problem, and what to do about it, Occasional Paper).

25.  ABS, Government Finance Statistics, Australia, cat. no. 5512.0.

26.  A "noticeable" improvement in learning outcomes is defined as a three percentage points or more increase in the proportion of Year 7 students achieving the agreed national benchmark in reading, writing and numeracy tests in a given jurisdiction.  All data are from 2001 to 2007, except for South Australia (2002 to 2007).

27.  Sue Thomson, Nicole Wernert, Catherine Underwood and Marina Nicholas, 2008, Highlights from TIMSS 2007 from Australia's perspective, Australian Council for Educational Research (ACER);  Justine Ferrari, 2008, "Doesn't add up:  Borat kids beat Aussies in maths and science", The Australian, 10 December.

28.  Audit Office of New South Wales, 2008, "Media Release:  Auditor-General's Report -- State of literacy and numeracy in NSW" (accessed 17 September 2009).

29.  Victorian Auditor-General's Office, 2009, Literacy and Numeracy Achievement, February.

30.  Andrew Leigh and Chris Ryan, 2006, "Long-Run Trends in School Productivity:  Evidence from Australia" (accessed 17 September 2009).

31.  The "assessed level of service" ratio is defined as the ratio of a jurisdiction's estimated gross expenses per capita to its assessed gross expenses per capita.  A ratio greater than 100 indicates that a jurisdiction is providing services at levels above the Australian average, and a ratio below 100 indicates below average levels of service.  This ratio is estimated by the Commonwealth Grants Commission in the context of its annual reviews of recommended GST funding shares between states and territories.

32.  Special Commission of Inquiry -- Acute Care Services in NSW Public Hospitals (Garling Report), 2008, Final Report, p. 1063.

33.  Ibid, p. 1075.

34.  Queensland Health Systems Review (Forster Report), Final Report, p. xiii-xiv.

35.  Ibid, p. xvii.

36.  ABS, Average Weekly Earnings, Australia, cat. no. 6302.0.

37.  Australian economist Sinclair Davidson recently noted that employers and employees have taken advantage of over two decades of labour market reform to save more jobs than would otherwise be the case.  Sinclair Davidson, 2009, "Rudd's stimulus furphy won't create jobs", Crikey, 22 September.

38.  The sectoral coverage of a public service wage pause rule will be an important practical matter to be settled, which is beyond the scope of this paper.

39.  William A. Niskanen, 1971, Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Aldine-Atherton, New York.

40.  The pattern observed at the state government level is broadly consistent with the notion of "time inconsistency."  This describes a scenario whereby a preferred course of action undertaken by a government today -- for example, announcing a policy limiting public sector wage increases -- will be opportunistically abandoned tomorrow -- in our example, where the government later reneges on its wage cap in order to gain votes at the next election.  See E. Finn Kydland and Edward C. Prescott, 1977, "Rules Rather than Discretion:  The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans", Journal of Political Economy 85:  473-491.

41.  It is noted that jurisdictions maintain an efficiency dividend policy, with expenditure savings clawed back from government agencies.  As these dividends are purportedly determined on the basis of productivity improvements in the public sector, presumably government possesses at least some information that should be made publicly available on its own accord, and could also be used for the purpose of a strengthened wages policy discussed here.

42.  Hon Troy Buswell, 2009, "Cap on public sector workforce announced", Media statement (accessed 21 September 2009).

43.  Parliament of Western Australia, 2009, Legislative Assembly Hansard, 11 August, p. 5,627.

44.  Ibid.

45.  It is noted that the WA government now required selected agencies to produce monthly or quarterly reports on their progress against meeting the global FTE cap policy, as a means to overcome any informational barriers between government agencies and political representatives.

46.  According to the father of modern economic thought, Adam Smith, governments -- and, by extension, the number of workers directly engaged to support them -- should be limited to activities "though they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, [they] are, however, of such a nature, that the profit could never repay the expense to any individual or small number of individuals."  Adam Smith, 1776 (1976), An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, Volume II, Chicago University Press, Chicago, p. 244.

47.  Sinclair Davidson and Julie Novak, 2008, Sustaining Growth:  Reforms for Tasmanian Prosperity, Report for Tasmanian Chamber of Commerce and Industry (TCCI).

48.  William A. Niskanen, 1971 (2007), Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Aldine Atherton:  Chicago, p. 38.

49.  Don Bellante, David Denholm and Ivan Osorio, 2009, Vallejo Con Dios:  Why Public Sector Unionism Is a Bad Deal for Taxpayers and Representative Government, Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 645, September, p. 4.

50.  In the case of states with significant geographic remoteness, there may remain a case for the delivery of services by governments if private sector alternatives do not exist due to an inability to achieve economies of scale (however, technological developments such as online schooling may help to alleviate these problems).  In this context, efficiency improvements could be attained by encouraging the development of operationally independent government schools or public hospitals.  Greater community participation in the governance of publicly provided units, such as through local public hospital boards, could also be important for the purpose of signaling the preferences of client groups to the governmental service provider.

51.  For a survey of the empirical literature, see Dennis C. Mueller, 2003, Public Choice III, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

52.  Existing ceilings on public service numbers would need to be revised downwards as public sector reform proceeds over time.  Cap revisions could be made on the basis of "one-in, two-out" (or similar) employment rules as a state government embarks on reform.  When state public sectors reach their ideal scope a global public sector cap could be maintained by a "one-in, one-out" employment numbers stipulation.

53.  Henry Ergas, 2007, State of the States, The Menzies Research Centre, Canberra, p. 6.