Friday, February 01, 1991

Can we stop prices rising?

If to do were as easy as to know what were good to do ...

-- Shakespeare.


RISING PRICES

Wages, prices, and the value of money are very different things now from what they were before the War.  None of us can help seeing that.  And, especially over the last three or four years, since the end of wage-pegging, wages have been rising steadily.  The basic wage has gone up 2/-, 3/-, or 4/- a week every quarter.  Last December there was a special jump of 19/- or £1, and the quarterly rise this February has been 8/-, the largest ever.  This should be a good thing for the worker, it would seem;  yet many workers, and trade-union leaders, too, are growing more and more unhappy about it.  No sooner does the basic wage go up 3/- or 4/- (less tax) than the grocer's, butcher's and other bills between them go up 4/- or 5/-.  Prices seem to rise faster than wages, and many of us shudder at the thought of where they will get to during this year.

This is how inflation strikes the average man and woman, and it is therefore no wonder that anti-inflation policies are increasingly called for;  that most of us feel the need for "putting value back into the pound".


WHO SUFFERS FROM INFLATION?

Although most people suffer from the effects of inflation, especially rapid inflation, some groups of people suffer more than others.

If inflation means a continuous rise in the general level of prices, this is the same thing as a continuous fall in the value of money.  As prices rise more and more, a pound note will buy less and less, so that its real value is becoming less and less.

That is why the greatest sufferers from the process are people whose money-incomes are fixed or rise very slowly, for their incomes are growing less and less in real values.  Such people are superannuated public servants, owners of fixed-interest investments, old-age pensioners, small landlords and some of the professional classes with relatively fixed fees.

For the same reasons, inflation is to the disadvantage of people who hold their property in the form of money, or money-equivalents such as bank deposits, bonds, insurance policies, etc., rather than in the form of real things such as land, buildings and durable goods.  The real value of their possessions keeps on declining.  Thus inflation hits the owners of Australia's 5½m. savings bank accounts.

Salary and wage-earners suffer relatively less than these groups in so far as their incomes rise along with rising prices.  Salaries tend to rise more slowly than wages, and therefore most salary-earners are more affected than wage-earners.  While wages are tied to the cost-of-living, a mild degree of inflation does not affect the wage-earner, but he suffers increasingly as the price-rise becomes more rapid.  The time-lag in cost-of-living adjustments keeps him always one step behind, and that step is growing longer each time.

At the other end of the scale, many businessmen, buyers and sellers, agents and middlemen gain from rising prices, and one group in Australia has been gaining very much from the process over the past few years -- primary producers, especially the sheep farmers.  Their incomes have been rising-much faster than the general level of prices, simply because the prices of the things they sell for an income (wool, wheat, etc.) have risen much more than most other prices -- see Table 1 (page 2a).

Because of this inequality of the impact of inflation, some groups of people fear inflation and its continuance much more than others, and more actively demand anti-inflation policies.  Also, though a mild degree of inflation may do little harm to most people and even be beneficial to some groups, as it becomes more rapid the inequality of suffering is increased and large-scale "social injustice" creates increasing social and political instability and can lead to dangerously hasty "crisis" measures.

How rapid then has the Australian inflation become?


HOW MUCH INFLATION HAVE WE GOT?

One way of answering this question is to look at the index numbers which attempt to measure price levels.  There is a difficulty here because there are many different sets of prices, some of which move up more rapidly than others.  There are retail prices, wholesale prices, import prices, export prices, and so on, and there is no "general" level of prices to which we can attach any precise meaning.

To the ordinary Australian the important prices are retail prices of the general run of things that make up the cost of living, and the "C-series retail price index number" attempts to measure changes in these prices (covering food and groceries, fuel, housing, clothing and miscellaneous expenditure).

This index shows that prices rose about 20% in the first couple of years of the war and then remained stable until the end of the war.  By the middle of 1947 they had risen by another 5% and since then have been rising at the rate of about 10% or 12% a year, so that three-quarters of the way through 1950 they were about 75% above pre-war level.  Later figures are not available at the time of writing, but indications are that the rise was slightly more rapid in the last quarter of 1950, and will be more rapid still during 1951 (very largely as a result of basic wage increases in December and February).

When compared with the "galloping inflation" of some other countries since the war, with China, Greece, and a number of European countries where price rises have been of astronomical proportions, Australia's experience seems scarcely to merit the name of inflation at all.  Yet there are two obvious reasons for concern.  One is that our prices have been going up more rapidly since 1947 than in other major countries such as Britain and (until recently) U.S.A., where they have tended to level off since then.  Another reason is that the retail price index number probably understates the extent of the rise that has actually taken place, largely because of the limited range of goods which it covers.  Most people's experience would probably reinforce this latter point, for, wages having risen on the average almost 100% since 1938-9 (see Table 1 -- below), if prices have really risen only 75%, then the average worker should be able to buy about 14% more now with his wages than he could then.  And few wage-earners or their wives would agree that this is the case.

We shall see later, too, that there are other reasons for urging that some steps should be taken as soon as possible to counter the increasingly inflationary trends in the Australian economy.  In the meantime, we can get a little more insight into the position by looking at the relationship between money and goods.

TABLE 1. Australian Wage and Price Index Numbers.
(In all cases, 1936-39 = 1000)

Wage
Rates
Retail
C-series
ExportsWool
Exports
Wheat
Exports
1938-910441029819793656
1945-613431278147711652130
1946-714231309208717343046
1947-815651393295528724195
1948-917571528348136494131
1949-5019131669399447274002
Jun., '5019761730470559214345
Sept., '5020251773628589004211

Note:  As distinct from wage-rates, average earnings (per male unit) have been calculated since 1942, and are as follows: -

1942-3£686
1946-76143
1947-87110
1948-98116
1949-50990
Jun., '509196
Sept., '501046

(All figures from Commonwealth Bureau of Census and Statistics.)


WE HAVE MORE MONEY THAN GOODS

The reason for generally rising prices is broadly that there is more money about than goods, or that the amount of money we have to spend, and are seeking to spend, is increasing more quickly than the volume of goods and services available for us to spend it on.

Roughly speaking, the total of Australian incomes is now nearly three times as great as it was before the war.  The National Income (the total of all incomes) was £814m. in 1938-9, £1248m. in 1946-7, and £2265m. in 1949-50.

Again, the volume of spendable money, consisting of notes in the hands of the public, bank deposits and savings bank deposits, has grown to more than three times its pre-war level, as follows: -

June, 1939£ 660m.
June, 1947£1550m.
June, 1950£1994m.
Sept., 1950£2115m.

Though not all of this constitutes an immediate spending pressure, it is probable that the major part of it does.

As against this growth in the volume of spendable money, it is doubtful whether the quantity of goods on which it can be spent has increased even a quarter as much.  There is no adequate measurement of changes in the total of goods and services produced, but some individual typical items are significant (these show a comparison between quantities in 1949-50 and in 1938-9): -

Refrigerators400% more
Beer85% more
Houses, coal, sugar, tobacco and cigarettes25% more
Flour10% more
Boots and shoes9% more
Meat8% more
Pig-iron, steel, bricksslightly less
Butter14% less

It is not suggested that these are a representative sample, but they certainly would not lead us to think that production of goods in general has gone up by anything approaching 50 per cent.  Even on this unlikely assumption, however, we would have three times as much money to spend on one-and-a-half times as much goods -- a somewhat greater degree of inflation than is suggested by the 75% price rise referred to above.


WHY HAVE WE GOT INFLATION?

A number of forces have contributed to Australia's present inflationary pressure by increasing the volume of money available for spending, and limiting or hindering a similar expansion in the volume of goods and services to spend it on.

First of all, some degree of inflation is an unavoidable effect of our present attempts at energetic economic development, population growth, and defence preparedness.

Secondly, there are other inflationary factors such as high export prices and incomes, high government spending, devaluation, our wages-system, industrial conflict, low productivity, and management and labour inefficiency.  We shall look at these forces in turn, and see what steps could be taken to reduce their inflationary effects.


ARE DEVELOPMENT AND IMMIGRATION AIMS BEYOND OUR CAPACITY?

The Australian economy is attempting at the present time an unusually high rate of investment.

As economists use the term, "investment" means the production of capital goods, goods designed not for current consumption but for increasing our future productive power.  These include such things as houses, factories, machinery, shops, schools, hospitals, roads, bridges, railway tracks, trains, cars, trucks, planes, silos, dams, water supply schemes, electricity plant, etc.

In normal times something like 15 per cent. of our total output consists of capital goods in this sense.  At the present time we are aiming at a level of investment of about 33⅓ per cent. of our total output.  This is unusually high, but there are good reasons for aiming so high: -

  1. We are still suffering in this matter from a hang-over from the war period, during which we allowed our capital equipment to run down, both by failing in many instances to maintain or replace worn-out capital (buildings, machinery, transport equipment, power plants, etc.), and also by failing to make the regular annual additions to our total stock of equipment which are essential in a living and progressive economy.

    This hangover is apparent both in private industry and in government works.  Both have large present and future investment programmes designed to make up the backlog.  It is especially apparent in the basic sections of our economy (coal, fuel, steel, transport, power), where the deficiencies have caused "bottlenecks" in the supply of many things which are basically necessary to the efficient working of all other industries.

  2. Population growth also makes high levels of investment necessary.  Our population did not stop growing during the war period when we were failing to increase our capital equipment along with it.  In the last two years immigration has greatly added to its growth, to the extent of over 150,000 a year.  And immigration policy aims at an annual addition to our population from this source of 200,000 people.

    The efficiency and productivity of industry generally, and consequently the standard of living which we can enjoy, depend very significantly upon the amount of capital equipment and power we have available.  Broadly speaking, if we want to maintain standards of living, it is necessary to increase our total capital equipment at about the same rate as our population grows, as well as maintain our existing stock of capital.  It has been estimated that every immigrant creates the need for £1,000 worth of additional capital (housing, transport, public services, tools, machinery, etc.) if our average standards of living are not to decline.  This means a need for £150,000,000 to £200,000,000 worth of new capital a year because of immigration alone.

  3. Current defence requirements reinforce the need for a high level of investment created by these war-caused backlogs and by rapid population growth.  Defence means additional investment in works, stores, equipment, vehicles and other materials, and expansion in these cannot be neglected in the tension of the current international situation.  Indeed, decisions made at the recent Commonwealth Conference of Prime Ministers will lead to an increase in our plans for defence expenditure.


SOME DIFFICULTIES

Now, aiming at an unusually high level of investment for the reasons we have discussed leads to several very important difficulties.

First of all, the full employment which we have enjoyed since the war period means that there are practically no unused resources of labour and materials which can be brought into use.  Consequently, any great increase in capital production can only be at the expense of other production, by withdrawing resources from the production of consumers' goods.  The only other way of adding to our capital equipment is by importing it (either paying for it with exports, or borrowing from overseas), and such imports are at present becoming increasingly difficult and expensive.  To a limited extent our labour resources, also, could be increased by seeking ways of drawing further upon the pool of aged workers and married women.

Secondly, we are unfortunately unwilling to let the necessary diversion of resources to capital production take place, because we are unwilling to save enough of our current incomes.  A3 governments and businessmen, we are trying to spend 33⅓ per cent. of our total income on capital goods, but as consumers we are trying to spend 80 per cent. or more of our incomes on consumers' goods (in 1949-50 we succeeded in spending about 75 per cent. of them on current consumption).  In short, we are trying to do two incompatible things at once:  -- to build for the future, and to spend high in the present, in a situation where we have not enough resources to do both as fully as we want to.

Again, it is a special economic feature of investment that it creates additional incomes without at the same time creating additional consumers' goods on which the incomes can be spent.  The men engaged in making machines and building factories get their wages now, but it is only after a lapse of time (often quite long) that the machines and the factories turn out the goods we can buy.

Thus a high level of investment is a powerful inflationary force, increasing the amount of money we have to spend without in the present adding equally to the total of things we can spend it on.  In the full employment situation it also tends to force up prices and wages through competitive bidding for limited supplies of materials and labour, both in investment industries and in consumption goods industries.

Policies of rapid capital expansion, immigration and defence are widely accepted as desirable and necessary in Australia at the present time, and a measure of inflation resulting from them must, I think, be viewed as healthy and inevitable, so long as it is not too rapid.  It can well be regarded as an automatic mechanism helping to reconcile the incompatibles referred to above -- it forces some reduction in present consumption, without which investment cannot expand rapidly;  and it prevents the investment programme from being too rapid by raising prices of labour and materials and enforcing some economy in the selection of investment projects.


SHOULD WE CUT DEVELOPMENT AND IMMIGRATION PROGRAMMES?

Our present position rather resembles having a cake weighing 15 ounces and trying to divide it into two slices, one of 5 ounces (investment) and the other of 12 ounces (consumption).  As things stand, we cannot do it.  In order to solve our problem we must either make the cake larger, make one or both of the slices smaller, or do both these things.

The possibilities of large increase in total production in the short period are severely limited by the shortages inherent in full employment.  Working harder, and more efficiently, using incentive schemes and improved managerial techniques, could help to some extent (and we shall consider them later), but by far the most important factor in high production is capital equipment and power.  Thus we can't cut down the 5 oz. slice very much or there is little hope of making the whole cake larger for the future.

There are, however, some ways in which the investment programme can be reduced without too serious effects.

Those forms of investment which aim to produce luxury goods and less essential goods, and those which are likely to come into production only after a longer period of time should be pruned in preference to those producing essential goods in the relatively short period.

For this reason it is worth considering seriously how far a developmental project like the Snowy River Scheme should be slowed down or postponed.  A sound suggestion might be to proceed only with that small part of the scheme which will give us hydro-electric power within four or five years, and to abandon the rest for the time being.  The proposal is even worth discussing that the Scheme should be carried out for us by American firms, under charter or with a franchise, thus giving us our development scheme without making big inroads upon our own resources of capital and labour.

Again, in N.S.W., it certainly seems that the principles we have expressed would favour such railway developments as the Singleton-Muswellbrook and the Nattai-Thirlmere lines (which will carry coal) in preference to the costly Sydney City underground railway extensions.

In private industry it would seem necessary to limit the extent to which the less essential industries could obtain finance and materials, by control over credit and capital-raising, and over important raw materials and supplies.

Machinery exists for preparing and applying this kind of policy in the recently established National Security Resources Board, the credit powers of the Commonwealth Bank, and the renewed Capital Issues Control.  I believe the Government has been far too slow in setting up the latter control, and it still remains to be seen in what ways and how promptly it will act upon the suggestions of the N.S.R. Board.

Again, if a good part of the pressure for high investment comes from our high intake of immigrants into Australia, this pressure could be reduced by cutting down our immigration targets.  If we aimed at 100,000 a year instead of 200,000, this would perhaps be nearer to our economic capacity to absorb them without too great an inflationary pressure.  On the other hand, this result may well come about without such a change of policy on our part, by a drying up of the stream of suitable migrants.

As for cutting down consumption, we have seen that the people are peculiarly unwilling to take steps in this direction.  Half-hearted propaganda in favour of savings over the past few years seems to have had little effect, and I doubt if much could be expected from a full-scale, high-powered "savings campaign" such as the Government seems to have in mind.

We should not, of course, ignore the possibilities of increased public subscriptions to government loans, or purchase of savings certificates, if higher rates of interest were offered.  But it is also a fair comment that governments are pursuing incompatible policies when they seek to encourage thrift on the one hand and in practice discourage it on the other hand by giving such social services as old age pensions to the thriftless and denying them to the thrifty.

Probably the most effective policy reducing the pressure of consumption demand would be a high taxation policy, linked with budget surpluses.  Higher income taxes leave the taxpayer with a smaller proportion of his income to spend on current consumption, and budget surpluses subtract more from the volume of spendable money in the community than they add to it by government expenditure.

The important thing here is the budget surplus, and it is necessary, though difficult, to avoid the danger that higher government revenues would simply encourage higher expenditures instead of the surpluses.

It is never politically popular to increase taxes, and it is understandable that in both the 1949-50 and 1950-51 Commonwealth Budgets, when increased taxes would have been wise from the point of view we have been discussing, the Governments concerned did not increase them.  In the first case, an election was due in two or three months;  in the second case, a double dissolution seemed not unlikely.

I believe that tax increases will have to come.  It takes, however, an unusually courageous government, a high level of public education in the effects of government finance and taxation, or a widely acceptable pretext, such as war and defence (note the higher taxes promised in Britain in connection with the stepping-up of defence), to make significant tax increases possible.

It would take, too, a government firm in its resolve to conquer inflation and in its resistance to pressures for further spending sprees, to produce the vitally necessary budget surpluses out of the increased revenue.

In general, then, it seems necessary to examine critically our development programmes in Australia.  Both government and private investment plans should be pruned of less essential projects, and perhaps immigration targets should be reduced.  If, better still, we can educate ourselves as well to the need for budget surpluses and higher rates of income tax, then the degree of inflation due to development and immigration should not be unduly high.


DANGERS FROM OTHER INFLATIONARY FORCES

Other factors, however, are strongly speeding up the inflationary process, and if it becomes much more rapid there are dangers of most undesirable consequences.

An over-rapid rate of inflation intensifies the "social injustices" of the unequal incidence on different sections of the community, and can lead to hasty crisis measures which may do more harm than good.  It can also, as it becomes more rapid, lead to the panic and complete loss of confidence in the currency which usher in "galloping inflation" and collapse.

Furthermore, unless the process can be reasonably controlled, it brings about a progressive distortion of the pattern of the economy which makes the achievement of the investment goals less and less possible.  It does this by over-stimulating the industries producing luxury and non-essential consumers' goods, these being more profitable in a situation of plentiful money and basic shortages, and by drawing resources away from investment and essential industries.  Over a growing range of industry also, easy profits remove the spur to efficiency in production and help bring about a spreading decline in efficiency whose only result, if we return to our earlier image, is to reduce the size of the whole cake.

This distortion also brings the danger of unemployment as the solution for inflation.  Indeed, in some industries, through shortages of basic materials and power, or through a process of "pricing themselves out of the market", we are perhaps already perilously close to the unemployment which, as it spreads, brings the traditional "depression" remedy for inflationary booms.  That remedy is a more bitter medicine than any of the policies suggested in this article.

To avoid these consequences we must examine the present inflationary forces which lie outside our development and immigration programmes.  These forces are progressively hastening the inflationary process in Australia, and in relation to them we must frame and apply anti-inflationary policies with the least possible delay.

I shall make, as I suggested earlier, a somewhat artificial division into (a) forces which have increased the volume of spending money, and (b) forces which limit the expansion of the quantity of goods and services.  And as we look at the causes, we shall look also at the appropriate cure in each case.


TOO MUCH MONEY
Where it comes from and what we should do about it.

A series of forces has operated strongly during and since the war to increase greatly the total amount of money we have available as purchasing power.


ACCUMULATED SAVINGS

During the war period about half of our labour and material resources were being used for war purposes and not producing goods and services for ordinary consumption;  yet everyone was receiving wages or other forms of income.  This was the characteristic inflationary situation, but price-rises were largely prevented by a high rate of saving and a rigid system of wage-pegging, price-control, rationing and subsidies.  The inflation was thus suppressed until after the war, when we emerged with large personal savings, and with an outsized pent-up demand for consumption and other goods that had been unavailable during the war (houses, furniture, motor-cars, clothes, etc.) and with a too-early removal of some of the controls.

There is little that can be done to reduce the inflationary force of these accumulated savings.  A capital levy would wipe some of them out, but there are many moral and economic objections to such a remedy;  increased taxation would help to absorb some of them;  steps aimed at producing more goods would help gradually to work off some of them.  And it may be that on the whole people will want to keep more of them in the form of money-savings now than they did before the War.


HIGH GOVERNMENT SPENDING

During the war the level of government spending sky-rocketed, and this largely created the increased incomes without creating things on which they could be spent.  And the level of government spending has remained high ever since, and is a continuing inflationary factor.  It is true that for several years now governments have not been spending more than they have taken from the people by taxes, other charges, and relatively small borrowings -- there has not been inflationary deficit-finance.  The inflationary effects of present high government spending arise from the high proportion of that spending which creates incomes without providing goods and services on which they can be spent.  This is especially the case with increased social services, and with large public works programmes.

I have urged before the need to prune public works programmes of less essential and less immediately-fruitful projects.  The government's efforts in this direction could well be more speedy and definite.

Reductions in social services, which would be theoretically valuable as anti-inflationary measures, are socially and politically out of the question (though it is well that we should realise that an increase in inflationary pressure is part of the price we have to pay for the increases we have made in our social services).

Also, further extensions of social services should, in the present situation, be approached with great caution.


RAPID WAGE RISES

Wage-levels have been rising in Australia since the abandonment of wage-pegging in 1946-47, and increasingly fast over the last half-year or more.  Three factors have contributed to this -- the strong bargaining position of trade-unions in a period of full employment;  the bidding up of wages by employers and industries anxious to obtain and keep workers;  and our system of automatic cost-of-living adjustments to wages.  This last factor must bear a considerable share of the responsibility for the familiar rising spiral of prices and wages.  Besides their inflationary effect in increasing the quantity of spending money, continual wage rises have a direct effect in raising the price-level because wage-costs are the most important element in the costs of most things.

The appropriate policy here would be a "wage-freeze" agreement (such as that which was so effective in Britain for two or three years, until quite recently), or a temporary abandonment of automatic cost-of-living adjustments.  Although the need for such a policy has recently been expressed by political Labour in two of the smaller States, and by one of our largest trade-unions, I see little chance of its being generally acceptable to organised labour as a whole, particularly in the highly industrialised States.  It would certainly be impossible for psychological reasons, without an associated policy of profits limitation (and this would be as strongly opposed by businessmen and employers) and of price-control (which is completely ineffective in keeping down prices unless wages and other costs are kept down).


HIGH EXPORT EARNINGS

Since the war, and especially since 1947, there has been an enormous expansion in the incomes of exporters because of high world demand and record world prices for primary products such as wool, wheat, metals and meat (again, see Table 1 -- page 2a).  Besides creating high spending pressure within the Australian economy, these high prices have had a direct effect on the price-level by raising the prices in Australia of meat, woollen goods, and wheat products, all important items in our cost of living.

Furthermore, our expenditure on imports has not risen to the same extent as our income from exports, and a surplus of exports over imports means a net increase in the money in the country not balanced by an increase in imported goods to spend it on.


DEVALUATION IN SEPTEMBER, 1949

This brought about further increases in export incomes (mainly through the increases it caused in world prices of our exports), and also higher prices, in Australian money, for some of the things we import.  It thus gave a further fillip to inflationary forces.  Even more important, perhaps, was the failure on Australia's part to seize this appropriate opportunity to appreciate the Australian pound against sterling and many other currencies, a step which would have had valuable anti-inflationary effects by reducing high export incomes and lowering the prices of almost all our imports.

These inflationary effects of our trading and financial relations with the rest of the world could be countered by several lines of action: -

  1. Freezing a part of high export incomes so that it could not be spent at present but was kept in reserve against a possible future drop in those incomes.  The wheat stabilisation scheme does this, and the stabilisation scheme recently enacted for the wool industry has the same effect, though the size of the levy (7½%) is too small to have significant anti-inflationary force.  Such schemes might be extended to other primary industries.  A more important and effective slice has been taken from woolgrowers' incomes as pre-payment of income taxes, though the form of this deduction is, in my opinion a poor second-best compared with a larger stabilisation levy.  It is, moreover, at the time of writing, under challenge in the High Court.

    Such anti-inflationary steps are strongly opposed by those whose incomes are affected.  And the argument against singling out one section of the community for special sacrifice is a strong one.

  2. Another line of action in the sphere of trade would be to increase the level of imports.  This does nothing, of course, to reduce the money-pressure from export incomes, but by bringing more goods into the country, it increases the volume of goods on which our incomes can be spent.  A considerable import surplus for a year or two might help greatly to reduce the inflationary drift in Australia.

    There are growing difficulties in increasing our imports, however, in the face of other countries' growing needs of their own output, and their increasing diversion of resources (and shipping) to defence purposes.

  3. Revaluation of the Australian pound would be deflationary in effect by reducing the incomes (in Australian money) of farmers and exporters;  by reducing the price in Australia of some important commodities such as wool and meat, and of all imports.  Thus it would be probably the most effective single anti-inflationary step we could take.  On the other hand, there are strong political pressures exerted against revaluation, by groups who would suffer by it.  These include farmers and exporters (whose incomes would fall), and a number of Australian manufacturers who would suffer stronger competition from cheaper imports.

    Again, with rising costs and prices in Australian industry, the longer delay there is in revaluing the greater will be the adverse effect of such competition, the more industries will suffer from it, and consequently the greater will be the political pressure against it.  From this point of view it was a mistake not to appreciate against sterling in September, 1949, or again in the 1950-51 Budget.


WHY HAVE WE FAILED TO PRODUCE ENOUGH GOODS?

Other factors have limited in various ways the increase in the volume of goods and services available to satisfy our vastly increased total of purchasing power.


BOTTLENECKS AND INDUSTRIAL UNREST

Probably the greatest limitation on expansion of production of goods and services has been lack of production in the basic industries, especially the coal industry.  Output of coal has increased, but far from enough to meet the growing demands of industry and consumers.  This has led to shortages and idle capacity in industries directly dependent on coal, such as iron and steel, transport, gas and electricity, and a consequent hampering of many further industries dependent on them for materials, fuel and services, for their own production and expansion.  Part of the reason for these bottlenecks lies, as we have seen, in the distortion arising from the growing inflationary process, a large consumers' demand stimulating consumption goods and luxury goods industries, so that it is more profitable to devote men and resources to them than to the basic industries.  The dependence of so much consumption-goods industry on the basic industries make this a vicious circle.  Another reason for the narrow bottlenecks is that the basic industries, especially coal, are those in which strikes and extensive industrial unrest have had such serious effects on production.

Because the coal-mining industry is vital, reduction of stoppages, easing of industrial frictions, acceptance by the miners of increased mechanisation, installation of machinery at a faster rate, expansion of open-cut mining, would be valuable contributions to the struggle against inflation.  The Joint Coal Board has had a measure of success in some of these matters over the past two or three years, but has had little success in others.  There is no doubt of the harmful effect of communist-inspired industrial action in this industry (as in several other basic industries), and effective measures to combat Communist influence would at the same time help to combat inflation.


THE 40-HOUR WEEK

The introduction of the shorter standard working week since 1947-48 has added to inflationary pressures by directly reducing output through the working of shorter hours (in some industries and occupations), or by raising incomes and costs through the working of overtime at higher rates of pay.

An increase of the standard week to 44 hours again would add greatly to our total production.  It would add, other things being equal, the equivalent of 250,000 workers.  Opposition from trade-unions and the likelihood of widespread industrial conflict over such a step make me regard it as impracticable -- unless it were accompanied by a wage-increase sufficiently large to make it acceptable to organised labour, and this would certainly be itself an additional inflationary force.


LOW PRODUCTIVITY

The standard way of measuring productivity in an industry is quantity of output per man-hour, or per man-week, or even per man-year.  It is often difficult to measure productivity in this sense, especially to make comparisons between different times, when a number of factors (nature of the task, types of machines, management methods, etc.) may have altered.

But Colin Clark's investigations and calculations show clearly that in some industries (especially building, transport, manufacturing and mining) productivity is lower in Australia than pre-war.  In building, for example, product per man is nearly 30% less than it was before the war.

It is clear, too, that Australian industry as a whole has shown relatively small increase in productivity (about 3% above 1938-39), and compares very badly in this respect with many other countries, especially Britain (35%), America (74%) and Canada (76%).

There seem to be some fairly obvious reasons for this low productivity.  When jobs are easy to get the pressure is not on workers to work hard, and when goods are easy to sell the pressure is not on management to increase its efficiency.  Bottlenecks in supplies frequently keep workers idle on the job.  The increasingly frequent changing of jobs by workers lowers efficiency by using up time training and retraining for new jobs.

We must beware, however, of thinking that harder work and more efficient management would lead to startling increases in productivity.  In the modern economy, high production is primarily a matter of the amount of capital equipment and of power available per worker, and this underlines again the desirability of a high level of the right sort of investment in the Australian economy.

But there is scope, with our existing level of capital resources, for considerable stepping-up of productivity in industry, and the following would be of value, and should be persisted with: -

  1. The dropping of "go-slow" policies by some sections of organised labour, and the removal of various forms of limitations of the "daily task" of workers in some industries;

  2. the introduction or extension, where applicable, of "incentive" schemes, particularly well-designed and acceptable incentive-payment systems.  To have any change of acceptance by many unions, such systems would have to contain water-tight safeguards against abuse by employers.

    To both these types of policy there is widespread opposition in many trade-unions.  Some regard "going slow" and limitation of output as necessary in order to maintain full employment, on the rather curious theory that working harder leads to unemployment.  For these reasons also, as well as through fear of sweating and intensified exploitation of workers, many unions (though frequently not the rank and file of their members) strongly oppose incentive payment schemes.  Notice the use of this argument in the attempt by the Miners' Federation to gain the support of trade-unions generally for proposed coal stoppages (end Jan. 1951).

  3. Considerable increase in output could often be secured by improvements in management efficiency, especially in cases where management has become slack through the existence of a sellers' market, easy profits and little need to worry about costs.  In this matter, as well as in trade union attitudes, we could well follow Britain's lead in attempting to learn from American industry through the work of the Anglo-American Productivity Council.


SUGGESTED REMEDIES

It is clear that there are difficulties and obstacles in the way of all the various measures suggested above.  Each of them would adversely affect some section of the economy or some group of people, and the attempt to put any one into effect would meet political difficulties and opposition from pressure groups.

In such a situation, inflation can only be combated by a complex pattern of compromises acceptable to a large number of groups in the community.  One single type of measure applied in isolation is politically difficult, if not quite impracticable.  A comprehensive policy must contain a number of measures and must embody some rough equality of sacrifice.  If exporters are expected to sacrifice some of their present high incomes, then businessmen must accept some squeezing of profits, and trade-unions must accept a halt or slowing down in wage increases.

In the present situation, I suggest that the most practicable and effective steps would be: -

  • pruning of our investment programmes, governmental and private, as suggested on pages (10-11).

  • appreciation of the Australian pound, and budget surpluses by the Commonwealth Government.

    These two would be highly anti-inflationary in effect, and are both indubitably within the constitutional powers of the Commonwealth.

    The first might need to be supplemented by tariff revisions, and perhaps subsidies, in the interests of certain industries (though we could well sacrifice some of the least efficient).

    The second, in view of the difficulties of reducing the current expenditure of governments, would almost certainly involve appreciable tax increases.

  • a wage-freeze and profits limitation, in conjunction with the above steps, would greatly strengthen the equality of sacrifice demanded, and would be highly anti-inflationary.  They meet, however, two formidable obstacles.  First, neither the Commonwealth nor the States can legislate effectively in these matters because of constitutional limitations.  (The Commonwealth can do so under its defence powers in time of war;  or it could seek such powers by means of a referendum -- my own view on the latter being that if the government sought power to control prices, wages and profits, it should be for a limited period only).  Second, even if the constitutional limitations could be overcome, the practical difficulties of arriving at an equitable system, and the practical oppositions from different groups appear to be insuperable.  These items may thus have to be regarded as theoretically most desirable but politically impracticable.

  • pressing on with other policies.

    1. a continuous attack on the problems of low productivity and industrial unrest;

    2. attempts (in the face of growing difficulties) to raise the level of imports, not only of capital goods, but also of consumers' goods, even at the cost of borrowing from overseas.

    3. perhaps a deliberate reduction in our immigration target.


CHAOS AND UNEMPLOYMENT IF WE DON'T ACT PROMPTLY

Australia, with its programmes for industrial development, population growth, and economic progress, is aiming high and bravely.  The aim must be kept high, even though limitations or resources make it impossible of full achievement and force us to accept a slower rate of progress and a lower present level of consumption than we seek to maintain.

We cannot have development and progress without paying for them by working harder and consuming less, and a moderate degree of inflation is probably less harmful than beneficial in the adjustments we have to make between our investment and consumption aims.

There are signs that other forces are now increasing the pace of the inflationary process so that we shall be increasingly compelled to make the adjustments in a way that will cause greater sacrifices in present standards of consumption, in political and social stability, and in economic development for higher future standards of living, and may well lead to a solution by widespread unemployment, the least desirable alternative.

The need, therefore, for an adequate anti-inflation policy is growing daily, and the dangers of delay are increasing.

Sixty-Five Not Out:  Consequences of the Ageing of Australia's Population

INTRODUCTION

The commissioning of this paper has been prompted by increasing reference recently in overseas journals to the problems being encountered around the world by ageing populations.  (An American report predicted recently that the aged will surpass energy as the U.S.A.'s major problem area within a decade or so.)

What, then, is likely to be the situation in Australia at and beyond the end of the century?  This is the basic question that I discuss in the paper.

Should such problems concern you?  If some way off retirement age, you may be tempted to concentrate on overcoming rather more immediate problems.  However, remember that the elderly are ultimately -- everyone;  they are "our future selves".

There can be no doubt that a marked shift in age patterns is taking place throughout the world population;  people are living longer, birthrates are down.  Changes of this sort can have an unsettling effect on people because, for instance, the social security systems which operate, in most Western countries at least, have been generally supported in the widespread belief that today's payments assure tomorrow's benefits;  unfortunately such a belief will become increasingly less tenable.

Undoubtedly the elderly in many countries have experienced a marked improvement in their economic status in recent decades;  in fact this has been due to the political power they wield, brought about by their voting strength, and by their time availability to espouse the issues of the aged.  This, coupled with the community's natural sympathy for the care and well-being of the elderly, probably ensures that their status will be maintained, and even possibly enhanced.

So, given the prospect of a substantial increase in the aged population, set against numbers of working age that are declining proportionately, how is it to be paid for?

I believe that the problems highlighted in this paper can be resolved, but it is important that they are not ignored just because they are not immediate.  The solutions will be the more painful the later they are left.

Questions that need the widest possible public debate are:

  • How much responsibility should government assume for the elderly?
  • What, if any, standard of living should government guarantee?
  • How much should government provide in services for the elderly, and how much should be provided by family and friends?
  • How much should government do to assure a retirement income, and how much should it be left to people to provide for themselves?

In short,

  • What is the division between collective and individual responsibility?

February 1991



Just as a cricket player on 65 runs is likely to make a higher score, so too most people attaining the age of 65 can look forward to an extended "innings".  Contrary to stereotypes of the aged as isolated and debilitated -- onlookers from the pavilion -- the majority of the elderly are active and healthy, often making important contributions to family and community life.  Because of norms about "retirement age" and "pensionable age", increases in the numbers of the elderly inevitably occasion heightened outlays on social security payments, income maintenance for the healthy aged being the largest single component of Australian social security expenditure.

Nevertheless, an ageing population also brings the prospect of increasing numbers of the elderly with failing health, thus necessitating greater spending on medical care -- in a period of rising per capita costs for such services.  This paper explores the theme of growth in relation to the aged in Australia, focussing on issues pertaining to the increasing proportions over 65 years of age, the increasing numbers of the elderly and the related growth of expenditure on age pensions and health.


DEMOGRAPHIC AGEING

Since the 1880s, Australia's population has been experiencing demographic ageing, entailing rises both in the average age of people and in the proportions over 65 years.  This trend is illustrated in Figure 1, which depicts the median age of the population -- the age which half are above and half are below.  In 1881, the median age was 20.1 years and each subsequent census until 1947 recorded an increase in this figure, the 1947 peak being 30.7.  Ensuing years brought an interruption to the trend towards an older population, but in the 1970s the ageing of the population resumed and is expected to continue into the twenty-first century.  Two questions arise from Figure 1:  Why has there been an historical trend towards an ageing of the population?  And why was this trend interrupted between 1947 and 1971?

Figure 1:  Recorded and Projected Median Age of the Population of Australia, 1881-2001

Note:  The projected figures from 1978 assume a net reproduction rate of unity, constant mortality and net immigration at 50,000 per annum.


Answering the former question, demographic ageing has been due mainly to the decline in family size which commenced in Australia during the 1880s. Women who had completed child-bearing by that decade had an average of six or more children, but since the 1940s married women have borne an average of only two or three children (Table 1).  Falling family size reduced the proportion of children aged 0-14 in the population from 39 per cent in 1881 to 25 per cent in 1947 (Figure 2).

TABLE 1:  Average Issue from Existing Marriage of Married Women aged 45-49 Years

YearAverage Issue
18816.4
18916.5
19016.1
19115.1
19214.0
19323.6
19423.0
19472.8
19542.4
19612.5
19662.7
19732.9

Source:  National Population Inquiry (1975:46)


Figure 2:  Recorded and Projected Changes in the Age
Structure of the Total Population of Austraia, 1881-2001

AGE DISTRIBUTION 1881-2001

Note:  The projected figures from 1978 assume a net reproduction rate of unity, constant mortality and net immigration at 50,000 per annum.


Changes in mortality have contributed little to the ageing of the population.  Indeed, declining mortality has tended to raise the proportions of children and young adults rather than older people, because improvements in health and medicine have extended the lives of the young rather than of the old.  For example, between 1881 and 1971, life expectancy at birth increased by 21 years for males and 23 years for females, while at age 65 the corresponding gain was one year for males and four years for females (Table 2).  Children have benefited from improvements in child care, nutrition and standards of living, together with control over diseases such as diptheria, typhus, typhoid and poliomyelitis (Young, 1976).  Among young adults, improvements in living conditions and medical procedures have appreciably reduced mortality from childbirth and infectious diseases, including tuberculosis.  At middle age and above tuberculosis has ceased to be a major cause of death but heart disease and cancer have taken a greater toll, thereby preventing substantial improvements in life expectancy.  Because mortality declines have favoured the young, falling death rates have been a force for lowering the median age of the population, but the much stronger ageing force of declining fertility has obscured this effect (Coale, 1964).

TABLE 2:  Expectation of Life at Selected Ages in Australia (Years)

AgeMalesFemales
1881-901970-7219781881-901970-721978
0476870517477
10496062526668
20405052435658
30344]43364749
40263233293739
50202324222830
60141517152021
65II1213121617
7091010101214
757787910
80566578

Sources:

1881-90:  1911 Census. Vol.3, pp.1209-11

1970-72:  A.B.S. Australian Life Tables 1970-72 Ref. No. 4.31.

1978:  A.B.S. Deaths, 1978, Cat. No. 3302.0, pp.24-25.


What then broke the upward trend in the median age after the Second World War?  Especially influential here was the so-called "baby boom" which spanned the years from 1946 to 1961 and was a period when unexpectedly large numbers of births occurred.  A clue to the nature of the "baby boom" is provided by the figures in Table 1, which show that average family size has fluctuated within a narrow range since the Second World War.  In fact the "baby boom" -- and the consequent rejuvenation of the population -- was mainly due to more women marrying and having children rather than to women having larger families.  Thus a marriage revolution raised the proportion of children in the population and contributed to the fall in the median age.  Yet the rejuvenation of the population continued beyond the "baby boom" years, principally because post-war immigration was also augmenting the numbers of younger people.  Ageing of Australia's population resumed in the 1970's as births and net immigration declined and further interruptions to the ageing process seem remote because there is no likelihood of another sustained "baby boom" (National Population Inquiry, 1978:39-46).

A further measure of demographic ageing is the expansion of the percentage of people 65 and over.  This proportion has more than doubled over the last hundred years from 4 per cent in 1881 to 9 percent in 1976 (Figure 2).  The future will bring further increases in this proportion, but only very gradually.  The percentage aged 65+ is expected to be about 10 in 2001, possibly rising to 14 in the twenty-first century as the "baby boom" generation reaches old age (National Population Inquiry, 1978:105).  This century, the greatest changes in the age distribution will occur among persons of older working age, signalling an ageing of the labour force (Figure 2).


THE FOURTH GENERATION

Although the proportion of elderly people in Australia will change only slowly during the next two decades, demographic ageing has probably contributed to changes in family life having major implications for the provision of care for the aged.  In the nineteenth century, when life expectancy at birth was less than 50 years, families consisting of three or four generations of surviving relatives were a rarity in Western societies (Townsend, 1968:168-9).  According to Australia's mortality pattern of the 1880s, only 27 per cent of males and 35 per cent of females could expect to celebrate their 70th birthday.  Now control over mortality has enabled more to obtain the biblical span of "three score years and ten", and 55 per cent of males and 73 per cent of females can expect to become septuagenarians.  Thus the expanding proportion of the elderly has increased the relative size of the third (grandparent) and fourth (great-grandparent) generations, although earlier child-bearing has had a similar effect.  The contribution of the increase in the number of surviving generations is probably the greatest impact that ageing has had upon the family;  it implies that a higher proportion of families have aged relatives to care for, and that social policies may be needed to assist families in this supportive role (United Nations, 1975:25-25), even though the majority of the elderly remain independent except for a reliance on the age pension.

Multi-generation households have probably never been the norm in Western societies (Treas, 1977).  Although the generations have preferred to live apart they have maintained contact and assisted each other:  a form of "modified extended family" is believed to be typical permitting "intimacy at a distance" between the generations (Stehouwer, 1968:180).  Thus in considering support for the aged, the relevant definition of the "family" transcends the dwelling unit and includes the group of relatives with whom the elderly person has frequent contact (Stehouwer, 1968:182).  It is popularly believed in Australia, as well as in other industrialised countries, that the elderly are lonely or isolated from family life (Australian Catholic Social Welfare Commission, 1980).  Yet overseas studies have found that family support for the frail aged is more pervasive than support from formal organisations (Brody, 1979:515), more disabled people being bedfast or house-bound at home than in institutions (Shanas, 1968:45).

In the future, families could face increasing difficulties in continuing this care without public assistance.  Some have even suggested that governments will have to assume many of the functions of the family in providing social supports for the aged, and more will be living alone or in institutions (Shanas and Hauser, 1974).  While such statements are more relevant to countries with demographically "older" populations than Australia's (Table 3), the changes provoking these views are evident here.

TABLE 3:  Percentages Aged 65 Years and Over in Major Areas of the World 1960, 1975, 2000

196019752000
Europe9.712.312.5
Northern America9.110.29.3
USSR6.89.111.8
Oceania7.47.48.6
East Asia5.06.17.0
Latin America3.43.84.4
South Asia3.43.04.2
Africa2.72.93.3
World5.35.76.1

Sources:  United Nations (1979:129), Mauser (1976:74)


Daughters rather than sons customarily have borne the responsibility of caring for aged parents, spinsters perhaps being especially important here:  for instance, in the United States in 1900, 42 per cent of married old people lived in the same household with one or more of their unmarried children, compared with 10 per cent in 1975;  one force of change was declining age at child-bearing, lessening the likelihood of there being an unmarried child still at home (Dahlin, 1980:105).  More universal marriage has reduced the relative number of spinsters in the population while, at the same time, the rising labour force participation of women has presumably functioned also to decrease the proportion of women able to care for an aged parent.  For example, in July 1980, 48 per cent of women aged 45-54 years were members of the labour force, 4 out of every 10 of them being part-time workers (ABS, 1980b:15).  Part-time employment or withdrawal from the labour force may enable many women to become carers when necessary, but rising labour force participation, like the growth in the demand for child-minding services, is a symptom of change in women's traditional roles within the family.

Declining family size, as illustrated in Table 1, is often cited as a further force diminishing potential family support.  However, the generations which produced the largest families are now deceased, and the present and future elderly belong to generations which have borne small families.  Figure 3 shows that the principal change in the total issue of cohorts of women aged 45 years or more in 1976 was the decline in the proportions having no children or one only, the shift in the percentage bearing five or more children being slight.  Moreover, falling death rates at young ages have brought improved survival to adulthood, so that large families are no longer necessary to ensure that parents in their old age will still have some offspring surviving.  At the same time, more universal marriage, together with more universal child-bearing, as depicted in Figure 3, suggest that higher proportions of the elderly are living their lives in a family context.

Figure 3:  Total Issue of Ever Married Women Aged 45 and Over, 1976.


Thus the issue appears to be not so much whether the number of potential family supporters is falling, but whether other changes are reducing the availability of sons and daughters to serve as carers.  Important here are changes in family roles and attitudes, early child-bearing -- which results in elderly parents having elderly progeny -- and residential mobility which can separate younger and older generations.  Although there are many changes operating, in the context of an unprecedented expansion of the numbers of three and four generation families, the outcome is probably an erosion rather than a maintenance of support from younger generations for the disabled elderly.


GROWING NUMBERS

While only a small proportion of the elderly are dependent on others for the needs of daily living, this group, together with the aged suffering chronic illnesses, are major users of health and welfare services.  The expansion of their numbers, as well as of the numbers of the healthy aged receiving income maintenance, are having an immediate impact upon government expenditure.  In 1976, persons aged 65+ in Australia numbered 1.2 million, a figure expected to reach about 1.9 million by 2001.

Expansion of the numbers of the aged is largely the result of the "momentum of growth" (Keyfitz, 1971) inherent in the transition from a "young" triangular age distribution to an "old" rectangular one, wherein there are similar proportions in each age group up to those at which mortality is most pronounced.  Comparison of the 1881 and 1976 population pyramids in Figure 4 illustrates the effects of demographic ageing on the proportions in each age group.  The 1881 pyramid -- representing the population before fertility decline began -- is triangular in form with progressively lower proportions at each older age.  By 1976, the profile had become rectangular below age 30, and a continuation of the small family system, together with the survival of high proportions to older ages, should result in the rectangularity extending eventually to all age groups below 65 years.  Thus the momentum of growth will be sustained until an "old" rectangular profile is achieved -- a process which could take 60 years or more (Ruzicka, 1977:88) -- and without immigration from overseas would cause the total population to increase by 40 per cent (National Population Inquiry, 1975:249).  The absolute numbers of the elderly have grown substantially over time and the ratio of males aged 65+ to women of the same age has shifted from a predominance of males to a predominance of females (Figure 5).  Mainly responsible for the changes in the sex ratio have been the increasing representation of females in immigration and the improvement in female life expectancy, which has exceeded that for males (Table 2).

Figure 4:  Age Structures of the Population of Australia, 1881 and 1976



Figure 5:  Numbers Aged 65 Years and Over, 1881-1976


Yet although women have greater longevity, men have benefited as much if not more from the effect of improved survivorship on the prolongation of married life.  In 1901, approximately 54 per cent of males aged 65+ were currently married and 27 per cent were widowers, while in 1976 the corresponding proportions were 71 and 17 per cent.  It appears not only that more men are marrying, but also that more have a wife to care for them in their old age.  For elderly women (65+), the proportions currently married have changed little this century -- the figure being around 36 per cent in 1901 and in 1976 -- while the proportion widowed -- 52 per cent in 1976 -- has hardly varied since the 1930s.  The outcome has been that the mean duration of widower-hood has decreased substantially while the mean duration of widowhood has remained fairly constant (Young, 1977:283).  In the growing elderly population, therefore, there has been no dampening of the expansion of the numbers of aged widows, the dominant group among the aged in need of support (Treas, 1977:487).  They represent the majority of the "problem" elderly because they attain ages at which infirmities are most prevalent, they are necessarily dependent on persons other than a spouse and their incomes are often limited.  Expansion of the proportion of elderly women is the leading mechanism in the gradual ageing of the aged population, which is raising the relative numbers of the "old-old" (age 75+ years).  At the 1976 Census the "old-old" comprised 36 per cent of the elderly and by 2001 the proportion should be at least 41 per cent.


PROJECTIONS

The future numbers of the elderly can be projected with more assurance than younger age groups where unpredictable changes in fertility and net immigration have an immediate impact.  The future net immigration of elderly persons is uncertain but this source of population change would add only about 48,000 to the total between 1978 and 2001 if immigration continued on the average pattern for 1972-76.  The Series "A" projection of the Australian Bureau of Statistics -- which assumes constant mortality at adult ages -- yields an elderly population numbering nearly 1.9 million in 2001 (Table 4).

TABLE 4:  Projected Population Aged 65 Years and Over ('000)

MalesSeries 'A'
Females
TotalMalesSeries 'D'
Females
Total
19815918211,4125938231,416
19866499091,5586659251,590
19917201,0081,7297651,0511,815
19967691,0771,8468531,1572,010
20017821,1091,8919141,2362,150
20068141,1591,9731,0021,3402,342
20118921,2582,1491,1461,5012,647

Notes:

(a) 197S was the base year for these projections.

(b) The figures include the effects of net overseas migration at an illustrative level of 50,000 p.a.

(c) Series 'A' projections assume adult mortality to be constant at the level for 1975-76.

(d) Series 'D' projections assume a decline of 1.5 per cent a year in the 1975-76 mortality rates.

Source:  Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1979:  Projections of the Population
of the States and Territories of Australia, 1978-2011
, Catalogue No. 3214.0.


In the 1980s, the age group 65+ could be the fastest growing segment of the Australian population with a projected average annual growth rate almost double the national one (Table 5).  In the 1990s, the rate of growth of the elderly population should fall temporarily as the small cohorts born during the "birth dearth" of the 1930s reach old age, but in the first three decades of the next century, the growth rate of the elderly population will rise again as the large cohorts born in the "baby boom" pass age 65 -- between the years 2011 and 2026.  The figures in Table 5 are most tentative for the two youngest age groups because of the difficulties of anticipating annual births and net immigration, although some might regard the statistics for the two oldest age groups as conservative estimates in view of recent mortality changes.  Nevertheless, the projections demonstrate that in Australia, where the small family system prevails and the proportion marrying is unlikely to rise significantly, the greatest potential for growth inherent in the age structure is in the numbers of the middle aged and the elderly.

TABLE 5:  Projected Annual Average Growth Rates* of Major Age Groups in Australia, 1981-2011

Period
Age1981-911991-20112001-2011
 0-140.40.9O.1
15-441.30.40.4
45-64i.l2.31.8
65+2.00.91.3
Total1.11.00.8

*exponential growth rates.

Note:  These are Series 'A' projections, inclusive of migration.

Source:  Calculated from Australian Bureau of Statistics, Projections of the Population
of the States and Territories of Australia, 1978-2011
, Catalogue No. 3214.0, p.14.


Those who view the Series "A" projections (Table 4) as overly conservative, draw attention to recent changes in age-specific mortality in Australia and in other industrialised countries (Myers, 1979).  Until the 1970s, it appeared that a plateau had been reached in mortality rates at middle and later ages, but during that decade the rates declined (Table 6).  Various explanations have been offered, including improved survival from diseases of the heart, healthier lifestyles, and a lessening of life stresses, since for example only a small proportion of surviving adults were affected by the First World War.  None of the arguments are conclusive and it is unknown how long the improvements shown in Table 6 will continue, and whether those who have had better survival in one period will subsequently have poorer survival rates.

TABLE 6:  Age-Specific Death Rates (a)

Age1921-25 (b)19721978
Males60-6428.127.122.5
65-6941.541.135.7
70-7463.564.953.4
75-79101.1100.387.3
80-84160.0147.1122.6
85+305.2238.6212.6
Females60-6419.312.711.2
65-6930.320.317.0
70-7449.034.628.2
75-7983.459.648.0
80-84138.6102.380.7
85+264.7188.8177.2

Notes:

(a) Rates per thousand population of the same age and sex.

(b) Average annual rate.

Source:  A.B.S. Deaths, 1978, Cat No. 3302.0, p.7.


The Series "D" projections in Table 4 assume a continuing decline in adult mortality, yielding a population of over 2.1 million elderly at the turn of the century.  The Series "D" figure for 2001 exceeds the Series "A" projection by nearly 260,000, and the realisation of Series "D" would necessarily entail a much greater cost in providing for the aged.  However, the continuous improvement in survival assumed in Series "D" is unlikely to be realised because of an expected drop in the rate of mortality decline (Young and Ruzicka, 1980:10).  The two sets of projections in Table 4 might be taken as defining the range within which the numbers of the elderly will fall.  Evidence presented to the United States Select Committee on Population (1978) emphasised the need for a range of projections of the elderly to reflect the uncertainty surrounding future changes in mortality.  This observation is equally applicable to Australia, and planning for the elderly will need to be flexible enough to meet variations within the projected range:  there is not enough evidence to adopt any one projection as a prediction.

Changes in life expectancy, as shown in Table 2, reflect that greater proportions of people are surviving to older ages, rather than an extension of the "normal" life span (Borrie, 1979:18).  The best guide to future life expectancy are estimates based on the experience of birth cohorts, and these confirm an absence of a substantial extension of life at older ages.  Young and Ruzicka (1980) demonstrated that the life expectancy at age 60 of males born in 1900 was 15.4 years, and they estimated that the corresponding figure for males born in 1960 will be 17.3 years.  Life expectancy of females does show an improvement at age 60 from, 19.8 years (1900 birth cohort) to 23.8 years (1960 birth cohort), and although the changes are gradual any prolongation of life necessarily heightens government expenditure on pensions and benefits.

Differences in the life expectancy of men and women are one of the major causes of concern, as well as of hope for future improvement, since these differences, compounded by age differences between husbands and wives, result in the loss of support from the spouse, prolonged widowhood and heightened dependency on other family members and organisations.  The higher mortality of elderly males is due to their greater susceptibility to the "degenerative" diseases of later life, although there is debate over the relative effects of lifestyles -- including smoking habits -- and biological factors in causing this susceptibility (Lopez and Ruzicka, 1977:82-88).


INCOME MAINTENANCE

Despite uncertainty about the future numbers of the elderly, it is clear that the next two decades hold the prospect of major increases in expenditure upon them.  This situation is due to a combination of factors including the greater relative size of the fourth generation, the increasing numbers over 65 years old, and changes in the composition of the elderly population.  In addition to these demographic forces prompting heightened expenditure, future policy changes could add greatly to the costs of providing for the aged, particularly in view of the existing latitude for improvement.  Indeed, during the 1970s policy changes, especially increases in pension rates and a relaxation of the means test on age pensions, outweighed the contribution of demographic factors to the real growth of expenditure;  for example, the population of pensionable age grew by 2.6 per cent per annum 1971-79 while the number of age pensioners grew by 6 per cent per annum (Dixon and Foster, 1980:10-11).

Extension of eligibility, however, is only one dimension of improved provision for the aged, another being increases in the value of pensions in relation to prevailing living standards.  While "poverty lines" provide guidance on the maintenance of pension payments to subsistence level, they are an "austere standard" above which an affluent country could aspire to rise.  Some have argued that social integration is a desirable goal in policy formulation concerning the aged, providing maximum opportunity for the aged to participate in and contribute to society (United Nations, 1975:25 and 51).  The National Superannuation Committee of Inquiry (1976:20-21) echoed this view in their reference to "belonging" as an objective:

We regard the distinction between subsistence and belonging as a useful characterisation of alternative sets of attitudes to social welfare policy.  Support for the present austere and means-tested age pension seems to us to accord more nearly with the goal of subsistence then with the goal of belonging, whereas the emphasis of the recommended National Superannuation Scheme is the reverse.  Because of the imprecision of the concepts, this distinction does not carry the argument very far.  Nevertheless it can be said that the income levels envisaged for the National Superannuation Scheme will enable Australia's elderly citizens to "belong" more fully than they can at present or are likely to do unless the available funds are augmented by contributions.  Their opportunities to "take a moderate part in those activities which the ordinary (Australian) takes part in as a matter of course" will be significantly enhanced.

The means of financing such a goal is a subject of debate, but it is at least clear that in demographic terms the opportunities for the provision of improved income security, as well as saving for future needs, are more favourable now than they will be in the future (National Superannuation Committee, 1976:40).  This is because for the rest of the century Australia will have a relatively small elderly population compared with the number of working age, but the "economic dependency ratio" will almost certainly deteriorate in the next century, reducing the number of potential contributors per potential recipient of welfare payments.

Dependency ratios, calculated from the Series "A" projections, confirm the relatively favourable demographic context for increased financial provision for the aged;  between 1981 and 2001 the ratio of aged persons to persons in the working ages (15-64 years) are projected to rise only slightly from 15 to 16 per hundred, while the ratio of children (0-14 years) to working aged persons will fall from 38 to 35.  The overall demographic dependency ratio (the ratio of persons 0-14 and 65+ to persons 15-64) is likely to remain between 53 and 51 dependants per hundred non-dependants until 2001.  Thus Australia faces a respite during which savings could be accumulated before the "burden of the aged" rises in the next century.  Demographic dependency ratios are only a crude measure of the ratio of dependants to supporters since they ignore, for example, that many in the working ages are not economically active -- including housewives, students, the unemployed and the sick.  Nevertheless, a refinement of this ratio to include only labour force members also reveals little change in the levels of age dependency this century (National Superannuation Committee, 1976:44).

Demographic ageing introduces the prospect of a diversion of resources from the young to the old, thereby potentially avoiding heightened expenditure on dependent age groups.  Yet this outlook is uncertain because, on the one hand, some believe the costs of children are smaller than those of the old, and that the family bears the majority of the costs of children (Sauvy, 1969:311).  Jones (1980:80) quoted American estimates that average per capita public expenditure on the aged is about three times greater than expenditure on a child.  On the other hand, the per capita costs of age dependency could fall if future generations of the elderly are healthier, if retirement ages increase as they have in other ageing populations, if the pensionable age of women is raised from 60 to 65 -- as advocated both in the Poverty Inquiry and in the National Superannuation Inquiry, and if more opportunities are created enabling the elderly to do part-time work.  Part-time work for the elderly has been advocated as a way of supplementing subsistence level pensions (Commission of Inquiry into Poverty, 1975:236) and as a means of enabling those who wish to work to maintain a sense of participation in society -- at the same time making retirement a less abrupt transition, with consequent benefits for morale and health as well as for income.

Supplementation of income from pensions, or higher pensions, are necessary since the elderly who depend solely for their income on social security payments are among the poorest in society.  The Poverty Inquiry found that the elderly comprise the largest group in poverty in Australia in 1973, although the aged married couples and home owners had greater economic security than single pensioners and renters (Commission of Inquiry into Poverty, 1975:234-5).  The aged in economic jeopardy generally include those who lack the foresight or the financial means to prepare for their own old age by purchasing a home, contributing to a superannuation scheme or saving through investments which keep pace with inflation:  poverty or a subsistence existence has commonly been the lot of the elderly who have not provided for themselves or who did not expect to live so long.

From the Australian Bureau of Statistics income survey of 1973, Henderson calculated that 7.6 per cent of the non-institutionalised elderly were below the poverty line, although he noted that a further 8 to 9 per cent of institutionalised elderly "income units" included "many frail but alert elderly people who hand over their entire income in return for somewhat less than the bare necessities of life" (Commission of Inquiry into Poverty, 1975:240).  Government action following the Poverty Inquiry's recommendation that pensions for the aged be raised has resulted in an improvement in pension rates (Table 7).  Yet further substantial increases in the age pension would be needed to reach the rate of 30 per cent of average weekly earnings, advocated in the report of the National Superannuation Committee, to achieve the goal of "belonging" as opposed to subsistence.

TABLE 7:  Age and Invalid Pension as a Percentage of Average Weekly Earnings

Standard RateMarried Rate
197019.016.8
197118.216.2
197219.116.7
197320.117.5
197420.618.0
197523.419.5
197623.019.1
197723.719.8
197823.919.9
197923.019.2
1980*24.120.1

* projected

Note:  In May 1980 the standard age pension rate was $61.05 per week while the married rate (per partner) was $50.85.  The pension for widows (without dependant children) was the same as the standard age pension.

Source:  Dixon and Foster (1980:  Tables 8 and 9)


Many of the elderly, however, have already achieved this goal in economic terms because of their other sources of income, as illustrated by the statistics in Table 8.  Although these figures are dated, they indicate relativity between groups, showing for instance that those most reliant on pensions -- which included 85 per cent of elderly females -- had the lowest median incomes, amounting to far less than half the median income of persons receiving superannuation.  Occupational superannuation clearly provides greater financial security after retirement but its coverage is most uneven, being especially biased towards persons in stable employment.  In 1974, superannuation cover extended to 36 per cent of employed men compared with 15 per cent of employed women, and 58 per cent of government employees compared with 24 per cent of employees in the private sector (National Superannuation Committee, 1976:46).  Thus arises a major dilemma in income maintenance for the aged:  whether to make universal provision for the aged at a higher level or to adopt a selective approach focusing on the most disadvantaged.

TABLE 8:  Sources of Income of the Non-Institutionalised Population Aged 65 and Over, 1973-74

Principle Source of IncomeNumbers ('000)Median Annual Income ($)
MalesFemalesMalesFemales
Wages or salary66.313.84,8103,980
Own business, trade or profession15.7*5,320*
Share in partnership15.79.74,3503,050
Government social service benefits280.9493.61,2601,280
Superannuation or annuity29.410.34,2003,090
Interest, rent, dividends, etc.33.844.53,4302,260
Other income*4.6*3,850
Total444.0579.91,5001,300
Median Income of total population aged 15+5,3801,370
Median income of wage and salary earners aged 15+5,7603,080

* Figures subject to high sampling variability

Source:  Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1976:  Income Distribution, 1973-74, Part 1, pp.20-21


Despite the low value of age pensions in comparison with average weekly earnings, government expenditure on age pensions and supplementary benefits totalled more than 63 million dollars per week at 30 June 1979 (Department of Social Security, 1980:8) and represented 10.9 per cent of total Commonwealth budget outlays for 1978-79, compared with 7.2 per cent in 1970-71 (Dixon and Foster, 1980:  Table 5).  Since the numbers entitled to age pensions under existing arrangements will have increased by approximately 28 per cent by the end of the century (Dixon and Foster, 1980:  Table 5), dramatic increases in government outlays on income maintenance for the aged may be expected, even without an improvement in the purchasing power of the pension.


HEALTH

Income support for the aged is the largest component of social security expenditure in Australia but the aged also account for a high proportion of other welfare costs, especially in the provision of health services (Jones, 1980:80).  The proportion of the total health budget spent on the aged in Australia is unknown, although in the United States one estimate is that the elderly, who comprised 11 per cent of the total population, accounted for 29 per cent of health care costs (Kane et. al., 1980:1327).  Increasing numbers of the elderly augur heightened expenditure on health, not only because of the greater prevalence of illnesses of older ages, but also because increasing numbers are in the last year of life, the period when hospital and medical services are probably used most intensively.  Australian life tables show, for example, that the proportion of men likely to die before their next birthday rises from 1.4 per cent at age 55 to 3.5 per cent at 65 and 8.3 per cent at 75 years.  Overall, approximately 36 per cent of Australian male residents aged 65 and over in 1971 had died by 1976.  Hospitalisation rates increase with age, and at ages 70 and over they are generally two or three times higher than for persons in their fifties (ABS, 1978:38).  In Queensland, in 1978, males aged 65+ comprised 4.2 per cent of the total male population but accounted for 19.7 per cent of hospital discharges, transfers and deaths of males, although repeated admissions complicate these data (ABS, 1980a:18-19).

The 1976 Census recorded that a quarter of all people aged 65 years or more reported that they were "handicapped" in one or more ways, compared with 9 per cent of the total population, a handicap being defined as "a serious long-term illness or physical or mental condition".  While this information is subjective and imprecise, limiting illnesses are more prevalent at advanced ages, often necessitating increased dependence on others for support.  Statistics in Table 9 indicate the greater incidence of handicaps and chronic conditions among the "old-old" compared with the "young-old" (65-74 years).  Yet the figures suggest that although around two-thirds of the non-institutionalised elderly suffer from a chronic illness, injury or impairment, the great majority are able to maintain their independence.  Those living in institutions -- hospitals, nursing homes and homes for the aged -- comprise about 3.4 per cent of the "young-old", 15.6 per cent of the "old-old" and 7.8 per cent of the total population 65 years and over.  The main chronic conditions affecting the elderly as a whole are impairments of vision and hearing (12 per cent affected), circulatory diseases (32 per cent), respiratory diseases (10 per cent), and diseases of the musculoskeletal system and connective tissue (22 per cent);  within the last group arthritis was reported to have affected 16 per cent of the elderly.  Given the need for a continuous increase in the provision of health services to the aged during the next 50 years, the issue awaiting resolution is how best to meet this need without undue expense and without undue emotional stress for the aged.

TABLE 9:  Percentages of Non-Institutionalised Population Handicapped
Because of Chronic Illnesses, Injuries and Impairments, 1974

HandicapMalesFemales
65-7475+65-7475+
In social or recreational activities19291626
In acts of daily living4828
In getting about alone615820
In ability to do housework441020
Total with a chronic illness, etc.56685867
Total with a chronic limiting illness, etc.29412643

Source:  Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1976:  Chronic
Illnesses, Injuries and Impairments, May 1974, Ref. No. 17.3.


The problems of the aged in Australia are under-researched and the current level of professional training in gerontology and geriatrics is probably insufficient for future needs.  One consideration in determining future manpower requirements in geriatrics should be the extent to which domiciliary care is adopted where feasible as an alternative to institutionalisation.  The literature stresses the importance of family members in supporting aged relatives and policies to assist the family in continuing this role are widely advocated (Howe, 1979).  For some, institutionalisation can be a traumatic and even fatal experience and may be unnecessary if adequate provision is made to maintain the elderly in their own homes.

Many have argued that domiciliary care should be the focus of programmes for the care of the aged, pointing out the potential cost savings and personal advantages of this approach (Australian Government Social Welfare Commission, 1975;  Committee on the Care of the Aged and the Infirm, 1977).  The relative costs of domiciliary and institutional care vary according to the degree of residential concentration of the elderly population, the quality of care provided, the patient's level of disability and his or her living arrangements, so great being the potential variation in these that costs cannot be compared for patients in general (Committee on the Care of the Aged and Infirm, 1977:41;  Doobov, 1980).

...  for the great majority of patients for whom the choice is home care or nursing home care the cost of providing home care services (i.e. not including the cost of housing, food, fuel, etc.) is less than the fee homes.  The resource cost of home care (i.e. including the cost of housing, food and fuel) is less than the nursing home charge for a smaller proportion of patients.  If the measure of the cost of home care were to include, in addition to the resource cost, a notional cost for the time spent by family and friends in caring for the patient, then home care so measured would cost less than the nursing home charge for a still smaller proportion of patients (Doobov, 1980:4-5).

Doobov (1980:3) suggested, from evidence in the literature, that about 25 per cent of patients in nursing homes and 10-33 per cent of patients in hospitals could be treated satisfactorily in their homes if suitable domiciliary care services were available.  Moreover, although the relative costs of home, nursing home and hospital care vary from person to person, he observed that the "resource cost" of home care is always much less than that of hospitals, and less than that for nursing homes for the majority of patients living with a spouse or other family members.  For patients who lived alone, however, the resource cost of domiciliary care was likely to exceed that of nursing home care.

These findings emphasise the need for flexibility in care provision, providing alternatives to suit individual circumstances, but attempting where possible to meet the wishes of the patient.  A greater emphasis on domiciliary care might result in some savings in expenditure on health, although the main criterion in determining the type of care should be not cost or convenience but the well-being of the patient.  Extension of home care for the disabled elderly entails the development of community-based, rather than centralised, services and programme development along such lines requires more information than is currently available about the distribution of services, the changing distribution of the elderly, the needs of those who care for elderly relatives, and the preferences of the elderly concerning domiciliary and institutional care.


CONCLUSION

Some of the main issues in the ageing of Australia's population arise from the growing numbers and percentages of the elderly and from the associated increasing cost of health and welfare.  Questions needing further inquiry include:  How to fund future cost increases.  Whether to advocate selective income maintenance programmes for the disadvantaged or programmes for all the aged.  How to assess the requirements of the aged and lessen the emphasis on institutional care in favour of domiciliary care.  And how to provide better support for family members looking after elderly relatives.  Yet in addition to these there are many other unanswered questions about the diverse and changing characteristics of the aged, essentially reflecting that the the scientific study of the old is very young in Australia.  Above all, there is a need to dispel misconceptions about the elderly and their families because public and private action based on inadequate information is unlikely to serve people's best interests.  The contribution of the elderly is often under-rated while their problems are often over-rated:  It is important to recognise that the majority of the elderly are not spectators on the sidelines, rather they are sixty-five not out.


ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

I am grateful to D.M. Gibson and H.L. Kendig for their comments on a draft of this paper.  The final version, however, is my own responsibility.


REFERENCES

Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1978, Social Indicators, No.2, Catalogue No. 4101.0.  Australian Bureau of Statistics, Canberra.

Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1980a, Hospital Morbidity, Queensland, 1978, Catalogue No. 4303.3.  Australian Bureau of Statistics, Queensland.

Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1980b, The Labour Force, Australia, July 1980, Catalogue No. 6203.0.  Australian Bureau of Statistics, Canberra.

Australian Catholic Social Welfare Commission, 1980, Report of the National Consultation on the Family 1979.  Australian Catholic Social Welfare Commission, Sydney.

Australian Government Social Welfare Commission, 1975, Care of the Aged.  Australian Government Social Welfare Commission, Canberra.

Binstock, Robert H. and Shanas, Ethel (editors), 1976, Handbook of Ageing and the Social Sciences.  Van Nostrand Reinhold, New York.

Borrie, W.D., 1979, "The Demography of Ageing in Australia", in Donald et. al. (editors) pp. 15-20.

Brody, Elaine M., 1979, "Aging and the Family", The Gerontologist, 19, pp. 514-5.

Coale, Ansley J., 1964, "How a population ages or grows younger", in Freedman, Ronald (editor), Population:  the Vital Revolution, Doubleday-Anchor, New York, pp. 47-58.

Commission of Inquiry into Poverty, 1975, Poverty in Australia, First main report, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Committee on the Care of the Aged and the Infirm, 1977, Report of the Committee on the Care of the Aged and the Infirm.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Dahlin, Michel, 1980, "Perspectives on the Family Life of the Elderly in 1980", The Gerontologist.  20, pp. 99-107.

Dixon, Daryl and Foster, Chris, 1980, "Social welfare policy for a sustainable society".  Paper presented to the ANZAAS Congress, Adelaide, May 1980.

Donald, J.M.  et. al. (editors), 1979, Ageing in Australia.  Proceedings of the Satellite Conference of the 11th Congress of the International Association of Gerontology, Sydney, 1978.  Australian Association of Gerontology, Sydney.

Doobov, Allan, 1980, Relative Costs of Home Care and Nursing Home and Hospital Care in Australia, Commonwealth Department of Health, Monograph Series No. 10.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Hauser, Philip M., 1976, "Aging and World-wide Population Change", in Binstock and Shanas (editors), pp. 58-86.

Howe, Anna L., 1979, "Family Support for the Aged:  Some Evidence and Interpretation", Australian Journal of Social Issues, 14, pp. 259-273.

Jones, M.A., 1980, The Australian Welfare State.  Allan and Unwin, Sydney.

Kane, Robert et. al., 1980, "The Future Need for Geriatric Manpower in the United States", New England Journal of Medicine, 302, pp. 1327-1332.

Keyfitz, Nathan, 1971, "On the Momentum of Population Growth", Demography, 8, pp. 71-80.

Lopez, A.D, and Ruzicka, L.T., 1977, "The differential mortality of the sexes in Australia", in McGlashan N.D. (editor), Studies in Australian Mortality, University of Tasmania Environmental Studies Occasional Paper 4.  Board of Environmental Studies, University of Tasmania, Hobart.

Myers, G.C., 1979, "Recent mortality trends among the aged and their implications".  in Donald et. al. (editors), pp. 21-27.

National Population Inquiry, 1975, Population and Australia:  A Demographic Analysis and Projection.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

National Population Inquiry, 1978, Population and Australia:  Recent Demographic Trends and Their Implications, Supplementary report of the National Population Inquiry.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

National Superannuation Committee of Inquiry, 1976, A National Superannuation Scheme for Australia, Final Report of the National Superannuation Committee of Inquiry, Part One.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Ruzicka, L.T., 1977, Reflections on Zero Growth of the Australian Population, National Population Inquiry, Research Report No. 7.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Shanas, Ethel, 1968, "Health and Incapacity in Later Life", in Shanas et. al. (editors), pp. 18-48.

Shanas, Ethel et. al. (editors), 1968, Old People in Three Industrial Societies.  Routledge and Kegan Paul, London.

Shanas, Ethel and Hauser, Philip M., 1974, "Zero population growth and the family life of old people", Journal of Social Issues, 30, pp. 79-92.

Stehouwer, Jan, 1968, "The Household and Family Relations of Old People", in Shanas et, al. (editors), pp. 177-226.

Townsend, Peter, 1968, "The Structure of the Family", in Shanas et. al. (editors), pp. 132-176.

Treas, Judith, 1977, "Family support systems for the aged:  some social and demographic considerations", The Gerontologist, 17, pp. 486-491.

United Nations, 1975, The Aging:  Trends and Policies.  Department of Economic and Social Affairs (ST/ESA/22), New York.

United Nations, 1979, World Population Trends and Policies, 1977 Monitoring Report, Volume 1:  Population Trends.  Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Studies No. 62 (ST/ESA/SER.A/62), New York.

United States Congress, Select Committee on Population, 1978, Hearings before the Select Committee on Population, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session.  No. 9 Consequences of Changing US population, Volume 1 Demographics of Aging.  Government Printing Office, Washington.

Young, Christabel M., 1976, Mortality Patterns and Trends in Australia, National Population Inquiry, Research Report No. 5.  Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Young, Christabel M., 1977, The Family Life Cycle, Australian Family Formation Project, Monograph No. 6, Department of Demography.  Australian National University, Canberra.

Young, Christabel M. and Ruzicka, L.T., 1980, "Mortality", Paper presented to the ESCAP Conference on "The Population of Australia", Canberra,


Postscript by D.A. Dixon, Policy Co-ordinator,
Social Welfare Policy Secretariat, Canberra

This postscript has been prepared in response to a request for the views of the Secretariat on the issues raised by Mr. Wood.

The Secretariat welcomes the paper as a significant contribution to the public debate on social welfare policy, and agrees with the general conclusion that the next two decades hold the prospect of substantial increases in outlays on the aged.

In some important respects, the prospective financing problem is seen as being substantially greater than that described by Mr. Wood.  Key factors are:

  1. The fact that women (who have a substantially longer life expectancy than men) become eligible for an age pension five years earlier at age 60 compared with age 65 for men.  (Mr. Wood's discussion is in terms of population aged 65 or more);
  2. Compared with earlier years an increasing proportion of aged person are receiving the income tested pension.  (This is due to an easing of the means test over a number of years and the greater ease since 1976 when the means test was converted to an income test for people with substantial assets to receive an age pension);  and
  3. The fact that at least to date Australian demographers have understated the significance of the reduction in mortality rates that has been occurring in recent years.

Mr. Wood has referred to the work of Myers (1979) about recent changes in age specific mortality in Australia.  The Secretariat has commissioned further research by Professor Myers and on the basis of that research and other information on recent trends in mortality has reached the conclusion that if anything even the ABS Series D projections (see page 9) are likely to provide conservative estimates of the growth of the numbers of aged persons in Australia over the next twenty years.

The following Table shows the implications of Series D projections for the growth in the numbers of the aged in Australia over that period.  Of particular importance is what can only be described as a phenomenal increase in the numbers of the aged, particularly those aged over 85 years, which will occur.  The incidence of use of nursing home and hospital care by this segment of the population is, as emphasised by Mr. Wood, particularly high.

Projections (a) of the Composition of Aged Population (b)

Age19802000Percentage
Increase
No.No.%
Under 751,200,0001,565,000+ 30.4
75-84400,000715.000+ 78.7
85 and over94,000220,000+134.0
Total1,694,0002,500,000+ 47.5

(a) ABS Series D Population Projection

(b) Females 60 and over and Males 65 and over.


One final comment is also relevant.  Compared to many Western countries, Australia is still fortunate in having a relatively young population, which has to date reduced the financial burden of dependency.  Nevertheless there are still some 2.5 million adults and 500,000 children reliant on the Commonwealth for income support payments.  Of the adults, 1.2 million are of working age but in receipt of unemployment, or sickness benefit, invalid pension, or special benefit.  Future trends in the numbers of such pensioners and beneficiaries are difficult to predict but it is quite possible failing a major improvement in the employment situation that pressures from this quarter will add to the problems discussed by Mr. Wood.

December 1990