Tuesday, August 21, 2001

Lending a hand to the volunteers

Visiting the United States in 1831, the French political scientist Alexis de Tocqueville remarked on the spirit of community and self help that pervaded that country.  In Democracy in America he noted how citizens came together on a voluntary basis to perform tasks which they were incapable of doing as individuals.

Voluntary effort, he noted, was preferable to government action because it was usually more effective and it encouraged the development of public virtue among citizens.

Australia's political and civic traditions, unlike those of America, are based not on freedom from government, but on the idea that government is the source of most, if not all, solutions.  Although there is an active and important voluntary sector in this country, its significance as part of the social fabric usually has been ignored.

According to the most recent data from the Australian Bureau of Statistics, there are more than 5,000 not-for-profit community organisations in Australia in the welfare area alone -- providing child care, aged accommodation and general services.

The Australian belief in the efficacy of government over voluntary, private effort has dominated policy discussion.  Perhaps typically, it took a sporting event, the Sydney Olympic Games, for volunteers to be recognised for their contribution.

This is the context of the controversy about Peter Costello's remarks last week on volunteers.  Instead of being praised for putting the issue on the public agenda, the Treasurer was criticised for not doing enough for volunteers.  There was a concern expressed that even by raising the issue, the Government was seeking to shirk its responsibilities.

In Australia the desire to protect the central position of the government in not only funding, but also delivering, welfare has restricted debate about the role of volunteers in the community.  In Europe and North America, voluntary effort is coming to be seen as a way of building what is now called social capital and of overcoming some of the failures of the welfare state.

Harvard professor Robert Putnam's Bowling Alone in the mid-1990s chronicled the decline of the spirit of community in the United States.  It focused attention on the decline of voluntary participation.

And according to Anthony Giddens, from the London School of Economics, the doyen of the "third way" and hero to Tony Blair:  "Church, family and friends are the main sources of social solidarity.  The State should step in only when those institutions don't fully live up to their obligations".

Costello has performed an important public service in raising the issue of volunteers.  The debate that will ensue about the role of volunteers must also involve discussion of the broader question of what is appropriate for government to deliver and what could be provided by the private voluntary sector.

As Ronald Reagan said in 1981:  "We have let government take away those things that were once ours to do voluntarily".  The question now for Australia is to decide whether some of those things that the government has taken away should be given back.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, August 19, 2001

Deals May Save Dollars

A conference in Melbourne this week addressed the issue of "public private partnerships" in infrastructure:  roads, schools, hospitals, rail facilities etc.  These partnerships are designed to maintain some of the impetus of privatisation.

Since the early 1990s over $90 billion of Australian publicly owned entities have been sold into the private sector.  Victoria was responsible for a third, mainly comprising the gas and electricity sales.

Privatisation has been an immense blessing.  It has been part of the range of micro-economic reforms that constitute the much loathed "economic rationalism".  As such, it has helped shift Australian productivity growth from among the worst in the world to among the best.  It has given the economy the flexibility to allow it to thrive when our major trading partners had gone into a series of tailspins.

If the political will to privatisations has waned, private partnerships allow some of the momentum of this process to be maintained.  They lasso to the public sector some of the cost savings and innovation seen in private enterprise.

Of great importance in this respect is the need to have full transparency.  Dealings by government cannot be like dealings by BHP.  Government does not have the discipline of profit results and owners who can sell in the event of poor performance, a feature that makes business intrinsically more efficient than government.

The public criticism that continually confronted the previous government with regard to the Casino deal was made possible because the deal was undertaken in greater secrecy than occurred with the electricity privatisations.  Those opposed to privatisation were able to harp on aspects of the deal that were never made public.  In the event, after years of trying to uncover supposed political payback nothing has come to light.  However, the issue allowed massive scope for the pro-government ownership cadres to ventilate their prejudices.

This provides a message in all government dealings and one that the present government appears to have learned well:  all dealings must be out in the open.

A final note of caution.

Private public partnerships also offer risks to public efficiency.  The outsourcing of schools, hospitals, law courts and the like may become a hidden way of increasing public spending.  Contracting out to the private sector allows governments to give the impression of controlling spending while some big ticket capital items are off the budget and being paid for over decades rather than in one year.

In addition, will public private partnerships live up to their potential?  To be sure, governments can utilise public/ private partnerships to have a building constructed and leased back to them.  But is this enough to justify the programme?  The real economies are in operations, which often means escaping the yoke of union conditions.  Will the government come at that?  Will the government say to MLC or Caulfield Grammar "We'll outsource the building, operation and ownership of schools in Victoria to you"?

It may well outsource law courts as buildings or negotiate a long term lease on a school but if that is all that is entailed this is a pale imitation of the potentialities available.


ADVERTISEMENT

Time to Bury the Genocide Corpse

The question of "genocide" in Australia's past is one that will not go away.  A fortnight ago, the Courier-Mail published a substantial extract from An Indelible Stain?, an informative new book on the issue by the distinguished historian Henry Reynolds.

As well as discussing such notorious 19th century cases as Tasmania's "Black Line", and Queensland's "dispersals" of Aborigines, Reynolds presents the appropriate historical context for certain later policies which, while easy to condemn now, seemed altruistic and progressive when introduced.  This should serve as a warning that future generations, seeking to denigrate the past as a painless way of establishing their own virtue, might similarly think that programs favoured by today's moral elites were reprehensible.

Unfortunately however, Professor Reynolds couldn't resist the unwarranted and partisan concluding comment that, without self-government and constitutionally guaranteed indigenous rights, the "disappearance of the Aborigines may yet come to pass".  And while An Indelible Stain? is worth reading, it suffers from some of the same evasions that characterise nearly all the writings from Australia's burgeoning genocide studies industry.

There are two important matters that must be addressed by people who wish to argue that the Convention on Genocide may have been breached in this country, either on a retrospective basis, or after its adoption by the United Nations in 1948.  Unless these matters are dealt with properly, it is reasonable to assume that the real objective of those who raise the spectre of Australian "genocide" is to deliver a metaphorical kick in the guts to the usual objects of fashionable loathing -- conservative Anglo-Celtic nation builders.

The first is whether any of the indigenous inhabitants of Australia have ever committed acts that might possibly be seen as genocide.  In the Convention this is defined as the "intent to destroy, in whole or in part, a national, ethnical, racial or religious group, as such", through any one of five different actions, the first of which is "killing members of the group".

Given the small size of Aboriginal groups, Professor Reynolds' contention that some white massacres of Aborigines were "genocidal" is plausible, because they resulted in the effective destruction of people with distinctive traditions, the equivalent of Western nations or ethnic groups.  But if we accept this point, it may be necessary to accept that certain massacres perpetrated by one group of Aborigines against another should similarly be seen as "genocidal".

One example might be the Irbmangkara massacre, which occurred just before the white settlement of Aranda country in Central Australia.  As recounted by the anthropologist T.G.H. Strehlow, in his book Journey to Horseshoe Bend, over 100 men, women and children from a particular group were killed by members of another group because of an act of sacrilege that had supposedly been carried out by one of the victims.

Other kinds of killings might also be thought of as coming under the definition of genocide.  The initial response of different Aboriginal groups towards mixed race babies varied considerably.  But in a number of areas they were killed, as the writings of some Aborigines themselves attest -- such as the memoirs of the Yorta Yorta woman Theresa Clements, From Old Maloga.  The infants seem to have been killed only because elders saw them as being members of a different racial group.

If, as Professor Reynolds and others argue, pre-war Aboriginal affairs officials such as A.O. Neville and Cecil Cook who spoke of "breeding out the colour", were guilty of "genocidal objectives", how should we view Aborigines who tried to "remove the white" through infanticide?  One prominent Melbourne academic to whom I put this question responded that it was only modern intellectuals who had genocidal thoughts, not tribal elders.

This leads to the second matter which the genocide industry needs to address.  Another of the five actions defined as "genocide" by the Convention is "imposing measures intended to prevent births within the group".

On this basis, radical Aborigines, together with their counterparts in America and the Third World, have long argued that family planning programs directed at them are motivated by "genocidal" attitudes.  As they see it, these programs have little to do with providing disadvantaged women with new opportunities for reproductive choice, and a great deal to do with limiting the number of non-whites in the world.

As fanciful as this may seem, there are actually some grounds for their suspicions.  The intellectual foundations of the post-World War II concerns about the "population explosion" are quite unsavoury.  Many who promoted these concerns had been involved in the earlier eugenics movement, which tried to discourage people of "inferior stock" from breeding, and which successfully campaigned to introduce sterilisation laws in many countries.

It is not hard to find objectionable racist notions in the seminal texts on "overpopulation".  In the enormously influential 1948 book, Road to Survival, William Vogt wrote that it would be a tragedy if China experienced "a reduction in her death rate".  And Paul Ehrlich's 1968 description in The Population Bomb of how he first gained an emotional understanding of the "population explosion" as a result of experiencing the crowded streets of Delhi, expresses what can only be called a revulsion towards Indians.

So if it is reasonable to suggest that Australian bureaucrats like Neville or Cook held "genocidal objectives", we should also seriously consider whether similar objectives motivated many of the prominent advocates of the population control movement.  Or perhaps we would all be better served by giving the whole debate on Australian "genocide" a dignified burial.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, August 18, 2001

Options for the Review of Standing Offer Tariffs for Victoria's Retail Electricity

Submission to the ORG:  Options for the Review
of Standing Offer Tariffs for Retail Electricity


INTRODUCTORY COMMENTS

MARKETS AND EFFICIENCY

Promotion of efficiency in markets is predicated on two features:  strong property rights and vigorous competition.

Strong property rights are essential to ensure that sellers are able to keep the profits their activities generate.  As a corollary, they must also face the likelihood of losses from taking the wrong decisions, losses that can lead to bankruptcy in extreme situations.  This property rights perspective forces sellers at every stage of the market process to ensure that customers' needs are researched and met at the lowest cost.

Competition is essential as a discipline on this process.  Without a competitor fully able and anxious to step in to supply the incumbent's market, the latter's motivation to continually search out new needs and cheaper ways of meeting them is blunted.  Indeed, a seller with an entrenched monopoly will raise prices and reduce sales beyond the level at which additional revenue covers costs, secure in the knowledge that a rival would be unable to undercut the price.

This process of competition is now generally accepted as offering the best means of setting the price and quality mix that gives consumers the best value.  It operates in both the static sense of bringing about the lowest cost outcomes for a given set of demand and supply configurations and in the dynamic sense of encouraging a ceaseless search for improving upon this in the light of shifting demands and input costs.

All regulatory bodies claim that they are seeking to replicate this competitive outcome in the context of a market in which there are some natural monopoly elements that require synthetic costs to be developed.  Hardly any authority would nowadays claim that regulatory overrides offer superior outcomes to those of a free and competitive market.  Regulators simply do not have the capability to assemble and process the information that profit-driven suppliers routinely undertake.

Hence, in the light of regulatory deficiencies, to legitimise intrusions, not only must there be such imperfections but the regulator must also be able to bring improved outcomes.  As Epstein (1) puts it,

"... regulation must be justified on the grounds that any monopolist charges too much and sells too little relative to the social -- that is the competitive -- optimum.  But even when true, the case for regulation is hardly ironclad.  The situational monopoly may confer only limited pricing power, and its durability could be cut short by new entry, or by technical innovation.  Regulation could easily cost more than it is worth, especially if the regulation entrenches present forms of production against the innovation needed to undermine its economic dominance." (p. 284)

Importantly, these remarks, and much of the literature counselling caution in introducing regulation, as well as Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act and Australian State based regulation concern situations where there is a monopoly underpinned by an "essential facility".  The case for regulation where there is no such natural monopoly is even more controversial.  Regulation in such situations rests on market dominance buttressed by some means by which new entrants are prevented.

These situations pertain to where a firm has gained for itself a dominance over a market as a result of its superior long-term performance or through having been given some initial legislative monopoly.  The obvious means of countering them are to ensure a market opening or to require the dominant firm to be divided.  In either case there are dangers to efficiency:  splitting up a firm that has gained a dominant position may mean reducing productivity and raising prices, while forcibly opening a market can disadvantage the incumbent firm, again to the detriment of economic efficiency.


REGULATORY INTERVENTIONS IN NETWORKS

Some background to the present reference stems from the treatment of electricity and other formerly integrated networks in Australia and other jurisdictions.

Where tranches of larger customers were opened in electricity and gas markets and retail competition commenced in telecommunications, other than to ensure that customers were properly informed and could transfer effortlessly to competing suppliers, there were no particular measures taken by governments to reinforce the natural rivalry that profitable opportunities bring.  In other cases, as with the opening up of US long distance telephony to new carriers, the dominant incumbent was at first obliged to take actions like publishing prices in advance and not being able to amend those prices to respond quickly to competitive reactions.  These measures, designed to give an advantage to new players, were strongly criticised.

A price cap on the incumbent has accompanied the recent UK electricity and gas retail deregulation at the household level.  As with US telecom openings this was motivated by the wish to promote competitive responses.  The concern has also been to prevent the dominant firm from being able to unfairly exploit its position with the incumbent customers.

Other intervention has been motivated by concerns about market distortions that may result from a market structure that falls short of monopoly.  This has been prominent in the US, where analysis has focused on the degree of concentration in markets.  A measure of market power, the Hirfindahl-Hirschman index, was first applied by the United States Department of Justice following its 1986 report on gas pipelines (see Laine). (2)  This takes as a proxy the existence of four similarly sized firms as providing a low risk of the exercise of market power.

While the existence of many players offer better competitive pressures than few, the application of oligopoly based analysis is highly controversial.  The requirement of a large number of players has often proven to be unnecessary.  This is evidenced in the vigorous competition in the soft drink industry where Coke and Pepsi are clearly dominant worldwide.  In Australia's domestic airline industry, the existence of just two competitors, periodically challenged by new entrants has (once the Government exited from the industry's control) proven sufficient to ensure highly competitive prices and services.  Similar conditions are found in the beer industry, while sales of distilled spirits in Australia are dominated by one firm without this bringing evidence of monopolistic practices.

Hence, even if there are only two firms or a single dominant firm operating in a market which can be readily contested, this is often sufficient to ensure against monopoly and prevent price gouging and other forms of consumer exploitation.  As Epstein and others have maintained, the onus is on the regulatory authorities to demonstrate they can ensure a superior outcome.


THE ROLE OF THE ELECTRICITY RETAILER

Under competitive circumstances, the retailer is the de facto agent of the consumer.  That role is assumed of necessity -- if abandoned or neglected a rival will step in.  The retailer's activities, to ensure its on-going success and even its existence, must extend far beyond passively breaking down bulk and ensuring products are delivered at convenient locations.  It must extend to assisting in discovering what the consumer wants.  Unlike self selected (and often government financed) consumer "representational" bodies the retailer is compelled to be the agent of the consumer, as long as the consumer can move to an alternative agent if the retailer provides unsatisfactory service.

The retailer is an agent in a far more comprehensive sense than any representative body because it needs to weigh up the needs against the available product inputs -- and to do so correctly or face replacement.  The retailer is under great pressure to seek out inputs from all sources.

The homogenous nature of electricity does not negate this.  Electricity may be undifferentiable but its supply is from highly variable sources.  In terms of assembling inputs, the retailer must decide, based on its customers' requirements (and those of its target customers):

  • how much power to contract rather than buy at pool
  • how much of different sorts of power (baseload, regular peak, needle peak) to buy
  • how much price risk to take for the needle peak.

In addition, this basic product has to be metered correctly, bundled in profitable packages, promoted to consumers who may have little awareness of their needs and options, and priced appropriately.  The retailer also needs to examine economies of scope (or synergies) in bundling his goods together with other similar products, sharing services of specialists like meter readers, back office functions etc..

Competition between retailers does tend to ensure that, for a given quality, products are purchased from the cheapest producers and sold on to customers at margins that are not excessive in relation to efficient retailers' costs.  Competition is also, and perhaps fundamentally, a discovery process, whereby the competitors set out to ascertain the needs of customers, where those needs are not well defined nor even fully understood by the customers themselves.

The foregoing indicates the dangers of simply treating electricity retailing as an automatic function that can be easily replicated by a smart regulator.  Joskow, Hogan and others (3) have suggested that we can make do with a simple pass through tariff from wholesale and line charges to the customer.  This proposition has drawn a sharp response from Littlechild. (4)


ELECTRICITY RETAILING IN VICTORIA

Structural separation of the former Victorian electricity monopoly left the retailing and distribution businesses as jointly owned.  The two arms were required to observe a strict accounting separation in the form of a ring fence.  Two of the five businesses have since made ownership separations while two others have formed distinct businesses.  In the absence of any claims that the host distributor favours its retail arm (and no such credible claims have ever been made) there are no natural monopoly conditions.  This distinguishes retailing in the FRC era from the conditions that give rise to regulation, e.g. those under the distribution price re-set or the oversight of prices for franchised customers generally.

Two ways of viewing electricity retailing to the household customer in Victoria are either as five dominant firms with market power over their (former) exclusive territories or some form of oligopolistic competition dominated by six or seven firms who may not compete strongly with each other.  The former calls for action to protect the consumer while the latter requires measures that promote additional competition.  Neither of these views is persuasive.  The market is not an oligopoly:  the energetic steps already being taken by retailers, including non-incumbent retailers, to attract customers are evidence of this.

Procedures are in place to effect a speedy and costless transfer of a customer from its host retailer to another that is able to offer a superior price or service.  Retailing competition across the Victorian market includes the five host retailers plus two dozen others.  Competition for the household market once it becomes contestable will include all five host retailers and at least two from interstate as well as several new players.  These conditions would satisfy the Hirfindahl-Hirschman index threshold for workable competition.

There is, in short, no lack of experienced competitors and few barriers to entry.  Indeed, as in the UK, serious concern is moving to the problem of over-aggressive sales techniques and the development of a code of ethics.

The notion that the incumbents are able to exploit their current monopoly is not plausible in the Victorian retailing situation.  Hence, even if there were no trade practices legislation as an insurance for consumers, the case for regulation either to combat monopolistic pricing or promote competition is extremely slender.  Indeed, the downside rests with regulatory not market failure.


THE RATIONALE FOR PRICE CONTROLS IN VICTORIAN ELECTRICITY RETAILING

Successive tranches of retail customers have been freed to choose their own retailer in Victoria.  The process has progressed smoothly and been an integral part of the great improvement in efficiency.  It has brought reduced prices while generation was over-supplied and minimised price increases as supply/demand dynamics change.  Given this experience, there should be a strong presumption against regulated prices in the household sector.  After all, energy retailing, though it requires sophisticated systems has no entry barriers and many capable providers.  With load profiling and FRC, any attempt by an incumbent retailer to raise prices above underlying costs would invite vigorous rival entry.

However, a case can be mounted along the lines that the household sector is less well informed at the present time about the options and, having been protected by a government determined tariff for many decades, some safety net is justified for a short period.  This was certainly the view taken in the UK and has been adopted for the 40-160 MWh customers in Victoria.  It rests on a theoretical foundation somewhat akin to the provisions regarding consumer protection codified under Part V of the Trade Practices Act.

The possible exploitation rests on consumer inertia.  But unlike, say the banking industry, where there are real inconveniences to the customer changing retailer, in electricity the process is straightforward and costless.  Even so, many would argue that since the host retailer at "Day 1" has a monopoly of the current franchise customers.  This could give rise to short-sighted opportunistic behaviour. (5)  That said, it would surely need to be acknowledged that the underlying ability of the consumer to shift to any one of a great number of actual and potential alternative retailers, could never justify such oversight beyond a very short period.

There are clear dangers in overriding the forces of competition, dangers that intensify with the length of time the controls remain.  These dangers of seeking to replace or improve upon the market outcomes are adverted to in the ORG's paper.  They can be distilled into two primary failings related to where the regulator sets the controlled price too low.  Setting prices too low will:

  • require cross subsidies and either bring an unravelling of the market balance and/or lead to financial distress among retailers and inadequate incentives for new investment;  an extreme outcome of these developments is evidenced in California;  and
  • crowd out the competitive provision that is being sought forcing (reluctant) host retailers to continue serving unprofitable customers.

These considerations underline one matter on which pricing controls or guidelines must be ruled out:  the prevention of price increases on the grounds that consumers would prefer not to pay higher prices.  Already in Victoria we have put prices in place that have been regulated over the past six years with little provision having been made for the changing costs -- absolute and relative -- on which the prices were first justified.  Unless prices are allowed to adjust to the underlying cost shifts, retailing will be seriously harmed and the consumer the eventual loser.  As the minister recognises in her Terms of Reference and as the ORG is amply aware, the danger of price controls is a general competitive paralysis and even with a milder form of fixing, price capping, some risk of this remains.

It may be that the Government would wish to shield some consumers from the true market price.  If so, there are well-established means of doing so.  Requiring cross subsidies from other consumers of the product is not one of these.  The preferred approach is direct provision of support to targeted customers through CSOs.  The industry has developed procedures to deliver such support, for example with pensioner rebates.  Though far from a sound policy approach, the CSO route would be less structurally damaging than forcing retailers to bear costs or cross-subsidise.

Compared to setting the price too low, the dangers of allowing excessive prices are considerably less.  This is not the least because excessive prices bring their own remedy -- competitors find ways of winning the ostensibly captive markets.  The recent Productivity Commission draft report on Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act drew attention to this asymmetry in the context of "essential services" and advocated erring on the side of allowing a higher price rather than risking an excessively low price.  These approaches are even more appropriate in retailing which does not have the long lived capital assets of network services and consequent ability temporarily to serve customers at marginal cost.

Indeed, as soon as full retail competition is in place, it is difficult to see any scope for price setting.  Any price that is set above market levels will mean customers will be won away from the incumbent supplier by a rival seeking to take advantage of a profitable opportunity.

In fact, an existing retailer may be vulnerable to a rival who is able to better its price because the target customers are complementary to others that it presently serves.  This might allow a rival to make price offers below the cost of the incumbent even if the latter is technically efficient.


SPECIFIC QUESTIONS RAISED BY THE ORG

1. Whether "effective competition" and "outcomes consistent with those expected in a competitive market" indicate that standing offer tariffs should reflect underlying costs

Effective competition delivers the ideal outcomes in terms of price/quality mix, diversity of product offerings consistent with the costs involved.

Contrary to some paradigms, the issue is not just to arrive at the lowest cost as a result of competition driving down prices.  To be sure, the tendency towards the lowest possible price is one important outcome of competition.  But this takes place in the context of shifting needs of consumers that are often inadequately understood even by consumers themselves.  And it is a continuous process with the availability of product constantly changing.

Hence "standing offer tariffs" or the eventual price to consumers in a competitive market will only reflect underlying costs in a rough-and-ready way.

To the extent that suppliers are able to buy inputs on favourable terms, or gain insights into consumer needs not shared by their competitors, they can set prices above a stylised notion of those of a "competitive market".  However, the nature of competition means any such gains are transitory as the innovatory approach that made them possible will be quickly imitated by rival firms and the benefits passed on to consumers through competition.  The prospect of making such gains should not be eliminated as it defines the dynamics of a market.

Attempting to estimate firms' costs and use the estimate as a means of setting prices will not be successful, at least beyond a short time scale, since the costs and customer needs have to be constantly re-estimated in the light of changing needs and conditions.  It goes without saying that estimating these costs and setting consequent required price ceilings prices at too low a level will severely prejudice the operations of the host retailer.


2. Extent to which the reference point or process for any review should be adjusted to take account of the risk that standing offer tariffs set close to or below efficient costs may hinder the development of effective competition in electricity retailing.

There is increasing documentary evidence about the effects of retail price setting in liberalised industries.  This shows that tariffs set below efficient costs will completely frustrate the development of competition.

This outcome was seen in California's retail opening in 1998 where the host retailers were obliged to buy from the Power Exchange at spot, and a competitive transition charge meant there was no customer advantage in locking in future prices.  In addition, mandated price cuts, which hindsight demonstrates were set at highly optimistic levels, increased the unattractiveness of the market.  Although there was considerable interest, and Enron was aiming to take 10 per cent of the market, insignificant entry was sustained and fewer than two per cent of residential customers switched retailer.  Enron subsequently withdrew from the market in a highly public manner.

Negative margins were also seen in Massachusetts between the wholesale price and the standard offer.  Again little switching took place.

In the UK, in 1997 even though the reserve prices for the main household tariffs were set at rates below previous levels, there was an influx of competition.  The incumbent retailers in the main did not price below the maximum rate specified and on average the best offers from rival retailers bettered this by 10 per cent. (6)  This was possible because the wholesale price fell leaving considerable headroom.  The fact that the retailers set prices at the maximum permitted level might indicate that the incumbent retailers did have some transitory market power.  However, the fact that this brought them to cede share to new rivals also showed them to be exercising commercial choices.  Neither the regulator nor the government has taken the view that the community would be better served by having prices permanently regulated.

The actual rates specified after March 2000 were lowered still further (although the regulator's initially suggested reduction was pared back considerably).  The OFGEM consultation paper argued that the price restraints need to reflect the benefits being seen in the competitive market.  It has already been noted that there is wide recognition in Australia that this carries grave risk of shutting out new players and exposing the protected customers to rate shock.  The regulation of UK prices has taken place during a fall in the main cost component and about 27 per cent of customers have actually switched retailer.  However there are thought to be few prepayment meter customers who have switched since the 2000 re-set because the price has been lowered to a level that makes competitive offers difficult.  Aside from inhibiting new competition, this is likely to store up difficulties at next year's scheduled lifting of the price restraints, since it implies that prices for this (mainly low income) segment are set too low.

In Victoria, the five host retailers are all active in each other's territories, and there are at least two inter-state retailers plus a start-up retailer actively seeking business in the household sector.  Indeed, the concerns have shifted from inadequate interest to inhibiting the zeal of the sales people seeking to win consumers from their host retailers.

There should be no serious consideration of any proposals to hold tariffs below or even close to the regulator's view of what comprises efficient costs.


3. Assessing the effectiveness of competition through proxy indicators

Setting hard and fast rules to determine whether competition is effective is impossible.  It is certainly true that where there are many competitors, as in classic commodity markets, the competition is intense and the conditions bear comparison with the classic "perfect competition".  However, highly idiosyncratic products or products that require considerable capital investment or skills often have few rival suppliers but still face considerable competition for the consumer's dollar.  Reference has already been made to certain air transport markets and the soft drinks market that are highly competitive with only one or two rivals.

The main criteria for a competitive market hinge on the concept of contestability.  The concept itself is usually credited to Baumol (7) and his associates.  Contestability refers to the ease of entry into a market and the subsequent ease of exit in the event of failure.  Where firms not presently active within a market are able to enter it without incurring large sunk costs a market is likely to be competitive.  The most extreme form of contestability is hit-and-run.  Under this model, the monopolist can find the entire market lost, and the new competition can exit without loss in the event of the previous monopoly or another supplier offering superior value.

The number of competitors, average number of competitive offerings and the rate of customer churn are measures often used to assess the effectiveness of competition in markets.  While these might offer some evidence of competition, the real measure is how easy is it for firms to attack an incumbent (monopolist's) position.  The answer in electricity retailing is very easy as long as regulatory restraints do not prevent it.

In the electricity retailing market, there are some dozen or so firms of reasonable size and skills contesting the market in Australia at present.  There are others, often with considerable resources and internationally honed skills, that stand ready to move in where profitable market opportunities present themselves.  It should not be presumed that these contestants would be willing to eschew opportunities for half the total electricity market that is represented by households.

Electricity retailing, unlike poles and wires businesses, does not require a heavy capital expenditure or a commitment to employing a large labour force.  Moreover, experience has been gained into the means of winning new customers in previously demonopolised industries.  This has been pioneered in the deregulation of telephone retailing with a mixture of media advertising (though this has proven too expensive in the UK) door-to-door selling and internet and direct mail.

The best measure of the extent to which competition is effective is to examine the costs and the inconvenience to customers of changing supplier.  Customer churn or the number of offers are poor and potentially misleading substitutes for this.  The most effective task the regulatory authorities can perform in enhancing this is to ensure retail shifting is cheap and seamless.  Added to this, the ORG should consider establishing a central repository of price offers to facilitate consumer choice.

All this boils down to the familiar refrain that even the best intentioned regulator cannot process the information necessary to ensure efficient performance, and that the difficulty in doing so rises with the rate of technological and market change within the industry.  The literature on this can be traced back to Hayek (1945) through Averch and Johnston (1982).

It is also true, as all this economic theory has shown, that the power of government agencies is greater than almost any commercial power in distorting markets.  This returns us to the need to be very sure that the outcome will be one of improvement before we impose any regulation.  In this respect, the distortions resulting from the long standing regulation of household electricity prices are already becoming apparent in the earlier applications for price increases by TXU and Origin.  In particular those submissions suggested that, aside from general price movements, some fixed tariffs rates especially to rural and for off-peak have become artificially low.  Procrastination on allowing these prices better to reflect the market will intensify the later price rises and bring considerable rate shocks to consumers.


4. Circumstances where it may be appropriate for the Minister to seek a review of market tariffs

It would be a most retrograde step if the electricity market were to revert to control over those tariffs that have been freed up.  Such action is not only unnecessary and at variance with competition policy (including agreements between the Commonwealth and the States) but it would undermine the market structures that are in place.

Reversion to control, or even threat of control, over tariffs that have been liberalised would signify a reversal of the past decade's policies.  This would cause considerable loss of value within the industry, a loss of value that would be translated into reduced levels of investment in all parts of it and a degraded service.


5. Circumstances where price oversight may prevent the passing through of efficient wholesale costs

This question encapsulates the risks inherent in placing price caps on firms.  These include:

  • insufficient risk margin to cover load
  • sudden movement in costs
  • lack of recognition of costs of hedging
  • inadequate attention to load shape and seasonality (especially relevant in view of the increased peakiness of the summer load due to air conditioning)
  • incorrectly setting the load to consumers due to the deeming provisions
  • delays in price changes.

In addition, the regulator might take an inappropriate view of the costs to retailers.

The matter of the appropriate cost to use has already been considered in the context of the ORG's review of the proposed tariff increases for Origin, TXU and CitiPower.  The ORG indicated that the actual prices on the spot will be important in determining the allowed pass through.  The regulator suggested (8) that additional peak capacity becoming available is likely to dampen prices in the coming summer peak.  This presents retailers with a dilemma.  If they were to seek price pass through on the spot basis at the time this would surely not be accepted (its corollary would be a highly volatile price to consumers).

A rigorous determination of costs to establish price levels would require the regulator to duplicate the procedures undertaken by each retailer, namely to

  • match the energy levels with the available flat, peak and off-peak swap products, although with some shape mismatch even on the average demand profile;  and
  • protect most of the remaining exposures up to the maximum demand levels using cap products (rather than purchasing extra swaps for the maximum load, because the cap contract is a better match for volatile load spikes).
  • allow the extreme load spikes, occurring for only a few hours per year, to be exposed to pool pricing

Such a procedure, which was arguably necessary in the first distribution price re-set, has no possible justification for retail pricing.  Unlike with the poles and wires, there is no natural monopoly and, indeed, a key policy goal is to foster not pre-empt competition.

Having stressed the pitfalls of attempting a precise price estimation process, should some form of cap be introduced, the regulator will wish to estimate some key costs.  In obtaining some broad fix on businesses' energy costs, the regulator must use contract rather than current prices, though these can be difficult to establish.  In addition, a price index rather than the actual prices that retailers pay should be used to avoid creating moral hazard -- an indifference on the part of the retailer to the prices actually paid.

The forward prices of the standard forward products can be obtained from a variety of sources:

  • brokers' prices, based on market bids and offers, published on Reuters screens;
  • AFMA forward prices based on polling of market participants;  and
  • survey of actual contracts bought and sold by retailers.

Pulse have developed the following chart of baseload prices in Victoria over the past year.

Chart 1 -- Wholesale MarketSource:  Pulse Energy Pty Limited, Comments on the Office's Special Reference June 2001

TXU have also set out their analysts' estimates of prices in the Victorian contract market adjusted for the peak and off peak components in a submission to the ORG.  The TXU estimates are shown in Chart 2 below.

Chart 2 TXU's Estimate of Forward PricesSource:  http://svc116.bne022u.server-web.com/TXUSubPricesJun01.pdf

It would be essential for the regulator to construct such a schedule in formulating a view of the appropriate cost base.  Even so, as the foregoing has made clear, this would not be a substitute for allowing the market to set the prices.  Indeed, setting any price cap will inevitably cushion some consumers from the need to take their own decisions, an outcome that will blunt the efficiency-promoting market processes.

If the government (on the regulator's advice) decides to impose price caps on sales to small users, these should leave considerable room for new competition.  Equally importantly, they should be transitory since they cannot be justified other than on the basis of the household consumer's lack of familiarity with the notion of retail competition in electricity.  Any such lack of awareness will very soon be removed by competitive offerings and government publicity.


6. Interpretation of "light handed" regulation and attributes of a review framework that would or would not be consistent with the principle

The terms of reference stress the need to have the on-going review of standing offer tariffs to be light handed and require that the regulation itself be light handed.  Light handed regulation was a term used to describe the regulation of distribution prices.  Whatever the precise meaning of the term, few would consider the outcome of the first review during 2000 to have fitted that description.  The ORG used the term sparingly with respect to the distribution price re-set as the procedure unfolded.

Light handed regulation may have had its derivation in the New Zealand shift from a planned economy.  In that country it applied to:

  1. the use of existing competition provisions (i.e. the Commerce Act 1986) rather than specific regulations to cope with the essential facility features of the network industries;  this allowed private parties the possibility of taking court action;
  2. extensive information disclosure so that there was transparency in the performance of the electricity and gas industries;  and
  3. the threat of further regulation such as price controls if market dominance was abused.

Light handed regulation in the retailer context would seem to mean reserve power regulation:  setting prices and service quality levels that act as backstops rather than standards to be achieved.  This would exclude the ORG from certain activities either because they are non-core to the primary goal of ensuring people are not exploited or because to do so would duplicate existing institutional arrangements.  It should also be seen as a short term staging post to the full removal of the ORG from retail price oversight.

Light handed regulation should avoid prescriptive measures.  It should concentrate on:

  • Ensuring the market is informed so that consumers can take their own decisions on their electricity retailer just as they do with other intermediaries in the goods and services they buy.
  • Removing any barriers to competition meaning that the cost of and the procedures for changing retailer should be minimal.
  • Assisting commercial or charitable bodies to set themselves up advising on the best deals to be had for each customer (several such bodies already exist).  The ORG might also consider setting up such a service itself (but should bear in mind that in doing so it might "crowd out" alternative commercial services).  It should, as now, also be ready to step in to address consumer complaints (but not to duplicate the work of the Ombudsman and another body, the Essential Utility Services Consumer Advocacy Centre, that is in the process of being established).
  • Avoiding addressing supplier collusion since the ACCC is well funded and has the expertise to undertake this.
  • Setting prices, as in the UK, for just one or two common tariffs;  and setting these prices, as occurred by good fortune in the UK, at levels that give considerable scope for new competition to establish themselves especially where the incumbent is high cost or seeking to benefit from prices above costs.

7, 8 and 9 Processes and procedures that retailers presently have that could avoid unnecessary duplication and procedures to reduce compliance and administrative costs.  Insights to be drawn from the oversight of other, excluded services

No comments


10. Extent to which regulatory options for standing offer tariffs should have regard to historical trends in wholesale market prices and to forward contract prices;  the ORG also seeks comments on sources of information on forward contract prices

Historical trends are not relevant to the prices that need to be charged.  A business will always base its prices on costs (though they can deviate below costs from time to time, e.g. for promotional purposes, and can be above cost where the seller has bought or managed more skilfully than its competitors).

Constraints on price changes that can operate to the disadvantage of efficiency.  The average cost of energy exhibits a distinct seasonal trend.  This is due to the summer air conditioning load, a load that is progressively leading to a peakier demand and an increased requirement for higher cost peaking production.  An efficient response requires the elimination of cross subsidies and replacement by prices that are cost-reflective.  A cost reflective price is vital in most industries in bringing an efficient consumer response.  Electricity's notorious demand inelasticity tempers this but does not eliminate it.  Indeed, it would cause some considerable rethinking of the decision to install air conditioning and to seek out lower cost units and generally operate more frugally if the increased costs were made known to consumers in the form of price offers.

At some point in time it is likely that, even without sophisticated metering, prices will be set on a seasonal basis.  They should be so set if they are to efficiently transmit information to consumers that costs differ by time of day and time of year.

And a business that neglected to make such a tariff would tend to be stuck with the less profitable customers as result of "adverse selection".  Of course, accurate time of day metering is required for this to operate most effectively but even without this, the marked average difference in cost of energy between summer and winter should be reflected in prices.

Information on forward trends is readily available to the market participants through Reuters, AFMA and other sources.


11. Expected outcomes on the energy component of retail tariffs from a competitive energy market

As discussed under question 5, the energy component of retail tariffs would be expected to closely follow the costs of energy for that particular segment.

Retailers who did not price according to their cost curves would face "adverse selection" -- and a deluge of demand from those who were priced too low and desertion from customers who were initially cross-subsidising them.  Eventually this would drive the retailer out of business.

This process will emerge from market forces.  Any attempt by the government to impose the market outcomes it expects to emerge from this process risks severely harming retail competition.


12. Outcomes that might be expected from a competitive market in relation to the market fees component of retail tariffs and issues that should be taken into account in investigating retail tariffs that use this cost component as a reference point

The market fees cover management fees for NEMMCO and NECA, plus some specific fees for the smelter contracts.  In addition fees are required to cover costs of ancillary services, for the renewable legislation and for the cost of prudentials.

A monopoly would seek to levy these and other costs on the parties whose demand was least affected by the additional impost (Ramsey pricing).  In a competitive market the fees would need to be spread among all users to the degree they could not be identified against particular categories of user or against particular firms.

At some future time ancillary services may well be measurable by users and retailers would then find it necessary to charge in a cost reflective manner.  With the ancillary services market due to come into effect shortly, retailers may also find ways to offer services or reduce costs and these would form a (negative) part of the cost structure.  With load profiling for the under 40 MWh customers this is not possible at present and it seems likely that the approach will be a straightforward allocation by energy usage.

Some aspects of these fees are likely to impact on some market segments more than others.  Costs of the Ombudsman and costs to defray the charges to finance the Essential Utility Services Consumer Advocacy Centre and the NECA end-user advocacy facility (presently under consideration by the ACCC) are likely to be related overwhelmingly to the under 40 MWh household market.  These costs should be loaded onto this segment's tariffs and augmented by the additional burden they place on the suppliers in terms of in-house resources needed to co-ordinate with them and contest the issues they raise.

In the interests of transparency and to improve public awareness of them, consideration should be given to separately identifying these fees on bills.


13. Expected outcomes in relation to the network services component of retail tariffs

Market forces will mean network service costs will be automatically passed through.  They will vary between distribution network service providers' host territories.

Indeed, they will vary within each distribution area due to such factors as differences in line losses.

Some averaging is inevitable since there would otherwise be an unmanageable number of tariffs.  But the danger is that a retailer could subject itself to a competitor's cherry picking strategy if the averaging were too great.

Even assuming the ORG issues broad price ceilings designed to leave considerable headroom for rival retailers, there would be a need to establish different reference prices for each distribution business area and probably several prices for the two rural host retailers.  In the initial period, this might only need to take line losses into consideration, but eventually all costs of lines and service need to be allocated properly and to form the basis of price offers.


14. Outcomes of retail service costs on competitive markets and issues to take into account in retail tariffs

It is essential that no attempt be made to set a price that does other than very broadly incorporate the costs of retail services.  To do other would be to micro-manage the whole competitive system.  It would totally destroy the information search and the diversity of retail service approaches that the market is likely to require.  These retail services, together with energy costs are the key arenas in which retailers will compete.

Retailer cost structures will differ in respect to the customer groups they intend to target and the service levels they offer.  Analogous market situations can be seen to be playing out with banking.  In electricity, some retailers will seek to press personal service, others hightech service, still others may promote new products like automatic telephone induced switching on and off of heating, ovens, water sprinklers etc.


15. Practical implications of striking a balance between not hindering the development of effective competition and protection of consumers from market or monopoly power

The objective of the electricity retailing regime is not to encourage increased numbers of suppliers per se but to encourage greater efficiency and lower prices to consumers.  Just as second tier retailers are free to make rapid adjustments in the prices they offer, so should the incumbent retailer.  To do otherwise would be tilting the playing field and risking the profitability and future viability of the incumbent retailers.

In establishing approval criteria for tariff applications, the ORG should limit itself to establishing backstop tariffs with a view to their rapid phase out.  It might adopt the following procedures:

  • determine indicative rates for only one or two, common tariffs;
  • adopt rates covering the entire territories of the three urban distributors and engage in consultation with the rural distributors to agree on a minimum practical number of rates in each of their areas;
  • fix prices, ideally on a summer quarter/rest of the year basis;
  • establish the capped prices for a short period only (probably one year) so that they are reserve prices rather than prices that seek to second-guess competitive outcomes;  they should be based on:
  • the contract price for the baseload, peak and needle peak energy requirements with the contract price established at a time to be determined after consultation with retailers, allowing retailers to select an alternative basis only if they can show good cause;
  • Retailers' risk exposure, including force majeure, pricing of ancillary services, distribution loss factors, and the risk of being associated with a retailer of last resort event;
  • FRC related costs, including marketing and information systems to allow customer switching;
  • allocate other costs based on volume;  and
  • determine retail costs based on the retailer with the highest current margin.

16. The extent to which the framework for light-handed review of standing offer tariffs should address the question of whether existing tariffs are consistent with the outcomes that could be expected from a competitive market

The review has only two alternatives in establishing these prices:  roll forward the existing MUTs or set new cost related price caps.  There is no case for rolling forward existing prices.  After six years and considerable recent market turbulence they bear little relation to the underlying prices they were originally intended to reflect.

While a capping process for the household sector is not intended to fix prices, some movement towards cost reflective caps is necessary in order to prevent the retail electricity industry in Victoria from facing strained financial conditions.


17. Whether it would assist the consultation process if the ORG were to undertake a preliminary assessment of the existing tariffs levels, at least for the most popular standing offer tariffs;  whether and how the framework for review of standing offer tariffs should, where necessary, address arrangements for moving tariffs towards a level that recovers their efficient costs.

If it is determined that the government (with the advice of the ORG) should impose a price cap, it would be necessary to undertake some preliminary assessment of the current tariff levels, at least the most popular of those.  In addressing question 15 above a skeletal outline of the approach considered most appropriate was offered.  It is important that the ORG avoids this process becoming a means to set the actual prices.  To reiterate, the need if it exists at all is to establish backstop prices that leave ample room for new players.

Reviews of the current tariff levels are important to ensure better understandings of the underlying costs that must be passed on.  At the same time, the ORG has a role in avoiding stimulating public expectations that the Government controls the market price of electricity.  Retail costs, even contracted costs, change rapidly as can be seen in Charts 1 and 2.  Where those costs were falling, there was a corresponding fall in prices for the contestable customers.  It is likely that these contestable customer prices are now rising.  The process for these customers was handled by market arrangements and with minimal fuss.

The danger with the present review is that the spotlight is placed on electricity prices and the public is given unreasonable expectations that electricity prices are under the control of the Government.  This, together with the natural agenda of the publicly funded consumerist agencies, is likely to put pressure on the Government to moderate market related price increases.  Such pressures would be far more damaging than those following on decisions to hold down prices of essential services like power lines, because the impact is more immediate.


18. Preliminary views on the options that seem most likely to meet the various objectives and principles set out in the terms of reference

Many of the options offered fall well short of the "light handed" notion and others are pregnant with considerable intervention.  One set of options ((iii) and (iv)) that should be summarily dismissed are those that involve rolling forward existing prices.  This would be especially the case where considerations of reducing prices are being made.

The option that most closely corresponds to the general approach advocated in this paper is option (vii).  This is the only one that offers explicit recognition of the need for the caps to allow headroom, that is for a cap that is an insurance for the less alert consumer but not a means that can result in the strangling of competitive responses.  This option needs to be tied to a strict time limitation and be sufficiently flexible to avoid financial distress to retailers caused by changing conditions that result in an unrealistic cap.  It could also be accompanied by a public promotion campaign about small users' freedom to select their own retailer.



ENDNOTES

1.  Richard A. Epstein Principles for a Free Society, Perseus Books, Reading Mass, 1998

2.  Laine, C. (1995), The H-H Index:  A Concentration Measure Taking the Consumers' Point of View, Antitrust Bulletin, Summer, pp. 423-32.

3.  For example, Paul L Joskow, "Why do we need electricity retailers?  Or, can you get it cheaper wholesale?" Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, revised discussion draft, 13 January 2000

4.  Littlechild, S.C., Why we need electricity retailers:  A reply to Joskow on wholesale spot price pass-through, The Judge Institute of Management Studies, University of Cambridge, September 2000.

5.  In fact the so-called Cournot model of oligopolistic competition predicts that the markup of a supplier depends not only on demand elasticity but also on the supplier's share of market output.  The larger the share, the more market power a supplier has and the greater its markup.

6.  Littlechild, op. cit. P. 47

7.  Baumol, W., Panzar, J., and Willig, R., Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure, San Diego, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1982

8.  For example in the CitiPower report p. 28.

Friday, August 17, 2001

A Brief Analysis of the Benefits of Privatising Victoria's Electricity Industry

Energy Forum Papers

1.0 INTRODUCTION

This paper considers the economic impact of the privatisation of the electricity industry in Victoria.  The changes in the Victorian electricity sector have led to increased productivity of capital and labour, improved system reliability, freed up public capital, reduced public debt and reduced final prices.  This paper commences with descriptions and evidence of these benefits and then provides a summary of retail electricity prices over the past decade.


2.0 BACKGROUND

Electricity market reform commenced in 1993 when the Victorian government embarked on a program to dis-aggregate and corporatise the State Electricity Commission of Victoria (SECV, its state owned electricity utility).  Once this was completed the corporatised components (power stations etc) were sold to private entities.  The gross proceeds from the sales were $23 billion of which, the State government netted $13 billion after paying back government debt associated with the SECV.  This conversion of government assets into cash boosted the state's economy at a time when it was hampered by high public debt and still smarting from the 1990-1992 recession.


2.1 PRODUCTIVITY

Reform was the catalyst for large productivity increases across the Victorian energy sector.  During 1993 there was a 17 per cent decline in employment within the "Electricity, Gas and Water" sector.  Overall, the 1990's saw employment within the industry halved, resulting in a productivity increase for the decade of over 70 per cent.  Meanwhile, during the same period Gross Product for the sector did not change (GSP increased by approximately 30 per cent over the same period). (1)

In 1995/96 brown coal plant utilisation rates were 66.6 per cent and by 1998 this had increased to 83.7 per cent (see Table 1).  Increases in utilisation rates illustrate how private management used a commercial focus to extract the maximum value from the generation assets that produced the cheapest power in Victoria. (2)  Table 1 also shows how brown coal generation displaced gas-fired generation over the period.  Brown coal is the cheapest form of non-renewable fuel based generation (Short Run Marginal Cost (SRMC) around $5-8);  gas fired plants are much higher on the cost scale (SRMC $30-50).  These changes in the generation mix further illustrate how privatisation increased the productivity of capital resulting in greater efficiency across the electricity industry in Victoria.

TABLE 1 Capacity Utilisation Rates in the South East Integrated Electricity Market

1995/'96
%
1996/'97
%
1997/'98
%
Brown Coal66.674.483.7
Gas28.416.415.9

Source:  Australian Energy, Market Developments and Projections,
ABARE Research report 99.4, April 1999, p 35.


2.2 RELIABILITY

FIGURE 1Source:  Office of the Regulator General, Victoria.
Electricity Businesses, Comparative Report 1999.  August 2000.

Based on the reliability measures represented in Figures 1 and 2 system reliability has improved markedly.  Figures 1 shows outage rates increasing until 1999 where they fall dramatically.  Figure 2 reveals a similar pattern for the number of hours that customers were without power.

FIGURE 2Source:  Office of the Regulator General, Victoria.
Electricity Businesses Comparative Performance 1999.  August 2000


2.3 FIRST MOVER ADVANTAGE AND THE RISK PROFILE

One of the major benefits of privatisation that has accrued to Victoria was the benefit of the first mover.  There was a great deal of uncertainty when the Victorian assets were sold, as the NEM had not even commenced.  Accurate forecasts of future spot electricity prices were a crucial part of the valuation of the generators and these were unavailable given the lack of a national market.  Stated simply, to value the assets, buyers estimated expected revenue streams going forward and combined these with their desired rate of return to produce a value.  As it turned out, the price forecasts were wrong and this in conjunction with other factors led to significant over valuations.  The beneficiary of these errors was the vendor, the Victorian government and Victorian taxpayers. (3)

One may argue that another part of the economy (the purchasers of the generators) incurred a loss that would off set the gains on the sales that accrued to the Victorian government.  Maybe so, but not in this case, the privatisations in Victoria were dominated by foreign purchasers.  Their funds were injections into the Victorian economy and the losses they incurred affected economies overseas.

It is unlikely that this situation will be repeated if NSW or Queensland sell their generation assets.  The recent sales in SA are evidence that buyers are more cautious and have a better understanding of the electricity market.

The Victorian Government has also eliminated the risks of continued governmental ownership in the new national electricity market.  Increased risks have manifested themselves as public and private losses across the National Electricity Market (NEM).  For example the:

  • Queensland Treasury Corporation on hedge contacts for the electricity industry.
  • NSW Government losses through Pacific Power's contracts with Powercor.

The risks of the national electricity markets are such to question the policy of continued governmental ownership of energy utilities.  The ACCC has already referred to the distortions that occur in the national electricity market through continued governmental ownership and the protection offered by governments for the utilities they continue to own.


3.0 RETAIL PRICES

As has been shown in the preceding sections, major changes have occurred within the Victorian electricity industry and the process is still continuing with one of the most significant parts yet to be completed.  Full Retail Contestability represents that final chapter in the process, the chapter where consumers will be able to choose their electricity supplier.  This is due to happen early next year.  Table 2 sets out the current Victorian Contestability Schedule although these dates could change given the investment in computer systems necessary for FRC to proceed.

TABLE 2 Victorian Retail Contestability Schedule

Market SegmentDate Contestable
> 5 MWDecember-94
1 MW - 5 MWJuly-95
750 MWh - 1 MWJuly-96
160 MWh - 750 MWhJuly-98
40 MWh 160 MWh (Remote meters)January-01
40 MWh 160 MWh (Non-Remote meters)August-01
0 -160 MWh (Public lighting unmetered supplies)August-01
All CustomersJanuary-02

3.1 INDUSTRIAL PRICES

Of the three categories (industrial, commercial and residential) industrial customers have always received the cheapest electricity.  This is because they offer retailers load shedding potential and flat load profiles (generally).  In addition to these factors there are a number of very large customers that have been able to extract low prices due to their volumes and the factors described above.  The prices charged to these customers have reduced the average industrial prices.  With a significant proportion of industrial demand contestable in mid 1996 prices in that year dropped to their 1994 levels.  As various tranches of industrial customers became contestable intense competition between retailers forced prices down.  Competition was fierce for these newly contestable industrial customers because of the qualities outlined above, the fact that they were the only available retailing opportunities and the desire of certain retailers to retain or increase their market shares.  From 1990 to 2000 the price of electricity for industrial users fell by 29 per cent (see Figure 3).

FIGURE 3Source:  NIEIR


3.2 COMMERCIAL PRICES

Of all the categories commercial electricity prices have benefited the most from deregulation and privatisation.  From 1992 to 2000 the average commercial price has decreased by almost 40 per cent.  To some extent the decreases were due to reductions in the cross subsidisation of residential users by commercial users.  This is illustrated in Figure 4.  Since 1994 charges to residential and commercial customers have moved closer to the ‘actual' costs of supply for each category.  This has resulted in residential costs charges increasing and commercial costs declining.  Other reasons for the decreases include the deregulation of trading hours (resulting in improved the load profiles) and the "bundling" of contestable customers to increase volumes and improve load profiles.

FIGURE 4Source:  NIEIR


3.3 RESIDENTIAL PRICES

The most expensive electricity is that supplied to residential customers.  Because of their relatively poor load profiles, higher infrastructure requirements and small individual volumes they incur charges that are significantly higher than industrial and commercial rates.  Furthermore, -- abstracting from socioeconomic factors -- there is a view that industrial and commercial users ought to be charged less for electricity because their electricity usage is essentially an input in to production whereas, residential usage represents the consumption of a finished good.  Nevertheless, residential electricity prices have been falling since they peaked in 1994.  This has been achieved through efficiency improvements in generation, transmission and distribution -- due largely to deregulation and privatisation -- that have allowed continual reductions in electricity charges over the decade.  Regulatory changes have also led to some minor reductions in real prices to residential customers.

Electricity distribution charges are a significant component of the price of electricity delivered to residential customers.  They account for between 30 and 50 per cent of the bill, with the variations attributable to location and volume.  The other components are transmission charges (passed on to the customer by the distributor), energy costs and retailing costs and margins.

The next section looks at electricity demand and pricing.  Electricity demand increased significantly over the decade due to economic growth, and in Victoria a growth in peak demand due to the expanded use of air conditioners.


3.4 ELECTRICITY DEMAND AND PRICES

Figure 5 illustrates how demand increased over the 1990's (at an annual average growth rate over two per cent).  From 1990 to 2000 total consumption increased by 7,000 GW hours.  In contrast, prices have been falling since 1992 with the sharpest decline occurring between 1996 and 1998 (where average annual decreases were nearly six per cent).  During this period de-regulation and privatisation were being implemented.  As shown previously (see Section 2.1), both capital and labour productivity increased over this period.  These improvements allowed additional demand to be met while prices continued to fall.  In addition to this without the additional increases in capacity utilisation (see Section 2.1) new capacity would have been required to satisfy the demand increases. (4)

FIGURE 5Sources:  NIEIR & ESAA


4.0 CONCLUSION

Since privatisation and deregulation commenced electricity prices have fallen across all categories.  This is due to the cost and generator availability improvements stemming from private ownership and the development of a national electricity market.  In addition to the absolute falls in prices the relative prices between categories have also changed.  The most notable is the reversal of the relativities between commercial and residential prices.  Commercial prices in 1990 were 32 per cent higher than 1990 residential prices, in 2000 they were 26 per cent lower than residential prices.  This is indicative of the "user pays" principle" that has been encouraged and in any case residences get the benefit of lower industrial and commercial prices in the goods and services they consume.

The downward trend in prices is unlikely to continue.  Most of the potential efficiency gains have been realised and those that remain will be harder to achieve and smaller than previous improvements.  Generation costs have been increasing inn 2001 due to the:

  • rise in electricity demand especially high cost peak demand;
  • progressive reduction in the excess supply in the NEM, especially in Victoria and South Australia, over the decade;
  • expanding use of relatively expensive gas fired generation particularly for peak demand;  and
  • lack of significant new generation capacity in Victoria or increase in interconnect capacity with NSW.

Spot prices have increased resulting in upward pressure on contract rates.  These price changes be passed on by normal market processes for the half of the market that is presently contestable.  For others, full retail contestability, scheduled to come into effect in January 2002, will allow retailers to pass cost increases on to consumers thereby forcing up prices substantially.  The Government is seeking some means of regulating this.  Any such measures that held down the price in the face of rising costs would cause considerable harm to the electricity retailing industry and to the long term interests of the consumer.  Figure 6 indicates the increase in wholesale contract prices over the past year.

FIGURE 6Source:  Pulse energy Submission to th Office of the Regulator-General's Special Reference on Prices, June 2001.  See http://svc116.bne022u.server-web.com/PulseLettPricesJun01.pdf

These price increases have led to increased investment in both gas peakers and in base load generation (at Loy Yang A) in Victoria.  They have also brought increased interest in the development of Basslink from Tasmania.  These are signs that the NEM is working well.  Capital intensive competitive infrastructure markets will encourage new investment with a time lag, given the caution of investors to ensure demand is likely to be permanent enough to get a return on their investments.  In comparison, public ownership leads to smoother adjustments to demand increases but with the likely costs of over investment and operational inefficiencies.

It is clear that privatisation has been a success on a range of measures and has brought considerable benefits to the Victorian community.



ENDNOTES

1.  BIS Shrapnel, State Industry Prospects 1999-2014.

2.  It should be noted however, that increases in Victoria's generation capacity during the 1980's were initiated to meet demand levels well beyond those extant when the new plants were commissioned.

3.  The Victorian Auditor General stated that "... the proceeds of the $6.2 billion received by the State from the sale of the (electricity distribution) businesses net assets compared favourably with the valuations of $3.9 billion,.  Resulting in $2.3 billion being received in excess of the float valuations."  Victorian Auditor General, Report on Ministerial Portfolios, May 1996, p.10.

4.  The increase in demand of 7,000 GW hours implies a new base load generator of 800-1000 MW would be required.  This is calculated in the following manner:

Hours in Year = 8,760
1 GW Hour = 1000 MW Hours

7,000,000 / 8,760 = 799
_ 799 MW required every hour.

This analysis ignores the fact that the additional demand would have fluctuated from hour to hour possibly implying the need for base load AND peaking plant.  Forced outage rates and line loss factors are also ignored.

Improving Risk Disclosure and Accountability in Public

An address to the Managing and Regulating Public Private Partnerships Conference,
16 August 2001

Over the past decade, Australia has enjoyed perhaps the most comprehensive privatisation program seen anywhere in the world.

Since the early 1990s over $90 billion of publicly owned entities have been sold into the private sector.  The process has covered a wide range of asset types:  telecom, electricity and gas, ports, banks, and gambling.

All States except Tasmania have been part of the process.  The Commonwealth with Telstra and the sale of the Commonwealth Bank and Qantas dominating has been the major privatiser with Victoria punching well above its weight with the energy privatisations eclipsing all others in value.  Other states have privatised less, in South Australia, energy has dominated, in Western Australia energy and banking and in Queensland and NSW it has been financial services.

Privatisation has been an immense blessing.  It has been part of the range of microeconomic reforms that constitute the much loathed economic rationalism.  As such it has contributed to a situation where Australian productivity growth has shifted from among the worst in the world to among the best.  It has allowed the economy a measure of considerable prosperity and growth during the past half dozen years.  During this period, Japan, our major trading partner, has stagnated and the economies of several of our near neighbours which were providing most of the better trading prospects have gone into a series of tailspins.

We have many worthwhile prospects for privatisation but it seems the political will or economic necessity has waned, except in the case of some rail assets.  It now seems unlikely that over the next few years we shall see privatisation of the rest of the power industry or of Telstra or of water and all the other remaining areas where private enterprise can make a difference.

Private partnerships allow some of the momentum of the privatisation process to be maintained.  They allow the galvanising onto a public sector development of some of the cost savings and innovation seen in private enterprise.  At the very least this should ensure against the horremndous cost over-runs and dead-weight government staff that accompanied developments of yesteryear.

Contracting out and privatisation has a long history.  Contracting out has always been a feature of manufacturing and service industries.  Often it has taken the form of vast numbers of sub-contractors.  Such methods, used by the Japanese transformed the motor industry from the previous archetype where steel and leather went in the factory at one end and a finished car rolled off the other.

A further variant, franchising, has proven immensely successful in galvanising the self interest of a quasi employee and turning him or her into a self motivated entrepreneur who seeks out economies in achieving customer satisfaction.

This reminds us that it has been in the operations of these facilities that the real economies have been made.  The Victorian privatised electricity distribution businesses started by contracting out activities on the periphery of their core business.  Among the first such candidates were workshops, civil engineering and construction activity.  These have been followed by undergrounding, meter installation, public lighting and in some cases line workers.

Most of the power stations have outsourced maintenance, catering, cleaning and security functions.  A great deal of this took place prior to privatisations.  Further efficiency gains have been made since then by paring down on excess staffing and better management generally.

For the power stations a major driving force for cost cutting generally and outsourcing in particular was the coming national electricity market where the Victorian generators estimated they needed to cut at least 35% of direct costs if they were to be competitive with NSW and Queensland.  The generation business reflected all the poor symptoms of union control:  restrictive work practices, over-manning, poor performance leading to major outages all stemming from an ingrained antipathy towards management.

In the case of maintenance, considerable pre-conditioning was necessary.  The first step was to establish a profit centre.  Some early successes in outsourcing, included Siemens taking over the electrical workshops in 1991 and Linfox taking over transport and stores at the same time followed by a consortium taking over part of the coal cutting business.  These early outsourcings presented a demonstaration effect.  Although the unions fought to retain existing staffing levels, the gains were plain to see and the Kennett Government was particularly ill-disposed to union featherbedding.  The contracting out of maintenance entailed 2,200 jobs with about 1,000 of those displaced finding work with the contractors.

Anticipating the current private public partnership push, some assets with a specialised role, like milling and boring machines for turbo-generator overhauls were not sold but leased out to the new contractor.  Such a move carries some risk that the new contractor will stint on maintenance of an asset he does not own.  This carries particular risks where the contractor feels he won't win the next round of contracts.  Although not followed in the SECV case, a strategy for combating this is to have an independent appraisal of the value of the asset pre-contracting and a further appraisal at the end of the contract with an agreement for payment where the asset has depreciated beyond an agreed point.

As with many other businesses, there are fears that the "emaciated corporation" will just become a bundle of contracts that nobody in the corporation itself is capable of overseeing properly.  Keeping core competencies and contracting skills is essential but the concept of core competencies is often elusive.  Western Mining, for example, outsources all its work at two of its biggest mines.  The Kennett Government outsourced its policy functions in the privatisation of the electricity industry.  The present government found a cost saving by abandoning the task altogether!

All this underlines the importance of what is meant by private partnerships.

More than 121 developing countries introduced private participation in at least one infrastructure sector between 1990 and 1999.  Those countries awarded over 1,900 projects that involved investment commitments of US$580 billion.

Investments encompass bridges, electricity, roads, dams etc.

Contracting out in Victoria has been accompanied by a comprehensive sales campaign of government publications selling the notion of Partnerships Victoria.  Under this the Government explains how it is to vastly expand public infrastructure and to do so in ways that:

  • get the best value for the taxpayers' money
  • ensure best practice
  • protect the public interest
  • ensure all the usual suspects are given rights to participate in the processes and to ensure disadvantaged groups can effectively use the infrastructure.

Of great importance in this respect is the need to have full transparency.  Unfortunately, dealings by government cannot be like dealings by BHP.  Government does not have the discipline of the bottom line profit result and owners who can exit the share registry in the event of poor performance.  This lack of consistent attention to fully benefiting the, shareholder, who in the populist nostrums of triple line accountability and corporate social responsibility would be dubbed the residual stakeholders, marks out business from government.  It is the feature that makes business intrinsically more efficient than government.

A perceived lack of full disclosure by government can be poison.  The public criticism that continually confronted the previous government with regard to the Casino deal was made possible because the deal was undertaken in greater confidence than occurred with the electricity privatisations.  Those opposed to privatisation were able to capitalise on aspects of the deal that were never made public.  In the event, after years of trying to uncover supposed political payback, both in Opposition and in Government nothing untoward has come to light and one would presume therefore that there is nothing untoward in existence.  However the issue became a cause celebre among the anti-capitalist cheer squad.  It allowed massive scope for the pro government ownership cadres to ventilate their prejudices.

This provides a message in all government dealings and one that the present government appears to have learned well:  all dealings must be out in the open Bids, terms of agreement, performance measures and all aspects of the deal should be open to public scrutiny and to the scrutiny of the Auditor General.  This is also an extra cost for the private sector of doing business with government but it is one that is unavoidable.

Let me finish on a note of caution.

The considerable activity of privatisation has allowed the debt that was amassed at all levels of government to be virtually eliminated.  Commonwealth general government debt is scheduled to be eliminated in two or three years, state general government debt is already eliminated and the debt of the public non financial corporations is down by over a third.  In overall terms, debt which in the dollars of the day was $164 billion in the mid-1990s is now more than halved.

In the context of the privatisation, and the vast reduction of debt we have seen, private public partnerships offer both a source of salvation and a source of risk to the soundness of public accounts.

The risk is that the outsourcing of schools, hospitals, law courts and the like will become a hidden way of increasing public spending, a means by which expenditure gives the impression of being under control but only because some big ticket long lasting capital items are now off the budget statement and are being paid for over decades rather than in one year.

This is not to argue against the treatment of these items on an accrual rather than cash basis.  The objection is that it becomes more difficult to hold governments accountable for their expenditure decisions.  We have budgets constructed on a different basis.  And the Treasury either won't or cannot offer a series of accounts that allow the comparisons that are meaningful and essential.  All we have is a spartan few lines informing us of "non quantifiable contingent liabilities".

The privatisations have left the infrastructure businesses at risk of government interference.  Already we are seeing grumbles on the part of some in the electricity business who feel the regulator has treated them harshly.  These have brought sales or attempted sales of two of the five businesses.  In the early years of the electricity market, there was downward pressure on prices.  Government could rest easy.  Now the investment cycle is such that there is upward pressure.  The political impact of this is vastly exacerbated by the rate-payer or tax-payer consumerist agitators that governments, even conservative governments, feel obliged to put in place.  We are seeing some further regulation of electricity prices being mooted.  This is serious for the electricity industry, itself a major part of the Victorian economy, but the impact could spill over onto other areas of investment by increasing the sovereign risk of investing in the State generally.

In the case of prisons, the renationalisation of Deer Park offers an indication of the ideology of government ministers seeking out situations where they are able to exercise their preferences.  An independent review found the prison to be superior to others in the public sector yet it was pilloried.  The Government also readily seized the opportunity to take back control of the Latrobe Hospital, only to see its waiting lists balloon out.

Governments are notoriously close chested when it comes to scrutiny of their operations.  We don't have a true public assessment of the different schools (although the UK Blair Government has grasped that nettle).  Anyone who tried to get information on the old public transport system was whistling into the wind.  Under privatisation, performance measures are in place and under firm public scrutiny.

But it needs measures that go beyond a building and lease back if we are to see efficiency.  To be sure, governments can utilise public/private partnerships to have a building constructed and leased back to them, thereby taking advantage of superannuation savings to step in where previously tax payers money went direct.  But is this enough to justify the program?  The real economies are in operations, which often means escaping the yoke of union conditions.  Will the government come at that?  Will the government say to MLC or Caulfield Grammar "We'll outsource the build operate and own of schools in Victoria to you"?

It may well outsource law courts as buildings or negotiate a long term lease on a school but if that is all that is entailed this is a pale imitation of the potentialities available.