Tuesday, August 29, 1995

All the world seeks change but the price is individual pain

Voters throughout the Western world are expressing discontent and insecurity. Richard Wood considers the consequences for policy.

I HAVE recently returned from overseas discussions with a range of senior economic officials employed by governments and international organisations, as well as with United States and United Kingdom think tanks.  Overseas, as in Australia, there is considerable angst being directed at governments in office, and considerable discussion of the causes of such angst.  While there is no one simple explanation, analysts highlight feelings of insecurity in the community which result from major structural economic changes that have exposed individuals and businesses to increased competitive pressures.

This insecurity is reflecting, among other things, the apparent stagnation of real wages and high rates of unemployment.  Although average living standards are increasing and high unemployment is often accompanied by relatively high rates of employment, that does not alleviate insecurity at the individual level.

There is even uncertainty about the value of one's own home, vividly reflected in the United Kingdom in the growing number of people being forced to sell and finding that they actually have negative equity in their homes.

Little wonder that electorates are taking it out on governments in office, almost regardless of political complexion.

Reinforcing this development is the growing acceptance that governments are themselves part of the problem.

Such feelings are probably most evident in the US, where the Republican victory in last November's Congressional elections unleashed a surge of political activity directed at reducing the role of government in fields ranging from social welfare to environmental regulation.

Some of this activity is not new, but the significant element of political bipartisanship is, as both perceive, that the electorate wants government to play a reduced role.  In the US for example, the apparent public support for balancing the Federal Budget by cutting spending and having a tax cut has forced President Clinton to adopt a similar Budget-balancing strategy to the Republicans.

True, the Clinton proposals would take longer to balance the Budget and involve a smaller cut in spending but the basic strategy is the same.  Even more exciting, there is now a developing prospect of bipartisan agreement on taxation reform that would radically alter the basis of taxation through a flat-rate "income" tax that exempted saving.

In the UK, the new leader of the Opposition Labor Party, Tony Blair, has not only got rid of the socialisation plank from his party's constitution but promises, if elected, a "wholesale review" of the welfare state designed to reduce dependence, deter fraud, bolster the family and make greater use of the private sector to provide welfare services.  Mr Blair is also clearly distancing himself from the union movement, Labor's policies on industrial relations will be determined only after discussion with employers as well as unions.

The union block vote at British Labor Party conferences is also diminished, as is the policy role of the conference itself.  Mr Blair evidently envisages a social democratic party that appeals to voters as individuals, rather than as members of a union movement with a declining role in society.

Given Mr John Major's lowly position in the opinion polls, and continued issues at by-elections, one might have expected his Government to have brought economic reform to a halt.

But not a bit of it.

In addition to cutting the size of central government, a massive privatisation of British Rail is proceeding on a basis designed to counter criticisms of previous privatisatiions no fewer than 25 companies operating passenger services on a franchise basis.  In Western Europe too, a steady flow of privatisations is rolling back more and more government-operated enterprises.

It is evident that, notwithstanding the electorate's feelings of insecurity, few political parties overseas are espousing the cause of no further economic reforms.  In part this is a response to the perception already mentioned, that government is increasingly seen as one of the main causes of instability.

But it is also a response to the growing realisation by governments themselves that, at least for the community as a whole, there is no security in a policy of standing still.

Failure to implement policy changes that allow businesses and individuals to compete internationally inevitably leads to lower living standards and even higher unemployment.

The pity of all this is that the overseas debate, and much of the action, seems to be passing Australia by.  True, there is considerable interest overseas in the Federal Government's proposals to increase saving and, in the case-management approach, to handling the longer-term unemployed.

Generally, however, Australia is perceived as an economic reform backwater "because you have a cultural resistance to change", it was suggested.  The perception that we are content with putting another prawn on the barbie is certainly one we could do without.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, August 22, 1995

States induce costly mistakes

SIR, Your editorial ("The way forward on State taxes", AFR, August 14) points out that, when competition between States takes the form of tax concessions provided to just one business, or even one industry, it can be counterproductive.

Indeed, many costly mistakes have been made in the past by all State governments in providing assistance of one form or another in order to induce enterprises to invest in their State.  State governments are nonetheless still in the business of providing such incentives.

While the scope for making costly mistakes may now be less than it was in the 1980s, there remains considerable public unease when governments do special "deals" with business enterprises.

It would help relieve such unease if, before such "deals" were consummated, the costs and benefits were evaluated by an independent body.  There is now a long record of federal bodies such as the Industries Commission, Foreign Investment Review Board and Trade Practices Commission examining commercial in-confidence material, evaluating it, and providing advice to the Commonwealth Government.  Even though some of that advice is itself provided in confidence, the processes undertaken reduce the mistake-risk and improve transparency.  One option for the State governments would be for them to establish their own Industry Commission to evaluate the costs and benefits of providing incentives where special deals are proposed, and to report to the Government.  Another would be to contract out such evaluations to the federal Industries Commission.  Either way, in the long run this approach could produce political as well as economic benefits.


ADVERTISEMENT

Thursday, August 03, 1995

State could use a review process for special deals

Ian Henke (28/7) points to the costly mistakes made by a previous Victorian Government in the power deal struck with Alcoa.

I do not wish to enter the debate about what, if anything, should be done about this now.

However, it does seem pertinent to point out that this is only one of many costly mistakes made in the past by a state government in providing assistance of one form or another in order to induce enterprises to invest in this state.  It may also be appropriate to point out that the present Victorian Government, along with other state governments, is still in the business of providing such incentives.

While the scope for making costly mistakes may now be less than it was in the 1980s, there remains considerable public unease when governments do special "deals" with business enterprises.

It would help relieve such unease if, before such "deals" were consummated, the costs and benefits were evaluated by an independent body.

There is now a long record of federal bodies such as the Industries Commission, Foreign Investment Review Board and Trade Practices Commission examining commercial-in-confidence material, evaluating it and providing advice to the Commonwealth Government.

Even though some of that advice is itself provided in confidence, the processes undertaken reduce the mistake risk and improve transparency.

One option for the State Government would be for it to establish its own industry commission to evaluate the costs and benefits of providing incentives where special deals are proposed, and to report to the Government.  In the long run this approach could produce political as well as economic benefits.


ADVERTISEMENT

Wednesday, August 02, 1995

Race and Culture

Address at Boston University
9 March 1995

KEN

Ladies and gentlemen, welcome to Boston University.

We are very pleased to welcome for today's address, Mr Richard Wood.

Mr Wood is one of the intellectual leaders of the resurgence of conservative thinking in Australian politics and indeed world politics.  He is visiting the US and he will be addressing a whole range of meetings while he is here.  I pointed out to him that I don't think I have seen so many economists inside this room except at meetings of the Economic Society.  But, never daunted, Mr Wood has a huge following in Australia and I am sure he is about to demonstrate to you why that is.

Please welcome Mr Richard Wood.


RICHARD WOOD

Thank you very much.  It is a great pleasure and an honour to be here in the US.  Now, I'm an Australian and I'm coming here to speak about matters American, to speak about race and culture in the US.  These are matters of great importance in my country and I believe that they touch on themes of universal importance.

I very much appreciate the interest that has been shown to me in these matters in the press and by the public since I've been here in this country.  But I must say, to the extent that what I have to say is relevant to your concerns, that's a matter that you will be better placed to speak about than I.  I will try as best I can to faithfully report the spirit of the critical views which I have tried to offer within the American debate.  I put them out there for your consideration and you make of them what you will.

I'm a veteran of what is sometimes called the "cultural wars" in Australia:  conflict within universities and politics and the press over very important matters of cultural interpretation and definition -- definition of national identity, matters of education policy, multiculturalism, affirmative action and that sort of thing.  That's been one of the areas in which I have participated in public discussion in my own country.  And this has been going on during a period of growing conflict in Australian society.

I have often had to confront the problem of balancing my desire not to disappoint the expectations of others, both whites and blacks but more especially whites, with my conviction that one should strive to live life with integrity.  This has led me to act sometimes against my initial inclination in ways which would elicit the approval of my racial peers.  Yet I now understand that, unless I were willing to risk the derision of the crowd, I would have no chance to discover the most important truths about myself or about life;  to define and pursue that which I most value;  to make the unique contribution to my family, my community and my nation that God has empowered me to do.

The issue that I raise here is one of the possibility of a candid and critical public discourse about the most sensitive matters.  As a white Australian in a country which has experienced great conflict around questions of race, I am sometimes constrained and I feel pressures -- understandable, well-meaning -- not to say what I really think for fear of how it will be understood, for disappointing the expectations of others, for seeming to be disloyal to certain deeply-held beliefs.  Yet the burden of what I want so say here today is that succumbing to that temptation of allowing oneself to be hemmed in by those considerations is in the end a disservice to oneself, to one's community, and ultimately to one's nation;  and that the best possible outcome in a democracy is to be achieved by people who are prepared to transcend their racial or ethnic differences and to seek some universal understanding of the fundamental principles that allow a free people to live together in peace and prosperity.  That's the general theme of my remarks.

Now, I talk about myself.  This is a private truth, perhaps of little interest to anybody in this room, but I think it points towards some larger social truths:  that the seductive call of the tribe can become a siren's call;  that there are no group goals or purposes which exist prior to, and independently of, the life plans and the ideals of individual persons;  that, unless universalism is truly exalted, multiculturalism can descend into crass ethnic cheer-leading;  that, after all is said and done, race is an epiphenomenon even in America, even for the descendants of slaves.  In these remarks I am going to try to explain why I think these statements are true.

Mind you, race talk like this is heresy for those whom I will here call racialists.  These are believers, blacks and whites in American society, in the doctrine that authentic blacks must view life through, first, a racial lens;  must see themselves as objects of mistreatment by whites while participating in some collective consciousness of that mistreatment with other blacks.  Racialists argue that the experience of being victimised by white racism contributes something essential to the development of blacks' personalities.  They insist that the black condition can only improve when whites fully acknowledge their racist culpability.  This is a deep-seated view, held by many with a religious intensity.

For decades believers in this creed have shaped the broad public discussion of racial affairs in America while assiduously policing, and therefore stifling, black communal discourse.  I believe their world view has been monumentally, tragically wrong.  Its pursuit has led not only to the alienation of whites but to the sacrificing of the potential of countless black lives on an altar of racial protest.  I know these are strong statements but I see them as commensurate with the crime.

The American philosopher Charles Griswold has captured one of the important dimensions of the deep problem I have with the racialist prospective.  In a recent essay he writes -- and forgive the somewhat abstract philosophical language, but I'll get the point across by quoting him --

One frequently hears people declare with passion, "speaking as an X, I can inform you that Y" -- where X is the name of the relevant group and Y stands for some description or evaluation of the conditions or beliefs of X -- an outsider not in group X cannot speak with any authority about that group.  One must and usually does defer immediately.  The moral authority embodied in the statement provided by speaking as X stems in part from an epistemic thesis to the effect that the point of view shared by all members of X is not accessible, or not at least sufficiently accessible, to non-X persons.

So what I mean is, someone says, "Men can't see things the way women do.  Speaking as a woman I can tell you that women feel the following" -- which is a trump card played to pre-empt the possibility that this woman's expression could be subject to critical evaluation by a man.  "As a black who has endured racism in America, speaking as a black, I have this to say to you about that" -- which is not to initiate a discussion, not to encourage a dialogue that might persuade, but, rather, to assert authority, to preclude and exclude the possibility of dialogue by saying that, because of the authentic experience of the speaker, the knowledge that is about to be conveyed by the statement is protected against some critical reaction by one who does not share that experience.

Now, this philosopher Griswold is interested, as I am, in the paradoxical situation in which, in a democracy, mutually-insulated groups, neither capable of understanding one another, nevertheless insist upon equal recognition.  This situation is in fact an apt description of the current state of American pluralism.  It follows naturally from the racialist position and it raises some interesting questions.

Can recognition reasonably be demanded when understanding is denied to the outsider?  Can genuine respect arise from mutual ignorance?  Can the white who guiltily confesses to having no idea what black people have endured in America really honour the concrete accomplishments of blacks who have transcended the barriers of racial constraint?  Can the black who angrily asserts that he never sees things the way the white man does ever hope to persuade that white man to meet him half-way on a matter of mutual importance?

It seems obvious to me that genuine empathy and effective persuasion that reach across racial group lines are not possible unless a universal understanding of the conditions and feelings of individual human beings, belonging to the various racial groups, is also possible.  It is equally clear to me that the only way we can gain such a mutual understanding is to look past the racial veil so as to recognise our common humanity in the varying specific situations that we confront.  This implies, contrary in my judgement to the racialist view, that the problems facing black Americans are best understood and presented to the rest of the polity in their essential human terms rather than as narrowly-framed racial claims.

The deep truth of the matter is that the most important challenges and opportunities confronting any person arise not from his or her particular racial condition but rather from our common human condition.  Racial group membership alone tells us little that is true about how we ought to live.  The social contingencies of race, gender, class, sexual orientation and the like are real.  They are real, and they are often confining and constraining, but they are nonetheless the raw materials out of which each of us must yet construct a life.  Expression of an individual's worth and personality is found in the blueprint that he or she uses to guide this project of construction.  Devising and fulfilling such a life plan is a universal problem confronting all of us, whatever our ethnic identities.  It is by facing up to and solving this problem that we grow as human beings, that we earn the dignity and respect from our fellows that we so much crave, and that we give meaning and substance to our lives.  Because we face this common problematic, identical in all things essential, different only in the detail, we have the potential to transcend the racial difference, to gain genuine mutual understanding of our respective experiences and travails, to truly empathise with one another.  Because, as Jean-Paul Sartre might have said, we all confront the existential challenge of discovering how to avoid living in bad faith, it is possible for us to share love across the tribal boundaries.

The greatest ethnic writers begin from this truth.  In Portrait of the Artist as a Young Man, for example, James Joyce says this about Irish nationalism:  "When the soul of a man is born in this country there are nets flung at it to hold it back from flight.  You talk to me of nationality, language, religion, I shall try to fly by these nets.  Do you know what Ireland is?  Ireland is the old sow that eats her farrow."

And, echoing that, in the great American novel The Invisible Man, the black writer Ralph Ellison has this to say:  "Our problem is not actually one of creating the uncreated conscience of the race but rather of creating the uncreated features of the face.  Our task is that of making ourselves individuals.  We create the race by creating ourselves -- and then, to our great astonishment, we will have created a culture.  Why," Ellison concludes, "waste time creating a conscience for something which does not exist?  For you see, blood and skin do not think."

This is the fundamental philosophical point from which I depart.  It is not a partisan point, it is not a political point;  it's a point about the elemental assumptions that we make as individual human beings concerning what gives our lives meaning and value, and about how we can achieve genuine dignity and respect as human beings in our various societies.  Ellison understood this point in a way I fear a later generation of black American writers have refused to credit.  "Blood and skin do not think."  They have no existence except that which is given to them through the fulfilled lives of individual human beings.  The "conscience of the race" is something that has to be constructed from the inside out, one human being at a time.

Now, this is a social, a philosophical, truth which has political implications, particularly for American democracy, though I would venture this claim for any democracy.  The racialist assertion of epistemic privilege is more than a philosophic stance.  In a pluralistic society, a democratic society, it leads to the destruction of any national community except that which is an arena within which war is waged for ethnic recognition and for the political and economic benefits which follow from that recognition.

In fact, in black and white relations in the US, matters are actually worse than that.  For this war for recognition of the group, waged by the racialists over the last generation under the banner of blacks' historic victimisation, has actually ended in a plaintive demand to be patronised.  In a stunning attempt at political jujitsu, voices of black authenticity insist that the very helplessness of their group gives evidence of whites' culpability to which the only response is the recognition of black claims.  In the event, we can now see that other white responses are possible.

Consider the issue of affirmative action.  Advocates of blacks' interests now practise a politics of desperation.  They have been reduced to insisting that affirmative action is just and necessary, because without the use of special criteria for selection the numbers of blacks in various important institutions of the society would be unbearably low.  In the universities, they publicly confess that the sons and daughters of the solid black middle class require special dispensation, justified by the sufferings of their ancestors, in order to gain admittance to the most prestigious academic institutions.  In the business world, entrepreneurs with free access to capital, competing in an open and fair marketplace, can nevertheless thrive only by having government contracts set aside for their special access.  These set-asides are rationalised as necessary because of the racial group identity of the entrepreneur.  This identity becomes the foundation of their participation in an open and free society.  Without the government taking it into account, they confess, they would not be able to succeed.  They have, in other words, to display their weakness, define themselves in the collective, and then throw themselves at the feet of their fellow citizens and hope that some sense of guilt about historic victimisation, not of these persons making the claim but of their ancestors long distant, might be recognised.  This pathetic client politics is ignoble in the extreme.

As the backlash against preferential policies favouring blacks continues to grow in the US, one can see that this strategy has proved disastrous.  It is no substitute for the concrete development of the capacities of individual human beings.  What matters is that students present themselves to the universities with the acumen and the cognitive abilities which allow them to compete head-to-head with the best students who come to universities from any place in the world.  The travails of their grandparents are hardly the issue.  What matters is whether or not the kid can read and count:  that's the issue.  When the kid cannot read and count with competitive proficiency, gaining his admission to the university on the basis of a quota does not change the objective fact that he cannot read or count.  Such a preference does not address the underlying structural factors that prevent him from presenting himself as someone who can read or count;  it does not give him equality in any true sense in society because everybody knows that he can neither read nor count.  The preferential policy does not redress the consequences of the historic victimisation of this person's ancestors.  Those ancestors in fact lived much more noble and creditable lives under the weight of Jim Crow and racism than does the person who can neither read nor count with adequate proficiency, but who thinks that by seeking protection under cover of his racial identity he won't be asked to account for himself.

Chillingly, the political weakness of the black poor has now become palpable.  Loyal Democrats all, racialist leaders in the inner city communities have cast their lot with the Left, with those seeking the expansion of the welfare state with increasing taxes, the promulgation of more regulations and so forth.  It's a respectable position.  People take it in various countries throughout the world.  It just happens to be a losing position in American politics today.

Blacks reliably provide a quarter or upwards of the Democrat vote in the Presidential contest.  Black congressional representation is significantly dependent upon districts having been arranged in such a way as to ensure that ultra-left black candidates are elected without the inconvenience of having to persuade any white people to vote for them.  And, despite the rightward political drift in the nation that has been going on for a generation, and notwithstanding the deep cultural conservatism of a religious black American population, these leaders have chosen to make feminist and gay rights activists, and civil libertarians of various kinds, their allies -- which is a defensible position not unobserved in other polities -- but to the exclusion of building bridges to the centre of American politics which might protect the interests of their people.

It is now obvious that a conservative political majority can be constructed in my country and can govern without the support of urban minority voters.  Moreover, the racialist perspective which I am attacking here unnecessarily exposes profound psychological vulnerabilities of the black population.  In a recently published book, The Bell Curve, Richard Herrnstein and Charles Murray point to a large gap in the average IQ score between blacks and whites, suggesting that some of this difference is fixed by genetic factors.  Now, let me be clear, I'm not a fan of The Bell Curve.  But, the fact is that Herrnstein and Murray can claim with cause that they are merely responding to the Zeitgeist by offering their psychometrician's brew, aggregated in the racial group terms which have previously been authorised by advocates of social equity.  They can say, in effect, counting by race was not our idea but, now that you've mentioned it, let's take a look at all of the numbers.

In fact, the record of black American economic and educational achievement, in the post-civil rights era, has been ambiguous.  There has been great success and there has been shocking failure.  The loudest voices among black activists have tried to bluff their way past this ambiguous record by cajoling or chastising anyone who expresses disappointment or dismay.  These racialists treat low black achievement as an automatic indictment of the American social order rather than as a revelation of blacks' inadequacies.  They are hoist on their own petard by the arguments and the data of The Bell Curve.  Having insisted that each individual life be examined first through a racial lens, they must now confront the spectre of a racial intelligence accountancy which offers a rather different explanation for the ambiguous achievements of blacks in the last generation.

Again, I want to emphasise, I don't believe that this racial intelligence accountancy accurately accounts for the failures, such as they have been, of blacks in the last generation.  But neither do I believe in exposing one's lack of achievement, by engaging in what I sometimes call an exhibitionism of non-achievement.  You know how it goes:  "So few of us are in the universities, therefore this is a racist society";  "have you taken a look lately at how many black doctors and lawyers there are" therefore "the law schools and medical schools are racist," etc.  By engaging in an exhibitionism of non-achievement one invites the pernicious speculations to which Herrnstein and Murray's analysis can lead.

Hence the question now on the floor, a question in the minds of blacks as well as whites, is whether black Americans are capable of gaining equal status, given equal opportunity.  It has been an implicit question for some time, and it is now becoming an explicit question in the American political dialogue.  It is a peculiar mind which fails to see in the light of your history just how poisonous a question this is in your democracy.  And let me again state my unequivocal confidence that blacks are indeed so capable.

Still, any such assertion is a hypothesis.  It is not a fact, my saying it does not make it so.  The fact, the lamentable fact, is that blacks have something to prove -- to themselves, and to what one great black thinker around the turn of century called, a world that looks on in amused contempt and pity.  This is not fair, it is not right, it just happens to be the way things are.  There are conservatives who are not above signalling their beliefs that blacks can never pass this test.  And there are black nationalists who agree -- arguing, increasingly more stridently now, that blacks cannot ever make it in white America, and so they should stop trying, go their own way, and maybe burn a few things down in the process.

At bottom these two parties, apparently at opposites of the political spectrum, share a fundamental common belief that the challenge in an open and free society to the great-great-grandsons and daughters of slaves, to rise to the occasion and make it, is beyond what we can manage.  Is it really such a radical move to suggest that, in essence, that challenge of rising to the occasion of opportunity and making it, whatever their background and whatever their baggage, the challenge confronting blacks today, is not really a racial matter at all?  Do I say something so hard to fathom when I suggest that it is primarily the human condition, and not their racial condition, that they must learn to cope with?  Hasn't everybody come from somewhere?  Haven't all of us, not too far back in our heritage (certainly here on this continent, and certainly on the one from which I come), inherited a history characterised, in part, by disadvantage, encumbrance, exclusion, discrimination, racism of one kind or another?  Have not civilisations been built outside of Europe by peoples moving, with virtually nothing, fleeing oppression, labouring under doubts about their capacities, and nevertheless succeeding in creating a life for themselves and their descendants?  Do those opportunities not now beckon to the richest and freest people of African descent anywhere on the globe who reside, some 30 million strong, in America?  Is it so much to say that the problem, the traumatic circumstance, the heart-rending and in some ways tragic but nevertheless hopeful condition, is yet another trial for the human, not the African, race?

Paul the Apostle wrote to the Corinthians many centuries ago.  He said, "No temptation has seized you except what is common to man".  The Greek word for temptation can be translated as trial or test:  No test has seized you, no trial, no temptation have you confronted but what is common to man.  But he goes on, "God is faithful, he will not allow you to be tempted beyond your ability.  But, when you are tempted, he will provide a way out so that you can bear it."  You don't have to be a Christian to see the wisdom in those words.

To advance the notion that a person's race is his most important characteristic is in today's America to commit a great, if common, moral and political error.  Whatever the merits of IQ tests (to return to that theme), there's no inevitability that the scores be bandied about in aggregate racial terms.  If low intelligence is a problem, and I don't know that it is, then it's a problem for people.  It's not lessened by changing the racial identity of those who are at the top or bottom of the IQ hierarchy.

Similarly, if crime is a problem, it is a problem for people, having nothing to do with skin colour.  Yet, a handful of vicious criminals who happen to be black in the US, and who prey disproportionately upon other blacks, can frequently be heard in the propaganda of the racialist to be described as victims.  The result of this propaganda is not to engender sympathy from whites, so much is now quite clear.  Rather, the result is to foster fear of, and contempt for, the very communities from which these criminals have been advertised to have come.

I want to propose that we suppress as much as possible the explicit use of racial categories in the conduct of public affairs.  Of course, I know that this will not erase racial identity as an important factor in society.  But I maintain that, on balance, a conscious effort to achieve a humanistic universal public policy and rhetoric in the US would redound to the social, political and psychological benefit of black Americans.

The Founding Fathers of the American government in the late-eighteenth century faced a similar problem with respect to religion.  Religion was a social fact of life in the American colonies at that time.  People had strong faiths, and the faiths were in conflict.  Yet the men who framed the government of the United States looked back at the last two centuries of European history and saw the years littered with the bodies of the many thousands who had been slaughtered in one war after another in Catholic-Protestant conflict.  They knew that it was deeply unwise to frame a government in which those divisions would be permitted to have explicit cognisance.  They did not deny social reality by excising religion, the recognition of religion, from the American government.  Rather, they accommodated a very profound fact about that reality, which was that those divisions, if reified, if elevated, if underscored and institutionalised, could be the basis of the dissolution of their society.

And so too, in racially diverse societies -- and again, I speak mainly about America but perhaps with resonance for some other nations which, because of migration and historical development, have become multi-racial -- to the extent that we institutionalise, reify, underscore, and admit into our formal governmental structures recognition of conflicting ethnic interests, we may end up buying for ourselves conflicts of the sort that we see being played out bloodily across the central European plain even today.

There is another reason that I raise these matters in the way in which I do.  It has to do particularly with my belief that achieving genuine equality for blacks in the US now depends as much on overcoming the problems of dishonour associated with their troubled legacy of slavery in America as anything else.  I'm motivated to say this in part on the basis of my reading of a very important book by the sociologist, Orlando Patterson, called Slavery and Social Death, in which he argues that the institution of slavery was not properly thought of as property in persons.  I won't go into the esoteric details, but the most important thing was not that people were owned.  What was most important was that they were dishonoured.  He argues that everywhere you look with slavery you see this parasitic relationship in which masters are elevated in their status and slaves denigrated, by virtue of the fact that the slaves have no social existence except that which is mediated by the masters.  He argues with respect to the US that precisely in a Christian democracy was it necessary to legitimate the practice of commerce in human beings by denigrating the worth of those who were being trafficked in.  They had to be seen as something less than fully human, in order for people to justify what was being done.

Now this observation has an implication, and the implication is that emancipation, which is the legal abrogation of the property claim -- one day the President of the US signs a paper which says no more shall we recognise this contract, A does not own B any more -- emancipation does not undo the ideological problem, the problem that creeps into the institutional superstructure of the society having to do with the dishonouring of these persons.  It does not make them respectable, acceptable, equal.

This is deeply problematic, because it has a lot to do with the ways in which blacks are seen by whites, the ways in which they imagine themselves to be seen by whites, and the ways in which they see themselves.  Even to acknowledge that it matters to blacks how they are seen by whites is already to take a step which the racialists, as I have been calling them, would find problematic.

On the other hand, it also confronts a reality.  The reality is that, at the end of slavery, blacks were a dispossessed, ignorant, impoverished peasantry.  And, in the south of the US, for nearly a century thereafter -- with the exception of a decade immediately after the war, when the occupying army of the north enforced the dispensation of Reconstruction -- blacks continued to be in an apartheid-like state of suppression and denigration.

That changed with the civil rights movement and the opening up of opportunity.  But many of the ideas, many of the suspicions, and much of the structure of dishonour and denigration, remained.  It has to be overcome.  As I have said, this is not fair, this is not right.  I would have it that the world were otherwise.  But it's not.

The question then becomes, how do we overcome this?  What has to be done?  There is too much crime in cities associated with black people.  It has to change.  There is disproportionate representation on welfare.  Too many kids born out of wedlock, with an illegitimacy rate of two-thirds among African Americans.  Too many of the youngsters are languishing in the remedial courses at the colleges to which they are admitted.  There is too much of that.

Now I am not an ideological opponent of any manner of social welfare.  I think a certain measure of it is appropriate and we can argue about which programmes and how much.  But the point I want to stress is that no amount of social welfare will overcome what I'm talking about.  The only thing that will dispel it in the end is the accomplishment of black people in America.  The only thing that will end it is to get young men out of the gaols.  We've got to bring the rape rate down -- it is 4 or 5 times higher for black women in cities than it is for white women because of the behaviour of these young men.  We have got to get these youngsters to forgo, if not sexuality then at least child bearing, until they can constitute families and raise these children properly.  We've got to bring some degree of order and -- I'm sorry for the word and I know it sounds quaint -- respectability to the lower-class ghettos of my country.  What's wrong with settlement houses?  What's wrong with Methodist or Baptist preachers with fire and brimstone rhetoric exalting a Christian, if that's the appropriate religious metaphor for that society, way of life to these youngsters?  What indeed is wrong with holding up the highest standards of achievement in the confident expectations that, in the fullness of time, black Americans will, like so many other immigrants of the society, be able to meet those expectations?

When the problem is establishing a base of honour and respectability, patronisation is your enemy.  The client-patron relationship is your enemy.  You don't want sympathetic white liberals hanging around black communities wondering what next they can do to elevate these people.  You don't want their sympathy.  You don't want their understanding that it shouldn't be expected that blacks should be able to perform, should be able to read and write before entering the university or whatever.  You don't want them in the courts letting off people who have committed crimes because "what can you expect, the youngster had no option".  That's the end, that's the sound of the death-knell of any possibility of equality in the society.  No amount of client-patron understanding, no amount of generosity, turning the other cheek, a shrugging kind of resignation among whites that -- "nothing more can be expected but we should accommodate because after all we are responsible for all this".  No amount of that can allow black people to be equal.  There is only one path.  It's a hard path, but it's a feasible path.  The obstacles for the pursuit of that path lie as much in the ideas, in the heads, of certain liberals -- whom I used to describe as well-meaning, but am no longer willing to do so -- as in any question about how large the social budget is in the US.

Thank you very much.


QUESTION TIME

KEN

Mr Wood, thank you very much.  We have our normal period of questions to follow that address you have just heard.  We'd like to invite our whole audience to offer themselves to ask questions.  We have a few already nominated, but if you would like to put a question to Mr Wood would you indicate your interest to my colleague, so he can give you a microphone.


ROBIN McCONCHIE

You talk about this American tradition of the exhibition of non-achievement as the basis for special treatment for ethnic and minority groups.  What success have black or non-white American politicians who support your views had in reducing the poverty trap and improving the situation facing the sort of people you are speaking about?  And, second question, it sounds a bit gauche, but what is your impression of the O.J. Simpson case, and its status and what it reflects about American society at the moment?


RICHARD WOOD

Well, I'm not going to comment on the O.J. Simpson case.  To be honest with you, I don't follow it.  I stopped following it about six months ago.  Really.  But there is enough written that one should be able to get a range of views in the press.

But your first question is fair.  And the honest answer to you is that there are so few politicians of an ethnic minority persuasion who take my point of view as yet, that there is not much of a track record to point to.  There are a few and there are increasingly more.  I wouldn't only look to politicians though, in answer to your question.  Because I believe a more productive area of inquiry would be to look, in those inner-city communities, to the most positive efforts at reconstruction and assistance that are going on.

Who has success at getting drug-addicted people back off drugs and into a clean life?  Who has success at working with teen mothers and ensuring that they don't become the mothers of three, four, or five children and that they can get their acts together and so on?  Who is successful in working with ex-offenders, young men who have had a prison record but want to straighten up their lives and get their act together and move forward?  There are many pockets of such success that one can point to.

One can point to public housing projects that had been dens of dope-dealing and gang residence that have been turned around through the work of community agencies of people who have gone door-to-door, kid-to-kid.  One can point to very successful drug rehabilitation programmes, some of which are secular, some of which depend heavily on private charity, which have also been successful.

If you go to an American city, as a reporter for the ABC, and you walk around and you talk to the black policemen, the black social workers, the black orderlies at the public hospital, the black American religious leaders who are running church ministries and so forth, the postal workers who might still be living in a depressed inner city area, and you ask them what positive things are happening in their communities, they will be able to point to some things.  Moreover, while they certainly would not describe themselves as conservatives, and they probably did not vote Republican in the last election, they would nevertheless, I suggest, describe the problem in ways not dissimilar to the way that I have described it:  which is to say, we don't want white liberals hanging around here making excuses for us, it's time that we quit belly-aching and got on with the work that has to be done -- "that building across the street, there is no reason why those people have to have trash out the front of it.  The trash can be picked up".  "You can live with dignity even if modestly".  "I wish those people would look after their kids and stop them from engaging in that loud behaviour and conduct themselves in a more orderly fashion", and so on.

That outlook is not -- and that's in part what I was trying to say, that's in part why the crimes of racialists are so outrageous -- new in African American history.  How could a people otherwise have survived -- and indeed, to the extent that they did, prosper under the repressive conditions that existed in the South of the US for the half century between 1880 and 1930 -- if they didn't have character, they didn't have mettle, they didn't have some sense of themselves.  They have had that.  They continue substantially to have it.

It's a controversial interpretation of the last 30 years of American history, but it is the one that I hold, that it wasn't until they got to the mid-to-late civil rights period and to the error of the Great Society -- and I'm now not talking about the causal effect of Federal spending, I'm talking about the attitudinal consequences of patronising white liberalism -- it wasn't until then that you heard people say:  "Are young black women having babies and have no husbands?  Well, what can we expect?  Are young black men committing violent crimes?  Well, we should bear that, we can understand it, after all they have to feed their families".  Those two arguments are contradictory;  but never mind.  "Are young blacks not able to meet the standard in school?  Well, let's not have a standard.  If we put in a test and we make graduation conditional on showing your competency at the level of the test then we may disproportionately affect the disadvantaged group, and we wouldn't want to do that."

The alternative assumption is that we put in the test, we set a standard for people, they will measure up to it, if not today then tomorrow.  But it seems too much to believe the possibility that they can be in control of their own lives.  It wasn't too much to believe for the people at City University in New York, which had been the engine of social mobility and integration for generation after generation of European immigrants.  The Jews from Russia had come to New York City.  They didn't score well on IQ tests either, but they went to City University, they met the standards and they prospered.  Similarly, the Italians from Sicily, the Poles and so on, they came to the US, despised because they spoke in a funny way, looked a funny way with odd habits, lived in tenements and ghettos.  They prospered.

But, come the 1970s, when it's time for blacks to make that step, what happens at City University?  They go to open admissions.  They guarantee admissions into the college for everyone who graduates from the high school, without regard as to whether or not they can perform competently.  What now is City University?  Well, it is a large institution and there are many things there.  But at the City College campus of City University, which had been a bedrock of achievement and excellence in generations past, what happens now is that you have an academic ghetto, you have a glorified high school, you have a situation where 40 per cent of the registrants are in remedial classes trying to get themselves prepared to take college courses.

It can be a self-fulfilling prophecy when we tell people we don't think you are capable of much but we are going to do something for you anyway.  Many of the successful community workers and people who are struggling to try to make a positive difference in the inner city communities will agree with me about that.  They will agree that it is time to treat people with the elemental dignity that they deserve by holding up a standard of expectation to them -- just like that which one would hold up to anyone else in society -- and demanding that they meet it.


MATTHEW FROST

In Australia, you may be aware that there is a debate currently occurring about the need or otherwise for racial hatred legislation.  Whilst it would probably be unfair to ask your views on what has been proffered in the Parliament, what are your views on the need in general for racial hatred legislation as a means of reducing the incidence of such a thing in society?  Do you think it is effective and do you think that the constraints on things like free speech make such an entity something that we shouldn't be dealing with at the moment?


RICHARD WOOD

I won't come in on the Australian legislation.  I am from a country that doesn't have a Bill of Rights and the First Amendment is an important part of that.  On the other hand, as the great Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes once said, the First Amendment right doesn't authorise you to shout "fire" in a crowded theatre.  If I were at a soccer match and there were whites sitting here and blacks sitting there, and someone begins to shout "fire" in the crowded theatre and engaging in an incitement, the result of which is a riot in which people are hurt and trampled and killed, that's a very bad thing.  A person should be punished for that.  On the other hand, you have the following situation.  I call you a dumb Polack -- say you're Polish and say I'm black -- I call you a racist white Nazi, a skinhead, a pig.  It's unpleasant, but it shouldn't be illegal.  You call me a Kaffir, I don't like it but at the end of the day it is just a word.  My judgement is that it shouldn't be accepted, it shouldn't be thought well of, it ought to be penalised socially.  But my own personal view about the US is that I would not want to see such language made illegal.

And the reason is twofold.  One is the Constitutional argument that I made.  People are expressing themselves.  The right response to speech that I don't like is more speech.  I don't like what the person said, I want to show my disapproval of it.  If I'm running a classroom and someone stands up and speaks impolitely to another student, in answer to one of their comments, my answer to that is not to expel the student from school for having violated some legal technician's dividing line about what's legal or not.  Our answer has always been social pressures, ostracising and disapproving of people who speak rudely.  After all, society wasn't invented last year;  people have managed to get along together, despite the fact that they haven't always liked each other.  And, by the way, there are many things you can say without invoking a racial epithet that will be vastly more disgusting and disrespectful of a person than calling them a name.  Our response has always been to deal with that socially and that's the method that I would recommend.

The other reason is that you don't stop people from thinking and talking like this.  You just make them mind their p's and q's while the Brave New World thought-police are on hand.  You don't control the kitchen table conversation.  You don't control the conversation outside the bar.  That still flourishes.  So at the end of the day, if you think you have solved the problem by passing an Act of Parliament when in fact the only real solution to it is a deeper social education that brings people into a real tolerance and a genuine mutual respect, then you turn your head away from the underlying thing that continues to smoulder, a backlash waiting to blow up in your face down the line.


AMANDA MEADE

You hinted at the beginning of your speech that you didn't want to comment on Australian issues, but I would be interested to see how your argument could be applied to racial inequalities in South Africa and in Australia.  Without affirmative action and specific government programmes for, say, Aborigines in Australia, how can they overcome the disadvantage that they suffered from very recent human rights violations?


RICHARD WOOD

Fair enough.  South Africa is a country with 44 million people.  Some 75 per cent are black, and they are not in the position of a minority making special pleading to a powerful majority to recognise and accommodate their claims because they have been victimised.  Rather, they are potentially a quite powerful and dispossessing majority, negotiating in their own understood interest with a property-owning and skilled minority component of the population so as to try to effect a peaceable transition, if possible, into a new political order.  Those circumstances are so different from America and Australia as to be quite startling.

To the extent that there is affirmative action in South Africa, I assume that it will not be because patronising white liberals decide that the blacks cannot make it on their own and they need a helping hand.  It will rather be the instrumentality by which a brokered accommodation of conflicting interests is managed.  I'll argue with you that some of the greatest constraining pressures on affirmative action in South Africa will come from blacks who understand that, if they kill the golden goose of economic efficiency that's the only hope for economic growth, they only hurt themselves in the long run.

With respect to the Australian Aboriginal situation, I know a lot about it.  But I will certainly say it is hard to imagine that a people as underdeveloped, disadvantaged -- that such a condition of backwardness or underdevelopment could be reversed without the injection of some resources.  Who would say otherwise?  It would certainly seem to me that it would be appropriate and morally right for there to be an injection of resources.  If forced to apply my argument about blacks in America to this situation, I would rather look to the question of how the Aborigines should rightly think about their own situation.  The essence of my concern regarding black Americans is that they must change the way in which they look at themselves, and their relations with whites.  There may be no parallel at all, but to the extent that there is any, it's this:  a racial minority seeking equality and dignity within the larger society cannot attain it while remaining the clients of the more powerful majority.


GAY DAVIDSON

Richard, please don't think I am trying to press you on an Australian issue.  I think that it can be interpreted much more broadly.

Politically, judicially, and administratively there are very widely varying degrees of sympathy for Aboriginal black tribal laws and lore.  We have been seeing a problem in just the last week or two there because part of those laws and lore actually break down to men's business and women's business and the one gender may not know what the other is on about.  And the situation has arisen where there is a commercial development interest in all of this too.  Would your feeling be that the black Australian laws and lore should be upheld by their people or should they let their culture be subsumed?


RICHARD WOOD

Well God knows I have no opinion on that!

What I think is this, again very tentatively.  The answer to that question is fundamentally important.  If that sounds like a cop-out, I'm sorry.  It seems to me that that is one of the critical issues:  whether or not this is one society, or two.  And whether, if it's not one society now, it should be that in 50 years, or whether or not one reckons it's always going to be two societies and it's a matter as between governments of working out a set of relations that are appropriate.

That's a very peculiarly Australian question.  What I can say, though, is that you are never going to get an answer to the question if you don't talk about it.  If you don't pose the question, if instead you grope in a way that tries to avoid ever pointedly bringing to the fore what is after all perhaps the fundamental conceptual issue that has to be resolved, before you can know what your goals are, against which you measure whether or not your policy achieves them.  So I urge you to ask yourselves the question, with Aboriginal persons present in the conversation.


JOAN McNAMEE

I have so much in common deep down inside me with what you have been saying and I have got to be brief because our time is up.  So one thing I wanted to mention quickly is that at an international community education conference in Melbourne, a lovely lady from one of our Housing Commissions said from her point of view just what you are saying of many people who are in the position of receiving welfare visits.  And she said that these people who came down and visited were working off their own frustrations.  And most of the people whom they were visiting knew how to get on with each other a darn sight better and look after each other than the comfortably-off person visiting them.  Also, that I put a lot of blame on the propaganda of Hitler and Goebbels for this stupid myth of exclusive races.  But I discovered a school human geography book, dated just after the turn of century and published in Britain, which talked of five colours of skins as the five races -- but for convenience they made them into three colours of skins!  It is this stupid false information which upsets our decent human attitudes.  So, please keep working and help us to become sensitively keen to have honest information.


RICHARD WOOD

Thank you very much and I will indeed do so.


PROFESSOR ZUBRZYCKI

Richard, one proposition which is often bandied about by our multicultural institutionalised lobby, and I happened to be its intellectual father many years ago, is that all cultures are equal.  No matter what practices are to be found in particular cultures, we are all equal.  Would you like to comment on that?


RICHARD WOOD

Yes, I suppose there is no way I could not comment on it.  I have heard this idea in the US also.  Well, look, it's obvious that all cultures are not equal at producing an industrial civilisation or at expanding scientific knowledge.  So much is obvious.  So if one says that, one can't mean that -- one means something else.  Perhaps one means that, at some higher level, all cultures are equally worthy of the respectful regard of those who are not themselves a product of them.  That is, outsiders when looking at a different culture should not be judgemental -- Oh, those people have these sexual practices, or they live in that kind of a living arrangement, or whatever it might be -- but, one should in some sense be agnostic, simply acknowledging that these are different ways of life.  I regard so much as reasonable and appropriate, as a normative proposition.

Why should I feel superior?  I am myself a product of western industrial society.  That's all I know, that's my life, my culture, that's who I am.  Why should I feel superior to the South Sea Islanders simply because they live differently than I?  Should I take satisfaction in saying of their culture that it is primitive, backward, or whatever, simply because it has not given rise to industrial civilisation?  It is not at all clear that the worth of a culture is well measured by the extent to which it approximates western industrial society.  Indeed, perhaps the contrary, there is an ethical perspective from which one could criticise industrial societies for being improvident stewards of our global inheritance.  So, yes and no is my answer to you.

I would be prepared to say that cultures are equal with respect to having the legitimate expectation that they not be judged for being different from something else.  On the other hand, I think as a pragmatic matter, given one's goals, it is quite evident that all cultures are not equally capable of producing those goals.  Hence, the most important question is the question of values.  What are our goals, what would we like to see?  How do we want to live?  And not those of judging the intrinsic worth of one or another way of life, divorced from a conception of what objectives one would like to achieve.


KEN

Richard you have excited some student interest.  There are potentially 5 questions there.  I am not sure we will be able to handle that, but here is the first one.


DAMIEN PACE

With reference to the problem in America, will the reduction of welfare to teen mothers eliminate the creation of an underclass of potential criminals?


RICHARD WOOD

I don't think so, is the short answer.  This is a much-argued subject and recent testimony before the US House of Representatives said as much.  The argument basically is this.  Welfare subsidises out-of-wedlock births.  Out-of-wedlock births are a terrible thing.  Therefore, if we are going to make a society better, we have to end the subsidy because then we will get fewer out-of-wedlock births.  That's basically what people argue in so many words.

There is a little bit of evidence that there might be some effect on the birth rate from cutting the subsidy, but I think not enough to warrant the conclusion that cutting it would reverse the birthrate, particularly when one considers that the subsidy will never be totally cut.  It is a matter of cutting back.

On the other hand, I would make the following analogy.  You can pull on a string and unravel a garment.  So the seductive attractions of the financial benefits of welfare may seduce people in larger numbers to get themselves into the condition of unmarried child-bearing.  But pushing on the string won't reweave the fabric.  So here we are 30 years down the line.  There has been a sexual revolution and women's roles have changed dramatically in the world.  A huge welfare state has grown up in the US where it hadn't existed before and these are dramatic changes attended by great changes in people's social behaviour.  Some link exists between the two.  But reversing this little bit of margin of the welfare state and expecting that that somehow is going to change the sexual mores of the large communities in the inner city in which patterns of behaviour are observed?  I don't find that plausible.


JIM CULLENS

My question, coming back to Australia once again, you mentioned multiculturalism.  Could I just read a very short comment on multiculturalism?  It is from Peter Hollingworth, Anglican Bishop of Brisbane.  "Multiculturalism runs the risk of emphasising difference to the exclusion of what we hold in common.  I believe that issue needs to be challenged on the grounds that if we fail to articulate a commonly-agreed set of goals and directions we are likely to move down a path towards fragmentation and social disintegration."  In the American context, but relating to Australia, I would appreciate your comments on that.


RICHARD WOOD

I think that's right, that's a part of what I was arguing.  Take this prior question:  Are we one nation or are we two, or perhaps many?  If you answer that we are one nation now, we are a democracy, we have to reckon with each other, we are going to live under a common set of laws, we are going to go off and fight the war to defend our borders together if it comes to that, well, now we really do have to get along.

I'll say this much about the O.J. Simpson trial.  We can't have riots breaking out in the cities of the US because the verdict goes one way or the other.  That's the end.  When that starts happening the society is indeed fragmenting and pulling itself apart.  We can't have people deciding whether or not they'll serve in the military when called to defend the country on the basis of whether or not they like the racial composition of the current leadership of the government.

If we are two countries then that is a different matter.  We don't have to have some kind of mutual regard and commonality or understanding.  We deal with each other across the treaty boundary.  But when we are one nation, and we are a democracy, we have to be able to persuade each other -- and according to my argument it's in the minority interest that those discourses of persuasion occur on a level of our humanity and focus as much as possible on what we have in common.  By the way, when you are hungry it doesn't matter what colour you are, you are hungry if you are a mother with no money.  The kid does have to be fed and housed.  So, nothing I say here argues against a decent provision.  Again, we can argue about what that means and how to do it, but nothing I say cuts against the idea that there would be a decent provision to the disadvantaged.  Because the disadvantaged class and poverty know no colour bound.  They know no racial or ethnic bound.  So, it is my very strong conviction that in a democracy one should conduct one's public affairs, in so far as it is possible, in terms of common human interests and the ideals of society as whole, and one should not gratuitously provoke the differences that already exist.


KEN

I apologise to the growing number of people who want to ask questions but this next one will have to be our last.


NIGEL

I'm just personally interested -- have you been taking your views outside of Boston Uni to younger African American youth in America and, if so, what has been their response to your views?


RICHARD WOOD

I appreciate the question very much.  Both in churches and in secondary schools, just this past year, I have been doing a speaking tour that one of the American foundations has sponsored that allows me to go around to different prep schools and public high schools which have integrated student bodies.  They are not all African American but there are certainly plenty of black American and Hispanic American and Asian American students who are present in these student bodies.

The response varies.  People are interested and intrigued.  I think they are made to think.  I don't believe that my younger generation is nearly as fixed -- and I speak now about students like yourself who are 15, 16, 17 years old or something like that -- not nearly as rigidly fixed in their conceptions of how this thing has to go, as are people of our older generation who came through the 60s and 70s when the intellectual foundations of the currently existing order were set up, though I hope they are soon to be overturned.  We younger people who have interactions across the ethnic boundary lines, who learn to get along with each other in the dormitories and classrooms -- it's a complex matter but their identity is still being shaped and formed.  These are critical years, mid to late adolescence, for the setting of identity.

Another thing I mention is that in the US you have many mixed-race young people, that is, African Americans, black Americans who are actually the products of inter-racial marriage.  When I say many, I mean maybe a few hundred thousand.  Which would only be a small percentage.  One or two percent of total population.  Of course, many more of you are ultimately of mixed heritage.  Very few black Americans would be purely of African descent after so many years in that kind of society.

But this later generation has started to express itself.  So you can see poignant articles in some magazines where a 22-year old will be telling the story of how they never knew that they had to choose to be black or white until they went to college.  You know what I mean, the kid grows up, the mother is white, the father is black, they live in suburban Cleveland or whatever, they go to high school, they have their white grandparents and their black grandparents, their white cousins, and their black cousins, and they see themselves as both black and white -- which is not unreasonable.  But when they get to college, the peer pressures are at them to identify.  Are you black?  Are you going to join the black organisations?  Are you going to live in the black dorm?  Are you going to march for the black cause?  And they're not accepted as simply being both black and white American, they have to decide whether they are going to be black or white.  And you can see that that would be quite problematic.  Well, I have heard those stories from young people.

So, what I want to say to you is -- no, I don't have the endorsement of the youth of Australia to come here to America and give this speech.  On the other hand, what I say is not categorically rejected by young people of colour in Australia.  They need to hear many voices in order to sort their way through some very difficult issues of identity.

Thank you very much.


KEN

Thank you very much, Mr Richard Wood.  We were speaking just before the event began about whether there was any realistic separation between the disciplines of economics and politics and you can probably see now where Mr Wood stands on that issue.  And we got through without one statistic, too!  One of our customs here, Richard, is for first-time speakers to receive, as a memento of the occasion, a Boston University tie which, given the splendid taste showing around your neck, you don't necessarily have to wear.  You could frame it perhaps.  Thank you very much for being with us today.


RICHARD WOOD

Thank you so much.  Pleasure to be here.

Tuesday, August 01, 1995

Taxation in the post war years

PREFACE

The review of taxation in this booklet was completed before the surrender of Japan.  As it was drafted on the assumption of an early end to the Japanese war, the main conclusions are little, if at all, affected.

The study comprises a broad survey of future taxation from the standpoint of economic and industrial policy.  It does not attempt to cover, or to make recommendations upon, the complex technical problems which arise in the determination of the exact nature and incidence of particular taxes.  These are matters requiring the attention of experts in taxation with ready access to all relevant information and with powers to obtain evidence and opinions.

A Summary of this booklet appeared in the Melbourne "Herald" and Adelaide "Advertiser" on August 28, 1995.  Since that date the first post-war budget has been brought down.  It is desirable therefore to stress that the recommendations and observations in this report are not restricted to the first post-war year, but refer to the several years which may be termed the post-war period.

August, 1995.



ARTICLE I -- POST-WAR TAXATION:  GENERAL PRINCIPLES

Taxation is one of the central problems of post-war economic and social policy.

We have come a long way from the days when an income tax of 1/- in the £1 could arouse the most furious political contentions and be attacked by its opponents as outright confiscation and as morally despicable.  In the light of later experience one would find it difficult to resist the conclusion that in those distant times taxation held a position in the public mind and in political and economic controversy far in advance of its true significance.  Even in 1939, when taxation in Australia on the higher incomes amounted roughly to 5/- in the £, the burden could be borne without radical readjustment of modes of life and without noticeable effects on the productive efforts of the people.  Up to the time of the outbreak of war nothing had occurred to suggest that taxation of these proportions had in any way seriously damaged the foundations of the Australian economy.  At any rate we entered the war, if not in a state of robust health, at least in one which gave no indication of early demise.

But after four years of wartime taxation at unprecedented levels the whole problem has assumed a new proportion and a tremendously increased national importance.  The great majority of Australians now realise with painful acuteness the personal, if not the national, significance of taxation, and cry out for relief.  But the prospect, while not one of unrelieved gloom, could hardly be called rosy.


HIGH LEVEL OF POST-WAR TAXATION CERTAIN

To-day not even the most cheerful optimist in his most sanguine moments could envisage a return to taxation of the 1939 proportions.  Indeed, many feel that we will be fortunate if we can get the burden of taxation down to double what it was in the pre-war days.  While anything approaching the present wartime levels would be unthinkable, we are forced to recognise that the magnitude of taxation in the future will be vastly greater than ever before in our peacetime economic history.  So will its spread -- in 1939 only about 300,000 people were paying income tax;  to-day taxes are paid by over 1,700,000 people and the number may not be greatly less after the war.  Taxation will extend to every corner of the economic structure;  it will influence directly every business decision and enterprise;  it will enter into practically every economic calculation as a factor of major importance.  From being a comparative mouse in the pre-war economy, it will be, if not a giant after the war -- and that is possible -- at least something to be reckoned with at every step.  The very size of post-war taxation calls for a new approach and a more intensive examination of its relation to the whole economic problem.

What has brought about this change?  Why should we have fought a lengthy and arduous war to end up having to carry a far heavier load of taxation than when we began?

These questions can be briefly answered.  We have chosen to allot to the state a position in the national life of much increased importance and extent, and we must pay the price of our decision.  This general agreement on the need for the state to undertake new functions is, of course, accompanied by profound disagreements on the nature of those functions and how they should be carried out.  Much of what the present Commonwealth administration has recently done, and proposes to do, has been severely, and often justly, criticised.  Nevertheless, post-war planners, no matter what their political colour or inclination, and however much they may disagree about the essential character of the kind of Australia they want after war, are at one in calling upon governments to render increased services -- often without counting the cost.

Thus for "full employment" the state must supplement and possibly, to some degree, regulate the activities of private enterprise.  To achieve a basic security for all, the state must institute schemes of financial assistance to protect its citizens against economic misfortune and the financial consequences of old age.  So that all its members will have adequate medical treatment, be properly educated, clothed, fed and housed, the state must increase its expenditure in the field of social services.  To achieve a greater measure of national security against external attack, the state must take upon itself the responsibility of maintaining larger peacetime armies, navies, air-forces and defence industries.

This is not the place to discuss the rights and wrongs of all these new demands on governments.  Enough to say that the war has aroused the social conscience and commended the great aim, so well expressed by Sir William Beveridge, of eliminating the giant evils of Want, Disease, Ignorance, Squalor and Idleness, to all right-minded people.  It is, however, certain that many planners who have gone gaily ahead placing orders on the national exchequer, have received more than a mild shock when presented with the bill of costs.


PRIMARY FUNCTION OF TAXATION

The obvious function of taxation is to raise revenue to meet the current costs of government.  The capital charges of the state can, in general, best be met from loan money or, in certain circumstances, from the expansion of central bank credit -- the latter, if wrongly used, would amount to disguised taxation.  But the current operating charges of the state must by and large be met and, in the long run, balanced from the proceeds of taxation.  The greater these charges, the higher must be the level of taxation.


TAXABLE CAPACITY

To what heights then can taxation safely be raised without producing ill-effects on the economy, or, in the terms of the economist, what is the taxable capacity of a country?  This question, which was chiefly of academic interest under the conditions ruling before the war, is likely to become of very real and practical concern in the future when the weight of taxation will press heavily on the resources and work of the nation.  It is a question which admits of no simple and direct answer.  When a famous British economist was asked how the taxable capacity of a nation could be ascertained he facetiously replied "Nohow".  This reply was probably not far from the truth at the time at which it was made, when taxation, at levels contemplated for Australia after the war, was unheard of, and even un-thought of.  It is by no means unlikely, however, that bitter experience in experimenting with very heavy taxation in the post-war years may give us some idea of where the taxable capacity of a democratic community, such as Australia, lies.

In any case from the conception of taxable capacity spring some of the most important problems of taxation policy.


TAXATION AND PRODUCTION

The first thing to note is that the amount of taxation which a community can stand varies with the total amount of wealth produced by its people or, in other words, with the size of its national income.  A country such as the United States, with great wealth, resources and productive capabilities, could sustain without feeling any ill-effects a per capita level of taxation which the people of a poor and undeveloped nation such as China would find unbearable, and even those of Australia, oppressive.  No consideration of the real burden of taxation is therefore possible without taking into account the size of the national income on which taxes are levied.  On this count it is not unreasonable to suppose that Australia will be in a position after the war to sustain a higher level of taxation than it could have done before the war, without incurring any increased strain.  But this would depend entirely of course on whether the per capita income of the nation is increased through greater efficiency, high productivity throughout industry, and a more economic application of resources.

It is impossible to emphasise too strongly that all taxation comes out of the total national production, and that the original source of the revenue of the state is the efforts and enterprise of the citizens of the state.  But if taxation is raised too high and the individual finds that a large part of his earnings is subtracted, his incentive to work, his inclination to take risks, and his ability to save will suffer, and the national income will fall.  Taxation above a certain limit must inevitably tend to dry up the source from which it is drawn.  The crucial problem of post-war taxation policy in Australia will be to find this limit, and for economic statesmanship to see that it is not exceeded.  Nothing could be more disastrous to the economy of the country and the standards of the people than a diminution of the total national production.  With taxation at pre-war levels, the effects on production were possibly negligible;  but with taxation at the high mark which is probable after the war, the most rigorous attention will need to be paid to economic incentives and to the financial resources left in the hands of industry for expanding, and for improving the efficiency of, its plant and equipment.


NEW CONCEPTION OF FUNCTIONS OF TAXATION

These considerations have led authorities in other countries, which are also facing a much heavier peacetime burden of taxation, to place first among the objectives of taxation that it should impose the least possible restriction upon an expansion of production and employment.  The point is well made in an editorial in the American journal "Fortune".

"A new kind of tax bill must be written.  It will be less a bill to raise revenue, than a bill to facilitate production and employment.  True, the effect of taxes on business activity is an old story -- it was the ultimate preoccupation of Adam Smith.  But aggregate taxes of 4 or 5 billion dollars -- the pre-war federal yields -- are one thing;  taxes of 15 billion dollars or more are something else again.  Taxes in this volume could be a determining influence for prosperity or depression."

TAXATION AND EMPLOYMENT

We should note here the mention of the word "employment".  An entirely new conception of the purposes of taxation lies in the possibility that it can be used as an instrument for assisting to maintain steady employment by ironing out the peaks and valleys of economic activity.  In the past conditions of great business prosperity have often led to reductions in taxation.  But this is just the time when the community is most able to stand a relatively heavy burden of tax.  Conversely when economic activity declines the community is least able to bear taxation.  By reducing taxes and leaving more money in the pockets of the people, and in the coffers of business, spending and investment is encouraged and business activity stimulated.  Recognition of this new function of taxation finds a place in most discussions of post-war employment policy.  For political reasons, however, its practical application will be far more difficult than its theoretical acceptance.


KINDS OF TAXES

Given a certain amount of money to be raised by taxation for the uses of governments, the real burden on the community and the effects, whether for good or ill on the whole economy will depend partly on how the money is raised and partly on how it is spent.  In Australia it has been customary for governments to use four main kinds of tax:

  1. Direct taxation on the incomes of individuals.
  2. Direct taxation on the profits or incomes of businesses.
  3. Taxation on capital, such as probate charges and estate duties.
  4. Indirect taxes of various kinds such as sales taxes and customs and excise duties.

From the standpoint of economic policy all these taxes have both merits and defects.  One of the most delicate and important adjustments of post-war finance will be to decide how the state's need of revenue should be allocated between the different types of tax so as to place the smallest possible obstacles in the way of national production and economic progress.  For instance, with a given sum of money to be acquired by taxation, is it advisable to maintain a relatively high level of taxation on personal incomes and to reduce sales taxes to negligible proportions?  And, within the field of personal income tax would it be advantageous to further widen the divergence between taxation on income from property and income from work?  Or again, do the requirements of industrial efficiency dictate that taxes on company profits should be kept to a minimum, and the resultant loss to the treasury recouped from other sources?  These and similar questions will be examined in later articles.


GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE

The burden of taxation on the community cannot be considered apart from the manner in which the revenue is spent after it has been raised.  It is possible that adverse effects caused by tax exactions may be more than offset by the benefits conferred on the community through wise expenditure by governments.  In fact, the central problem of public finance, and one might almost say of modern economics, resolves itself into balancing the advantages to be gained by increasing the expenditures of the state against those which would accrue if the money were left in private hands.  A great deal of course depends on the particular type of spending undertaken by the state.  For instance, it would clearly have been to the net benefit of the Australian people in the years before the war if governments had used much more of the community's income to strengthen the defences of the nation.  For this purpose an increase in taxation would have been amply justified.  On the other hand, one could point to many instances of wasteful government expenditure, and to a number of public projects which had better been never undertaken.

In other words, as a leading authority has stated:  "It is not possible to pass a complete judgment upon any operation in public finance without balancing against one another both sides of the operation, the effects of the raising, and the effects of the spending, of public revenue".  It does not require much reflection to appreciate that the tendency of a great deal of post-war planning is to disregard the former and to consider only the latter operation.  This is probably the reverse of the tendency before the war, and certainly the complete reverse of accepted thought a century or so ago when a contemporary economist could say:  "The very best of all plans of finance is to spend little, and the best of all taxes is that which is least in amount."


TWO PROPOSALS

In this article we have given a broad sketch of the purposes and of some of the main problems of taxation policy.  It would be premature at this stage to attempt detailed suggestions, but two broad proposals can already be made with assurance.


EXPERT STUDY NECESSARY

First, the new high level of public expenditure in Australia calls for comprehensive "and expert study of taxation in relation to its effects on the entire field of economic policy particularly on problems of production, industrial efficiency, incentives and employment.  In other countries this is being done.  In the United States several notable taxation plans have already appeared.  These have resulted in the main from the efforts of private citizens.  Perhaps the one which has aroused the most interest is that of the Committee for Economic Development, an organisation formed by a number of leading industrialists, and playing a significant part in the preparation of the American economy to meet the new problems and demands of the coming peace.  In Britain, the Government has given special attention to the taxation of industry with a view to promoting its rapid recovery after the war, and to placing it on a competitive basis with the industries of other nations.  Already certain far-reaching measures involving significant tax concessions have been placed before Parliament.  In Canada, two important investigations, are, at the time of writing, under way.

The second proposal is that, even if the Commonwealth Government is not yet in the happy position of being able to give precise indications of its post-war tax intentions, at least it should point the direction in which it will move as soon as circumstances allow.  Is it possible for us to expect some reduction, and if so, of what general nature and of what rough proportions?  Otherwise we will enter the peace, ill-prepared in comparison with other nations, ill-equipped for the giant problems of post-war reconstruction.  It is impossible for either business or individuals to plan ahead with assurance, and in a practical and effective manner, while the present uncertainty prevails.



ARTICLE II -- THE BUDGET OF POST-WAR COSTS

The starting point of any realistic discussion of post-war taxation must be some forecast of the expenses of Commonwealth and State Governments which it will be necessary to meet from taxation after the war.  It is idle to talk of this or that reduction in taxation unless we have some general idea of the future expenditures to which governments are already largely committed and which will need to be paid for out of the proceeds of taxation.  Naturally any estimates of government expenses must be approximate, but on the basis of present knowledge it is possible to get a useful idea of the magnitude of the main items in the post-war budget of government costs.


PRINCIPLE OF PUBLIC FINANCE

It is a commonly accepted and sound principle of public finance that, over the years, receipts from taxation and other sources of current revenue should be at least adequate to cover the current costs of governments.

The two main items in the current expenditures of Australian governments consist, first, of cash payments to individuals, such as unemployment, sickness and repatriation benefits, military pensions, child endowment, invalid and old age pensions and similar social benefits;  and, second, of interest and sinking fund payable on the national debt, comprising both the part held in Australia and the part held overseas.  Other important charges of a current nature are the administrative costs of the various government departments, including social service costs on account of health and education, and the operating charges of the defence services.


ESTIMATES OF POST-WAR COMMITMENTS

On all these items, and particularly on the first two, the post-war costs of governments are certain to be vastly greater than before the war.  For instance, the cost of social payments, which in 1938/9 amounted to about £30 millions, is likely to be somewhere in the region of £100 millions a year in the post-war period.  In 1943/4 these payments had risen to £77 millions.  This figure will expand over the next four years, because of increases on account of child endowment, military pensions and other benefits, and higher prices.

In 1938/9 interest and sinking fund on the national debt held in Australia and abroad was about £52 millions.  In 1943/4 it was approaching £80 millions.  Borrowing will remain high while the war with Japan continues, and will probably be fairly high after the war to finance large public works and developmental programmes.  Three or four years hence the interest and sinking fund bill may be close to £110 millions.

In 1938/9 £8 millions from current revenue was spent on national defence.  After the war £60 millions a year has been suggested as a minimum figure for the total cost of defence.  Some of this expenditure, such as the cost of military buildings and naval vessels, would be in the nature of capital investment, but assuming 50% -- which would seem reasonable -- to consist of operating costs, the post-war defence charge to be met from current revenue would be £30 millions compared with £8 millions in 1938/9.

In addition to the claims on the national finances just « mentioned, numerous other items, such as the administrative costs of government departments and subsidies to aid ~ financially distressed industries, must be met out of the f, proceeds of taxation.  Among the most important of these sundry items are health and educational services, both of which are certain to expand after the war.  In 1938/9 these sundry items of expenditure amounted to £64 millions.  In 1943/4 they had risen to £73 millions.  It is unlikely that it will be possible to reduce this figure after the war.  On the contrary it will almost certainly increase.  Decreases in some items, such as wartime costs of administering government departments, can reasonably be expected, but these will probably be more than counter-balanced by increases in other directions -- particularly in health and educational services.  On the assumption -- an optimistic one -- of the strictest economy and efficiency in government administration, a reasonable estimate of these sundry items might be of the order of £85 millions.


POST-WAR EXPENSES TO BE MET FROM CURRENT REVENUE

On the basis of this forecast, government expenses to be met from current revenue, after the completion of the main demobilisation of the forces and industry, would be as follows:

Social Payments£100 millions
Interest and Sinking Fund£110 millions
Defence£30 millions
Sundry Items£85 millions
Total£325 millions

This would compare with £155 millions in 1938/9 and £368 millions in 1943/4.

In addition to taxation governments have other sources of current revenue -- for example, business undertakings such as the Post Office, sales of land, legal fines.  In 1938/9 net income from business undertakings and other revenue was £28 millions;  in 1943/4, £45 millions.  Informed quarters have estimated it at between £50 and £60 millions after the war.  Assuming £50 millions from these sources, £275 millions would have to be raised annually from taxation to cover a total current expenditure of £325 millions.


CONTRIBUTORY SOCIAL SERVICES

It would be wishful thinking to suppose that any material reduction in the post-war costs indicated above will be possible.  We are already committed to a huge bill for social payments, and even if it desired to do so, it would be politically impracticable for any government to reverse the trend, common to all modern democracies, toward increased cash benefits from the public purse.  Social payments of the order of £100 millions annually are already an established part of the Australian economic and social pattern of the future. (1)  Even should these services be placed on a contributory foundation -- as many people, with complete justification, contend -- instead of being paid for, as at present, almost entirely out of national revenue, it is difficult to see how any great alleviation of the real burden on the community would result.  Certainly the weekly or monthly tax deductions from the pay envelope or salary cheque of the individual would be diminished, but this advantage would be, to a considerable degree, offset by compulsory deductions on account of his contribution to the social insurance fund.  This does not mean, however, that the burden as between different individuals and income groups would not be changed, or that it would not be more equitably distributed.  But social services must be paid for either way.  Some lightening of the apparent burden there would certainly be -- and this is of greater importance than may appear on the surface.  But the argument in favour of the contributory system, although not without financial and economic justification, is chiefly moral and spiritual.

This is not to say that there cannot -- or should not -- be a review of the entire organisation of social services in this country.  One great mistake in recent extensions of the social services is the failure to develop them according to an ordered and logical plan as is being done in Great Britain along the lines of the Beveridge Report.  Certainly considerable savings in the costs of administration of cash benefits would be possible if the administration of all social services were placed under a single authority (as a logical scheme would certainly suggest) instead of the haphazard multiple system of organisation with which the taxpayer is encumbered at the moment.  But these savings, while significant in themselves, would be little more than a drop in the bucket of £100 millions which the Australian people will be paying for their economic protection after the war.

From interest and sinking fund on the national debt there is no escape.  It would be possible in course of time to reduce the size of the capital part of the debt and consequently that of the interest payable, but the whole history of public finance in the democracies indicates that national debts, despite the best intentions, keep on growing irresistibly.


COSTS OF POST-WAR DEFENCE

Defence costs may possibly be above, rather than below, the figure of £60 millions just mentioned.  There can be no thought of stinting the post-war budget for defence.  Australia's position in the Pacific is far too critical and of far too much strategic importance for that.  Also the bitter experience of the inter-war years has shown that there is no prospect of permanent world peace unless the peace-loving nations possess among themselves the military might necessary to enforce it.  Defence is one thing in which Australian governments, whilst exercising proper financial control, cannot afford to economise.


FORECAST OF NECESSARY POST-WAR TAX REVENUE

The total of Commonwealth and State taxation raised in 1938/9 was about £125 millions.  On the most optimistic stand possible it will be necessary for governments to collect about £275 millions a year from taxation after the war -- more than twice the amount in the last pre-war year.

For the financial year just past, 1944/5, the revenue from taxation was over £350 millions.  Assuming the strictest economy in government use of public moneys, and that the social benefits and interest bill will not be increased above the figure indicated at present -- about £210 millions -- it may be possible to cut taxation by some £80 millions below the present high level in the post-war years.


REDUCTION IN TAXATION PROBABLE BEFORE NEXT ELECTIONS

It seems as certain as anything can be that some reduction in taxation will be made before the next twelve months have run their course.  Apart from economic or financial factors, it would be political suicide for any government to go to the polls in August next year without promising the public some relief of its present tax burdens.  In any case strict financial considerations should justify some lightening of the load.

While the war with Japan continues war expenditure will remain high, but not so high as it has been.  Already very large reductions in direct war costs are occurring.  For 1944/5 direct war costs at £370 millions are about £100 millions below the previous year and £150 millions below 1942/3.  With the probability of an early end to the war with Japan and the announced reduction of the Australian military establishment, a further large decline in war expenditure during the current financial year can be safely anticipated.  To some extent this decline will be offset by increasing charges on account of social services, interest payments, deferred pay and other costs incurred in partial demobilisation of the forces.  It also needs to be borne in mind that a large proportion of the gigantic sums expended on the war in 1942/3 and 1943/4 was financed through the expansion of central bank credit.  With the falling-off in the costs of the war, and to protect the nation against the possibility of disastrous inflation, central bank credit has rightly been the first source of revenue to be reduced.  In fact in 1944/5 no revenue was obtained from this source.  The scope for a reduction in taxation is, therefore, not so great as a cursory examination of the figures of reduced war expenditure might suggest.

Nevertheless, even with all these considerations taken into account, it should be possible to make some cuts in taxation during the current financial period.


STEP REDUCTIONS

It might well be a desirable policy for the Commonwealth to take as an aim a series of step reductions in taxation over, say, the next three years of the order of £25 to £30 millions a year.  A total reduction of this magnitude -- that is about £80 millions -- would seem to be within the ambit of practical policy.  At least if some such programme could be tentatively laid down, much of the uncertainty which is at present clouding the financial prospect and hampering post-war industrial preparations would be removed.  From facing as they are at the moment an unknown and apparently perilous future, industry and individuals would be able to plan ahead with some degree of confidence and knowledge as to their post-war prospects.


WORK -- THE ULTIMATE SOURCE OF ALL TAXATION

Now taxation of the order of £275 millions a year will impose a colossal burden on the economy of the country.

Without question every right-minded citizen wishes to see the Australian community adequately equipped with social services of all kinds.  Cash benefits to supplement the income of the individual in time of economic distress are, from every standpoint, desirable.  It is difficult to conceive of too much money being directed toward the education of the nation's youth, the health of its citizens, and its defence against possible aggressors.  But it must be thoroughly appreciated that all these things can be achieved only by a nation whose national income is rising, whose people are encouraged to work and to put forward their best efforts, and where vigour, enterprise and inventiveness are stimulated to the utmost.  Under any other conditions it may well be found impossible even to maintain, let alone increase, the scale of social services brought about and planned for during the war.  The ultimate source of all taxation and of all state sponsored services is personal endeavour.  High taxation must inevitably tend to weaken this endeavour and therefore to destroy the source of its own creation.  It is impossible for a nation to tax itself into prosperity.  It is entirely possible for a nation to tax itself out of prosperity.  To the wealthy, vigorous, producing country, all things concerned with the material, and indeed spiritual, welfare of its people are possible.  To a poor country, struggling under a load of tax exaction too heavy for it to bear, social welfare must remain at a standstill.

Many may argue that post-war taxation of the proportions indicated in this article will be destructive of enterprise and endeavour, undermine incentives to hard work and destroy the healthy spirit of adventure and risk-taking necessary to any progressive forward-moving economy.  There is undoubtedly some justification for these contentions.  Countless examples could be quoted -- and many have already been quoted in articles in the press -- of the reluctance existing among people of all income grades to work their hardest, to undertake high responsibilities, to venture on risky enterprises, when so much of the extra income they may hope to earn will go not into their own pockets, but into the treasuries of governments.  In many businesses the prospects of expansion and modernisation after the war have been seriously affected by the taxes which their profits have been forced to bear over the last few years.  But whilst industrial recovery may have already been damaged the position is by no means beyond hope of repair.


UPPER LIMITS OF EXPENDITURE

If governments will now firmly realise that the upper limits of government expenditure on current services have for the present -- and for some time to come -- been reached, and that any further increases for these purposes will almost certainly react disastrously on the total national production and therefore on the well-being of all the Australian people, much can be done to prepare the ground for healthy industrial recovery after the war.

Already it has been suggested that the uncertainty about the future of taxation which at present confuses the business prospect should be dispelled by a definite statement of government policy.  This would represent an important forward step.  Other measures will be discussed in succeeding articles.



ARTICLE III -- PRODUCTION AND TAXATION

The previous article pointed to the unavoidable conclusion that the post-war costs of governments to be met from taxation will be exceedingly high -- probably somewhat higher than the level consistent with the most efficient use of our productive resources and the most rapid increase of the national income and standards of life.  At the same time it was suggested that the taxation position is not so out of hand -- at least, not yet -- as to preclude all possibility of healthy economic recovery and development after the war.  It is important now that the right measures of economic and financial policy be taken to ensure that the huge bill of government costs, to which we are committed, is managed in such a way as to ease, to the greatest possible extent, the burden of whatever load is inescapable.


GREATER PRODUCTION

Although the patient may have been inflicted with a chronic ailment, this does not mean that nothing can be done to maintain him in a condition of reasonable health and vigour.  In fact, it is even possible that out of a dark necessity can come glowing virtue.  For the most effective way of lightening the burden on the individual of heavy post-war taxation is to increase as rapidly as possible, by every means at our disposal -- including hard work -- the size of the community's total production.  A higher total national output means a higher average individual income.  An annual tax of £30 is much easier to bear from a yearly income of £400 than from one of £300.  A national tax bill of £275 millions or £300 millions is a far lighter burden on a national income of £1,500 millions than on one of £1,000 millions.  The burden of taxation is to be measured not by its absolute scale but by the proportion it bears to the income which is forced to carry it.

If this fact can be impressed upon the Australian public then the individual taxpayer may find that not many after the war the taxes he will be called upon to pay, however fearsome they may appear at the moment, can be borne without excessive strain.  The sum which would go into his own pocket week by week for his personal needs and comforts should be sufficient to make him feel that his labour is not after all largely devoted to satisfying the demands of governments.  This, of course, assumes that governments will recognise the dangers inherent in the new high level of taxes and will put a curb on their tax-raising proclivities.  If an increase in the national income is absorbed in higher taxation then the individual is no better off so far as his own pocket is concerned.  A higher national income lightens the load on the taxpayer only insofar as it results in a lower rate of tax per £ of income than before the increase was achieved.  This lower rate of tax is compatible with the maintenance of government revenue since the taxes are now spread over the larger national income made possible by improved productivity.


CAMPAIGN OF ENLIGHTENMENT

There is a desperate need in Australia for a campaign of enlightenment to bring home to the people the supreme importance of efficient work and increased production.  It is a message which cannot be emphasised too strongly or repeated too often.  "Increased Production" should be made a national slogan to be rung around the country again and again.  In an expanding robust economy the size of post-war taxation, large as it will be, can in a relatively short space of time after the war be reduced to bearable proportions.


AUSTRALIAN STANDARD OF LIFE

Studies from widely different sources indicate that the Australian standard of living is, in comparison with that of other nations, by no means so high as is commonly supposed in this country.  Colin Clark in his book, "The Conditions of Economic Progress," published in 1938, places the Australian standard of life below that of five other countries.  An estimate used by the Army Educational Service reveals that the real income per head of the working population in Australia in 1935 to be just under £4 Australian a week, whereas in the United States the real income per head was over £5/10/- Australian a week.  According to this computation Australia was surpassed by six countries including Argentina and Switzerland.  A Canadian, Lewis C. Ord, with experience of industrial production in many countries, in an important book published in 1944 -- entitled "Secrets of Industry" -- places the Australian standard of living last among the English-speaking countries -- below Canada, New Zealand, the United States and Great Britain.

The results disclosed by these different studies are strikingly similar.  They suggest that there is ample scope for speedily increasing the productivity of the Australian economy and thus for raising our standard of life.


INDUSTRIAL EFFICIENCY

Australia is well-placed by comparison with many other countries in respect of conditions making for a high level of industrial efficiency.  In proportion to our population we have a solid foundation of physical resources -- despite some important exceptions the country is fortunate in the possession of considerable supplies of essential industrial raw materials.  With the advantage of a healthy, stimulating climate, the physique, virility and native intelligence of the Australian worker -- descended from good British stock -- are surpassed in few, if any, countries in the world.

In experienced industrial leadership we are at a disadvantage because of our national youthfulness.  The importance of efforts now being made to overcome our deficiencies in this regard cannot be overrated.  But they are capable of great extension.  Production and industrial organisation need to be taught more and more in appropriate institutions from the standpoint of an exact applied science.  Much more attention needs to be devoted to means by which our industrial capital equipment can be more rapidly replaced and kept abreast of the most modern standards.  Scientific and technical research needs to be more widely applied.  Managerial technique in the most effective and scientific use of labour can be greatly improved.  Without a greater unity of aim and mind between the participants in industry than exists at the moment we cannot hope to achieve the standards of industrial performance of which we are capable.  Too much lip-service and too little practical attention is given to the significance of vigorous competition as an efficiency factor in industry.  Methods of distribution need to be tied more closely to the requirements of efficient manufacture;  for instance, standardisation of product, type and design can be taken a long way further without seriously affecting the variety and attractiveness of the goods available to the consumer.


OPPORTUNITIES FOR EXPORT

The small Australian home market is admittedly a serious drawback to the achievement of the highest standards of industrial productivity.  But it is by no means so serious as many people suppose.  In any case great opportunities exist for building up an export trade in manufactured products to supplement the home market, and this would assist in the achievement of a cheaper unit cost of production, and benefit the community by making possible a greater volume and variety of imports.  There are altogether insufficient signs of determined and properly organised preparations by governments and private enterprise to grasp these opportunities.


"WHITE PAPER" ON FULL PRODUCTION

Industry could do no better service to the country than to supplement the Commonwealth Government's White Paper on "Full Employment" with a "White Paper" of its own on "Full Production".  Certainly it is a job which needs to be done.  A great load of taxation must be carried after the war.  But it is a load which we should find well within our capacity comfortably to bear provided we are united and determined on the goal of efficient production, and provided governments allow the income earner to benefit directly from this efficiency.



ARTICLE IV -- TAXATION AND PRODUCTION

The previous articles pointed to two main conclusions on the post-war taxation problem.  First, that the absolute scale of taxation after the war would, of necessity, be at least double -- and probably considerably more than double -- the pre-war level.  Second, that taxation of these proportions would seriously influence both preparations for post-war expansion and the level of economic activity and national production in the years following the war, unless certain action was taken.  Two steps were suggested.  First, that the Commonwealth Government should state, in reasonably definite and concrete terms, the taxation policy it proposes to pursue until the end of the Japanese war and over the succeeding two or three years until the economy has been restored to some kind of peacetime equilibrium.  Second, that given the inevitability of high taxation after the war, the most efficacious means of reducing its burden on the taxpayer was for governments and the community to take as a major post-war aim the achievement of maximum production and highest efficiency throughout industry.  As a contribution to this end it was suggested that a campaign of economic education should be launched to impress upon the public the supreme importance of industrial efficiency in the whole context of post-war planning.

But taxation is itself one of those factors which affect the level of production and the degree of efficiency attained in the use of resources.  Even though government commitments may make unavoidable the raising of a definite sum of money by taxation, it is still important to ask how the necessary taxes can best be distributed and levied in the light of the goal of high production.


WHITE PAPER ON "FULL EMPLOYMENT"

The Commonwealth Government's White Paper on "Full Employment" took sound ground in adopting the principle that "taxes will be designed to have the least possible restrictive effect both on the readiness to undertake private capital expenditure and on the efficiency with which production is undertaken".  This statement, while implying that taxation of the proportions to which we are committed in the post-war years must have some oppressive effect on industrial activity, rightly suggests that that effect can be minimised by a wise discrimination among the different types of tax.  This problem, however, opens up a vast and complex field of which very little is yet known.  All that can be attempted in these articles is to discuss some of the broad lines along which a wise policy might proceed.


STUDIES OF POST-WAR TAXATION IN THE U.S.A. AND GREAT BRITAIN

During 1943 and 1944 in the United States and Great Britain a number of important studies were made of post-war taxation from the standpoint of production and employment.  These investigations are concerned chiefly with the merits and demerits of the three main types of tax customarily used by governments in the democratic nations -- the personal income tax, taxes on company profits, and indirect taxes such as sales tax.  The conclusions indicate the weight of opinion to lean in favour of relatively heavy taxes on personal incomes, and correspondingly light taxes on company profits, and on sales of materials and commodities.  In other words, the studies in general adopt the view that the first-mentioned tax has less of a repressive influence on production and industrial expansion than the other two types of tax.


TAXES ON COMPANY PROFITS

It is argued in those reports that taxes on company profits take money away from where it is needed most and where it can be put to greatest advantage -- that is away from private enterprise on whose efficiency, and decisions regarding the improvement and expansion of capital equipment, the welfare arid standard of living of the community largely depend.  Taxes on company income, by reducing the incentive, and more especially the financial capacity of businesses to undertake new investment, put a brake on economic progress and react adversely on the living standards of the people.  High taxes on industry -- one of the reports suggests -- have four main disadvantages.  They reduce business reserves and thus the rate of capital development, detract from business incentive and the willingness to undertake risky forms of investment, and tend to hold up prices and to depress wages.


SALES TAXES

On the other hand the studies point out that sales taxes, by raising the prices of the commodities and services on which the community sends its income, affect adversely the other major factor in economic prosperity -- that is the demand for the products of industry.  This results from the fact that high prices reduce the purchasing power of the people's incomes.  It is conceded, of course, that personal income taxes also tend to reduce consumption and purchasing power.  But against this the reports, in general, argue that income taxes possess several significant advantages over sales taxes.  First, the incidence of personal income taxes can be directly assessed and, therefore, their economic effects more readily traced.  Second, and following upon this, they can be levied with a greater approach to equity than sales taxes, the burden of which falls relatively heavily on those sections of the community who spend the largest proportion of their incomes -- that is the lower income groups.  Third, and probably moat important, personal income tax brings home to the taxpayer, more directly and forcibly than the other kinds of tax, the real burden imposed on him by government expenditures, and consequently the importance of economy and efficiency in government administration.

From this analysis these overseas studies conclude that business profits should receive the major benefit when the falling-off in war expenditure makes possible some reduction in taxation, and that taxes on profits should eventually be reduced in a greater proportion than taxes on the incomes of individuals.  Personal income tax should also remain high relative to sales taxes, because of the unfair incidence of the latter on the lower incomes and their greater tendency to reduce consumer demand and thus the level of business activity.

The conclusion of these studies in the United States 'would, therefore, lead to a system of taxation imposing heavy taxes on private incomes, with relatively light sales taxes and taxes on business profits.


AUSTRALIAN PROBLEM

In view of the influential body of overseas opinion in favour of a post-war taxation policy broadly along these lines, it might profitably be asked how far the proposals made are applicable to the Australian position.  On the surface it would appear that our own problem calls for a different prescription.


REDUCTION IN PERSONAL INCOME TAX

While international comparisons of the burden of taxation in different countries are of dubious reliability, all comparisons which have been attempted would suggest that personal income taxes in Australia are at present the heaviest of all the democratic nations -- certainly much heavier than in the United States.  It is difficult to resist the conclusion that, for Australia, the requirements of efficient production demand material reductions in the present scale of personal income tax, and that work, enterprise and risk-taking throughout the whole range of incomes will be dangerously, perhaps fatally, affected unless the individual can be assured of a much higher direct net reward for his efforts than is possible at the moment.  In addition, it is too little appreciated that the efficiency of companies largely depends on the efforts of the individuals of which they are constituted.  These efforts in turn are determined in great measure by the inducements offering, the main one of which is direct monetary reward.  On the face of it, it would appear more dangerous to keep personal income taxes somewhere near their present level and to permit any relief in taxation to accrue mainly to the benefit of the incomes of businesses and to indirect taxation than to follow the reverse policy.  In the light of the Australian scene it would seem wise to discriminate in favour of private income as against company income,

This does not mean that no reductions in taxation on public and private companies would be possible, or that there is no need of a more lenient and intelligent treatment of company profits.


INDIRECT TAXATION

Nor does it mean that the present rates and incidence of sales tax would have to be continued without modification or removal of outstanding anomalies and defects.  The yearly revenue from excise on such commodities as beer, tobacco, cigarettes is at present some £30 millions higher than before the war.  There is a strong case for continuing high wartime rates of excise into peace.  If this were done, it would be possible to lower rates of sales tax in certain directions and, at the same time, maintain at its present level total revenue from indirect taxes.  With the expansion of imports almost certain to occur in the post-war period, proceeds from customs duties should increase.  Also, as government spending falls off and consumer goods become available in ample quantities, the total value of sales on which sales taxes are levied should grow.  Both these factors should also make feasible a reduction in rates of sales tax without affecting the total proceeds from indirect taxation.

The manner in which sales taxes can best be levied in the interests of cheap and efficient production is a subject for specialised examination and one beyond the scope of this booklet.  One aspect however calls for immediate attention and overhaul.  This concerns sales taxes on capital equipment and aids to manufacture -- machinery, machine tools, engineering supplies, design and planning materials.  These taxes seriously inflate the capital charges and therefore the cost of production of industry.  They must also tend to slow up the rate of development of the nation's productive equipment -- the rapid improvement of which it should be a first object of post-war policy to promote.  So far as possible sales tax directly affecting costs of capital plant and equipment should be abolished.


SHOULD INDIRECT TAXES REMAIN HIGH?

There are strong grounds for the view, however, that in Australia governments should continue to draw a good part of their revenue from indirect taxes after the war, and that this course would have a less damaging effect on production and employment than a large reduction of revenue from indirect taxes accompanied by relatively high direct taxes on income.  Indirect taxes have the qualities of their defects.  The very fact that their incidence is uncertain and hard to assess, and that their effects on the size of the individual's real income are not so readily apparent as in the case of personal income tax, means that they do not affect incentives to produce nearly so markedly.

There is a further argument in favour of maintaining a relatively heavy burden of indirect taxation as against income tax in the post-war years.  Statistical investigation reveals the significant fact that whereas in 1938/9 indirect taxation comprised 60%, and direct taxation only 40%, of total government revenue from this source, by 1943/4, these proportions had been just about reversed -- indirect taxation now contributing about 40% and direct taxation 60% of total tax revenue.  It is perhaps not necessary that we should attempt to restore the pre-war balance between direct and indirect taxation, but the figures suggest that any concessions might well be adjusted to the advantage of direct taxation.

Why should not governments continue to draw the present revenue of about £130 millions from indirect taxation, and allow any reductions possible -- we have suggested something of the order of £80 millions -- to go to the advantage of direct taxation, particularly to personal income taxes, and to a less extent to taxation on company profits?

Such a policy would have obvious disadvantages -- one being that it might possibly be out of harmony with the basic taxation tenet of ability to pay.  But it is highly probable that the defects attaching to it would be less damaging to enterprise and production, and thus to post-war standards of life, than a policy which did not allow of very substantial reductions in income tax, both personal and company.



ARTICLE V -- PERSONAL INCOME TAX

In recent decades the growth of indirect taxation has reduced the relative -- but not the absolute -- significance of income tax in the whole complex of public finance.  Nevertheless the latter still remains the classic of all the taxes, and the one around which social and economic controversy will continue to rage most strongly.

Income tax really comprises two taxes -- taxation on private income and taxation on company income.  Each requires to be treated as a separate and distinct problem.

In the last year before the war Australian governments, through direct taxation, extracted about £26 millions from the incomes of private individuals.  In 1943/4 individual income earners were being relieved of some £140 millions of their earnings.  No figures are yet available for 1944/5 but on present indications around £160 millions would probably prove an accurate estimate -- about six times the pre-war sum.  This amounts to over £20 per head of the population or, what is more striking, £70 per head of the working population.


PERSONAL INCOME TAX REVENUE POST-WAR

What will be the position after the war?  Clearly there is no hope of returning to the happy pre-war situation.  Equally clearly, and by universal consent, some relief from the crushing wartime burden must be effected.  We have suggested -- in the second article -- that on the assumption of the strictest economy in the use of public moneys, and provided no further large-scale commitments are incurred on behalf of the public purse, it should be possible for yearly government revenue from taxation to be reduced by some £80 millions below the 1944/5 receipts of approximately £355 millions.  A later article proposed that the major reductions in taxation might profitably be made in personal income tax and company tax, especially the former.  On this line of reasoning it might just be possible to reduce the total government yield from personal income tax by some £60 millions, leaving £20 millions to accrue to the benefit oi industrial enterprises.  This would give a post-war government revenue from private income tax of something of the order of £100 millions -- a figure about halfway between the wartime and pre-war yield.  This might well be a desirable target -- although admittedly a rough and ready one -- at which to aim.  It would admit of very substantial reductions in rates of tax and allow the hard-pressed worker to handle again sufficient of his own earnings to make him feel that, although life was still real and earnest, it was not altogether an empty dream.

The figure of £100 million of course requires to be expertly examined and checked.  It has been mentioned, mainly to arouse discussion and interest and to establish a principle -- one already affirmed -- that some kind of target should be set up for post-war taxation to relieve the income earner's mind, and to provide something at which governments can shoot.  The fact that they will never hit the bull's eye, or possibly even the target itself, is immaterial beside the fact that the presence of the target would help to restore to public finances a direction and certainty which they at present lack.


BURDEN OF POST-WAR INCOME TAX

The burden of the tax relative to the pre-war or wartime burden would, in all probability, not be so great as the actual figures suggest.  This, for at least two reasons.  First, the natural growth of the population, the return of service men and women to civil life, and the tendency for an increasing number of women to take their place beside men in industry, mean that the number of income earners on which taxes can be levied will be greater than before the war.  Second, whatever misgivings may be held about the post-war efficiency of Australian industry -- and present indications hardly justify optimism -- it is difficult to believe that the productivity per head of the population will not be somewhat higher than before the war.  Certainly the economic prospect is black indeed if this cannot be assumed.  This factor would also tend to reduce the burden on the individual taxpayer.  Indeed, as we already have argued, there is no more effective way open to the Australian community of lightening the load of its post-war taxation, than by concentration on the means by which the greatest possible industrial output can be secured with the least possible expenditure of effort.


OVERSEAS TAX SATES

At the present time there seems little doubt that rates of personal income tax in Australia are higher and more steeply progressive than those of any other of the English-speaking countries.  If industrial progress in this country is to keep abreast of the best overseas performance, and our industry made more competitive after the war, then it is certain that our personal income tax will need to be roughly in line with that of other nations.  The reduction of this tax to levels comparable with overseas standards should be made a general aim of post-war financial policy.  If this is not done, it is more than probable that we will suffer from a gradual, but steady, exodus from the country of some of our more brilliant, enterprising younger men attracted by the broader horizons and greater scope offering abroad for satisfying healthy personal ambition.


AN EXAMPLE

A specific example can be mentioned.  A few years ago a leading industrial company in Australia sent one of its most promising executives to the United States for special experience and training.  Recently he expressed a desire to remain in the United States, in view of the excellent opportunities open to young men for rapid advancement and for obtaining high salaries, and of the comparatively limited opportunities likely to exist in Australia because of the taxation prospect.  The same company has had in mind for some time the institution of a scheme for sending abroad every year a number of its young men to gain knowledge of overseas practices.  In the light of the above experience, it feels that little advantage would accrue to the company, and a positive disadvantage to the country might well result, from proceeding with the scheme.

On the reverse side of the picture there is no prospect of attracting high-class men to Australia if the level of our income tax is to be substantially above that of other countries.  Already difficulties in planning post-war developments are being experienced by leading Australian industries desiring to obtain the assistance of overseas experts and technicians during the growing pains of their new ventures.  A similar problem arises in the case of important companies in the United States or Britain wishing to establish subsidiaries in this country.  Naturally enough such companies usually desire to place in control of their new ventures top-ranking men from within their own organisations.  It is clearly not possible to persuade men of this type to come to Australia for any length of time if they stand to lose by so doing.  Exceptionally high rates of income tax would therefore act as a serious obstacle to the investment of overseas capital in this country.


ABILITY TO PAY

In determining rates of income tax the well-known tenet of "ability to pay" must continue to be an important general criterion.  But it is at best a vague indefinite concept capable only of the broadest and most general application.  It implies different things to different people.  All that it can be taken to mean is that the broadest backs should carry the heaviest loads.  In practice it leads to some degree of progressive taxation -- which is now accepted by intelligent opinion -- and to differential treatment according, for example, to whether the income earner is married or unmarried, with children or without.  But the principle of "ability to pay" gives little help, if any, in determining the precise nature of the progression.  One or two things can, however, be said.


TAXES ON THE LOWEST AND HIGHEST INCOMES

Income tax on the lower bracket of incomes should not be so high as to reduce the income of the taxpayer below the minimum standards of subsistence and life regarded as necessary by modern opinion.  On the higher incomes it should not be so heavy as to discourage the adventurous, striving, ambitious individual from attempting great deeds.  This type of rare person has been the inspiration of economic progress in the past, and it is certain that no society -- in the foreseeable future -- will be progressive unless he is retained.  The man prepared to risk the long, hard, hazardous ascent to the heights must not be deterred from so doing by failure to place glittering prizes at the summit.  The state must continue to reward its great men greatly if it is not to deny itself the fruits of exceptional skill and enterprise.  The Editors of the American journal, "Fortune" have coined an excellent sentence which should be firmly implanted in the minds of all those striving for social improvement -- "this will be a happier century for the common man if it is also the century of the uncommon individual".  An equalitarian society, that is one in which men are rewarded primarily according to their needs, and not according to their skill and efforts and achievements, will be a stagnant, dormant society with death at the heart.  The tremendous industrial and scientific gains of the past century will be dwarfed by those of the next so long as we keep the pathways to the satisfaction of high ambition clear and broad.

Here we have two general principles for determining the nature and magnitude of personal tax at the extremes of the income scale.  But what of the rate of progression between these extremes?


EXTRA REWARDS FOR EXTRA WORK

At least, we have learned, or should have learned, from our experience during the war that taxation should not rise so steeply as to make the extra rewards obtainable from harder work and the carrying of extra responsibilities seem not worth the candle.  The classic example is, of course, the protest of the workers and the trade union movement against existing taxation of overtime earnings.  The plain fact is that men are so constituted in the twentieth century that they are reluctant to undertake extra work without the prospect of satisfactory reward.


EXTRA REWARDS FOR SPECIAL SKILL

Income tax rates should also not discriminate harshly against the possessor of acquired qualifications and aptitudes.  There should be a fair margin of gain between the net rewards -- after payment of taxes -- of the unskilled and the skilled man.  The principle of special margins for skill is an accepted part of the Australian system of wage payments, and these differential rewards should not be largely eliminated by a line of progressive taxation rising too steeply.  The same argument applies in the case of those men who acquire specialised professional or technical knowledge in spheres requiring many years of expensive and arduous academic training.  Years in which no income is earned, and the prospects of marriage postponed, should be adequately balanced by years of especially high rewards for special work well done.


EQUALITY OF OPPORTUNITY

The equalising of incomes, however much it may appeal to the doctrinaire reformer or moralist, is seen in practice to lead to all sorts of ethical injustices and economic evils.  Equality of opportunity, however, is an entirely desirable and legitimate social objective and one which should be in the forefront of future policy.  The principle was crystallised by Mr. Churchill in his broadcast on post-war policy in March, 1943 -- "All cannot reach the same level, but all must have their chance. ..."



ARTICLE VI -- COMPANY INCOME TAX

Taxation of company income, while usually combined in government statistical returns with personal income tax under the single title "'income tax" is really of an entirely distinct genus and poses a distinct set of problems.


BETTER LIVING STANDARDS WILL DEPEND ON PRIVATE ENTERPRISE

The pronounced movement to the left of the Australian economy during the war alters in no way the inescapable fact that, in the post-war years, the provision of employment and better living standards will depend fundamentally on the activities of private enterprise.  Whether the business man will decide on a high, or a low, level of activity in his particular enterprise will be determined by a complex of factors, of which the magnitude and kind of the taxes the business will be called upon to bear are by no means the least important.  Here Australian governments have a clear responsibility.  In their capacity as guardians of the public interest, they must endeavour to create conditions which will stimulate the business man to the utmost enterprise and efficiency.  In the past governments have paid comparatively little attention to the effects of company taxation on business enterprise.  They have looked at it more as a convenient means of amassing revenue to meet their own expenditure.  This approach will not be good enough for the future -- more especially in view of the higher peacetime taxes to which company income will almost certainly be subjected.

There is no question that heavy taxation of company income must exercise some restraining influence on business and tend to slow up the rate of economic expansion.  This is due less to the loss of incentive because of the smaller prospective profit -- although in the case of the riskier forms of investment this is a material factor -- than to the inroads made on the financial resources of the business, and thus on its capacity to expand and to keep its plant and equipment up to date.


FINANCING OF CAPITAL DEVELOPMENT

Contrary to popular belief, probably the greater part of business development is financed from savings put by from year to year out of profits rather than from new capital raised by the issue of shares or debentures.  In many cases the best and simplest method of financing new buildings, plant and equipment is through profits "ploughed back" into the business.  The raising of capital externally necessitates, frequently, delay in waiting for a favourable moment in the capital market, or, alternatively, obtaining money by means of bank overdraft.  For the financing of fixed assets the latter course has certain drawbacks.

The disadvantages of acquiring capital from sources outside the business are more marked in the case of the private company than in that of the public company, owing to the difficulties associated with control and the lack of liquidity of the investment.

All this adds up to a strong case for the lightest practicable taxation of company income and company reserves "ploughed back" and reinvested in industry.  It should be clearly understood, however, that a plea for low taxation of company profits is in no way a plea for leniency towards the rich.  On all income which the individual eventually receives, he should pay his proper and fair proportion of tax.  But to encourage business to improve and develop rapidly its capital equipment by leaving adequate financial resources in its hands is to pursue the commonsense path of public interest, rather than that of narrow private gain.


POST-WAR REVENUE FROM COMPANY TAX

During the war taxation of companies has been exceedingly heavy.  In 1943/4 these taxes produced £52 millions of revenue for governments, compared with £16 millions in the last year before the war -- an increase of £36 millions, or over 220%.  Out of every £ of company income about an average of 12/- is now taken by the state as against approximately 4/6 in 1938/9.  We have suggested that it might be possible to reduce annual revenue from this source after the war by about £20 millions -- this would mean that governments would collect some £32 millions from company taxes, or about twice as much as before the war.


EFFECT OF WAR ON FINANCES OF INDUSTRY

The effect of wartime taxation on the financial position of industry is interesting.  Whilst undoubtedly burdensome, inequitable and capricious in its incidence, it may not be so severe as is sometimes supposed.  This statement of course refers to the whole field of industry.  Cases abound of individual companies which have suffered seriously, even ruinously, from the load they have been forced to carry during the war.  Nevertheless, possibly the big majority of businesses, despite taxation, have been able to maintain a reasonably strong financial position.  This, of course, is due to a number of influences peculiar to a war economy, and particularly to the basic fact that the state has become a purchaser, on a huge scale, for the products of industry -- and where the state does not itself purchase, it dictates the kind and quantity of goods which will be available for the private consumer to purchase.  The satisfactory financial position maintained by many businesses during the war therefore provides no argument for the continuation of a high level of company taxation into the peace, when the multifarious wants and desires of millions of private individuals will, necessarily and rightly, again become the first concern of industry.

But the fact that the finances of industry may be little less satisfactory than before the war does not answer the question whether they are adequate to enable it to surmount the complex tasks of post-war reconstruction.  It should be clearly understood that the post-war needs of business -- either in the short or the long run -- bear very little similarity to its pre-war position.


SHORT-RUN FINANCIAL NEEDS OF INDUSTRY

In the short period of transition private enterprise will need to make special outlays to cope with problems quite out of the normal run.  First it will need to convert its plant, used to a large extent over the last five years for making war equipment and supplies, to peacetime purposes.  In many cases this may be a costly proceeding.  Second, it must repair, modernise and replace a great deal of equipment, which has been run down during the war because of excessive use and inadequate maintenance, or which has been rendered obsolete by the technical developments occurring over the war period.  Third, there is the great backlog of postponed business expansion enforced or industry by the war.  This will involve a demand for immense capital resources concentrated in a very short space of time.  Fourth, there will be the special costs of recapturing and rebuilding peacetime markets involving expensive marketing, research and sales promotion and requiring large sums of working capital.  Finally, all these necessary outlays will be magnified by the fact that the post-war price level will probably be something over 30% higher than pre-war prices.


LONG-RUN PICTURE

This, it should be emphasised again, is the short-run picture.  But what of the longer perspective?  On this one thing can be said with certainty.  Pre-war standards of industrial progress will be a treacherous guide for policy in the post-war world.  If Australia is to retain its place among the advanced industrial nations, then the improvement of the capital equipment of industry, the achievement of more efficient methods of production, the discovery of new, more effective products must proceed at much faster rate than before the war.  This is the significant conclusion to be drawn from recent industrial thought and practice overseas, particularly in the United States of America.  But, if such a policy is to be translated into a programme of practical action, then industry will require every £ of capital and the largest possible reserves of finance which the economy can afford.  On this line of argument, it cannot be concluded that private enterprise is other than poorly equipped for its immense national responsibilities of the future.


AUSTRALIA'S INDUSTRIAL EQUIPMENT

Much of Australia's industrial equipment is out of date, and some of it archaic, judged by the best modern standards.  To vie with industry abroad Australia will have to indulge in some large-scale scrapping and replacement of plant in the years following the war.  This will require exceptionally large financial resources.  Now the degree of obsolescence of industrial plant is something which figures do not reveal.  In fact, a sound financial position as disclosed in a balance sheet may well tend to conceal a dangerous state of technical and scientific backwardness.  The whole question of taxation of companies needs to be freshly examined in the light of the industrial and economic policies necessary to cope with the new conditions of the post-war world.  Sound intelligent principles need to be firmly established having in view the paramount public need of maximum efficiency and enterprise throughout industry.


DEPRECIATION ALLOWANCES

As an instance the trend of industrial opinion abroad strongly favours more liberal allowances for depreciation of plant and equipment as one means of speeding up the rate of technical progress.  In the United States the taxation report of the Committee for Economic Development -- which is advised by economists of national repute -- proposes that, within certain broad limits, businesses should be permitted to use their own judgment in establishing the rates of depreciation of their assets.  In Britain "The Economist" has long advocated that existing tax legislation be amended by the raising of depreciation allowances and by the widening of the definition of obsolescence.  This general view has been followed by the British Government in its Income Tax Bill introduced in the House of Commons in February of this year.  Under the bill industrial buildings, plant and machinery will be written off out of depreciation allowances in shorter time than hitherto allowed -- there are to be initial allowances of 20% on plant and machinery and 10% on the cost of new buildings.  Even these provisions have been criticised in informed quarters as insufficiently imaginative to meet the real demands of industry after the war.  Of these eminent opinions and of the action taken by the British Government, Australia must take notice.  To mention one point, Australia is unique in its failure to permit depreciation on buildings -- apart from exceptional cases -- as a legitimate industrial cost against the profits on which taxation is assessed.

From the standpoint of strict accounting principle, it can be argued, with some force, that the rates of depreciation on industrial machinery permitted under existing taxation laws in Australia, are on the whole fair and reasonable in the light of past experience.  But is this the real issue?  If future technical advance can be accelerated through the more rapid replacement and modernization of capital plant and equipment brought about by a more liberal depreciation policy, then, regardless of other considerations, is there not the strongest reason why this policy should be followed?  The state itself would not lose, in the long run, either in tax revenue or in other ways if this course were pursued.  On the contrary it would stand to gain.  It would have soundly based, technically efficient, and financially strong industries, and consequently, in the end a greater taxable income on which to levy its taxes.


VALUATION OF STOCKS

Another problem requiring express attention concerns the basis of valuation of stocks before the determination of company income.  This affects especially retail and wholesale traders, who have a big proportion of their capital invested in stock, but it is by no means an immaterial factor in the case of the manufacturer and primary producer.

Since the outbreak of war, peacetime stocks have been replaced with stocks purchased at temporarily inflated costs owing to war-risk insurance, higher freight rates, increased production costs and so on.  Added to all these, and possibly more important, is the change-over of normal merchandise to wartime substitute merchandise.  In these circumstances the basis of valuation is a matter of great importance when the values of stocks held by many businesses may fall precipitously after the war.

It is a recognised and essential practice, from which there should be no departure, that provision be made for losses resulting from falls in value in the year to which they relate.  Failure to make provision would result in the levying of taxation on profits represented by unsold stocks which are not "realised profits" and which, in fact, may never be realised.  Businesses would have not internal reserves on which to lean any many might be forced into bankruptcy or, at best, their financial stability seriously impaired.  In the final outcome taxation is paid on all income actually earned and consequently the revenue does not suffer.


RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT

Scientific and technical research and development in Australia should be encouraged to the utmost in the interests of industrial efficiency and rapid progress.  Taxation is one means, and an important one, of assisting this desirable objective.  The recent Income Tax Bill of the British Government again sets an example which might be followed with advantage.  The Bill relieves from taxation all expenditure on research from fundamental work up to the stage of full-scale commercial development of the product.  The leadership of the future rests with the scientific nations, and no policy will be misdirected which aims at enlarging the resources devoted to the whole field of industrial invention.


TAXATION OF PROFITS

Provisions regarding allowances for depreciation and obsolescence, research and development and valuation of stocks, concern the determination of the amount of profit on which taxation is assessed.  There still remains the larger issue of the taxation of the profit itself.  After the payment of company tax the profit remaining falls into two categories -- first, that part paid away as dividends to shareholders, and second, that part set aside as a financial reserve and usually reinvested in the business in one form or another.


SHAREHOLDERS' DIVIDENDS

Shareholders' dividends form part of the problem of personal income tax, the basic principles of which were discussed in the previous article.  One or two particular observations might be added -- although they do not strictly fall within the subject matter under consideration.

Taxation law has long made a commendable distinction between income earned as wage or salary or commission by way of personal exertion, and income received as a return on invested capital -- the former being charged at a lower rate of tax than the latter.  Insofar as it is practicable, future policy might well aim at widening this gap to the benefit of personal exertion income.  It is plainly necessary, however, to allow investors a sufficient margin of return on their investments after payment of tax to attract the savings necessary to economic progress, and to encourage people to place money in the riskier forms of enterprise.  It should also be borne in mind that investment income often provides an indispensable source of livelihood for aged and sick people, who have worked hard and saved hard throughout their lives.  These worthy people should be protected against the hardship which might result from an over-severe tax policy.

The present method of taxing composite income -- that is, income derived from both personal exertion and investments -- gives rise to many inconsistencies, and in certain cases, to gross injustices.  It should be overhauled with the object of introducing a more satisfactory basis of treatment.

The double taxation of the return on capital which occurs under Australian wartime legislation, as a result of company and personal income tax, might be modified.  In other English-speaking countries the general rule is to grant a rebate of tax to the shareholder for taxation paid by the company.  This was the policy pursued in Australia before the war.  If restored after the war it would almost certainly tend to increase the rate of capital expansion and investment to the benefit of the community, as well as assisting those people depending almost wholly on income from savings for their livelihood.  Greater encouragement would be provided, too, for overseas investors to invest capital in this country.


RESERVES

We have already drawn attention to the singular importance of savings made out of profits and reinvested in industry.  Company tax policy should be so framed that these reserves, taken in conjunction with allowances charged against profit, are sufficient to enable the capital plant and equipment and methods of Australian industry to be kept abreast of advanced modern standards.  As a first move the present Super Tax and Wartime Company Tax should be abandoned as soon as possible -- these taxes produce a comparatively small proportion of the total revenue derived from company taxes -- and Undistributed Profits Tax on private companies reviewed with the object of making its incidence more certain of estimation, and more equitable as between individual companies.


ASSISTING NEW VENTURES

Adventure and risk-taking would be encouraged by a taxation policy giving special "compassionate" treatment to income earned by new business enterprises.  There is a strong case for assisting new industries to strengthen their financial position in the early years of their existence by the creation of adequate reserves.  This objective would be promoted if their undistributed profits were taxed at a special low rate of tax.  A new industry might be defined as one which has not been in commercial operation for more than seven years.  How far taxation concessions to new ventures would be practicable as a general policy would have to be determined by expert study, but at least it can be affirmed that, in principle, they have many advantages to offer.

The taxation of company income is a large subject on which it is customary for even the best-informed to hold different, and often diametrically opposed, views.  In one overriding objective, however, all shades of opinion can find common ground -- that is in the public need for the highest attainable industrial efficiency and for the utmost rapidity of technical advance.  It is in the light of this purpose that all detailed proposals for the future should be considered.



ARTICLE VII -- SUMMARY OF MAIN CONCLUSIONS

  1. The level of taxation after the war is certain to be far higher than ever before in our peacetime economic history.  Governments are committed to greatly increased expenditures on account of interest and sinking fund on the national debt, social benefits, education and health, defence and general administration.  The major part of these costs must be borne from revenue from taxation.

  2. At a considered assessment, governments will need to receive annually from current revenue, after full restoration of a peacetime economy, at least £325 millions to meet their post-war commitments and obligations.  This estimate of £325 millions is made up as follows --

    Social Benefits
    (Unemployment and sickness
    benefits, child endowment,
    military pensions, etc.)
    £100 millions
    Interest and Sinking Fund on the
    National Debt
    £110 millions
    Defence£30 millions
    Other
    (Administration, Government
    Departments, Health, Education, etc.)
    £85 millions
    Total£325 millions

    To keep down post-war expenditure from revenue to the level indicated in these figures would be possible only on the basis of the utmost efficiency and economy in the use of public moneys, and only provided no more large avoidable commitments are incurred on behalf of the public purse.  A reasonable post-war forecast of net income from business undertakings and of revenue from sources other than taxation would be of the order of £50 millions a year.  This would leave about £275 millions annually to be raised from taxation.

  3. In the past taxation policy has been regarded by governments primarily from the standpoint of the most convenient and equitable means of acquiring the necessary money to meet their current costs.  Little attention has been paid to the impact of taxation on the wider field of national economic policy.  In the future the new heavy burden of taxes will raise vital issues concerned with enterprise, production, employment and standards of living, and the entire problem of taxation therefore needs to be examined from a fresh perspective.

  4. This examination should be carried out by an expert committee appointed by the Commonwealth Government.  The committee should investigate the whole field of taxation policy in relation to the post-war economy.

  5. The present uncertainty surrounding the intentions of governments regarding the future of taxation -- particularly its magnitude -- is seriously impeding preparations for post-war reconversion and expansion.  This uncertainty should be dispelled immediately by a broad statement of government policy.

  6. A total reduction in taxation revenue of approximately £80 millions below the 1944/5 level of about £355 millions should be within the ambit of practical policy.  Assuming that about three years from now will elapse before the economy is restored to a normal peacetime equilibrium -- which seems a reasonable assumption -- governments might well take as their aim a series of step reductions in taxation over this period of the order of £25 to £30 millions a year.

  7. The burden of post-war taxation will be inescapably heavy, but it can be lightened provided intelligent measures of economic and financial policy are adopted.

  8. The most effective way of reducing the burden of taxation, both on the nation and the individual, is unquestionably by concentrating on enlarging, by every means at our disposal, the size of the community's total production.  This is a responsibility which falls squarely on the shoulders of employers, trade unions and governments.  It can be simplified, however, provided there is an effective basis of public support.  To this end a campaign of economic enlightenment should be launched to impress upon the people of Australia the central importance of efficiency in all phases of industry.  Employers, because of their key position, might well take a leading part in such a campaign by outlining a national plan and stating the national conditions for full production.

  9. The magnitude and kind of taxes are both factors vitally affecting productivity throughout industry.  Of the three main taxes contributing to government revenue -- personal income tax, company income tax and indirect taxes -- it is suggested that the major reductions in taxation might well be made in the personal income tax field.  Unless the individual can be assured of much greater extra rewards for his extra work and initiative than are possible under the present scale of income tax, then work, production and enterprise throughout all ranges of income will be dangerously affected.  Company taxes should also be reduced to the greatest extent practicable.

    The total amount of government revenue from indirect taxation could be maintained at the present level -- this would not rule out the possibility of considerable reductions in rates of sales taxes or of the removal of some of the main defects in the present system of levying sales tax.  With the return to peace revenue from customs duties and excise should increase -- provided present rates of excise are maintained -- whilst the total value of sales on which sales taxes are levied will probably expand.  In particular, sales tax on capital equipment and on aids to manufacture, because of its snowballing effects on costs of production should, so far as possible, be abolished.

  10. Of the £80 millions suggested as a practicable deduction from the present level of taxes, it is suggested that £60 millions less revenue might be raised from personal income tax and £20 millions less revenue from company income tax.  This would mean that governments would draw about £100 millions of revenue from personal income tax, compared with probably about £160 millions in 1944/5, and £26 millions in the last year before the war;  and about £32 millions of revenue from company income taxes, compared with an estimated £52 millions for 1944/5 and £16 millions in 1938/9.  From indirect taxation governments would continue to receive the present yearly revenue of about £130 millions.  The balance of £13 millions -- to make a total tax revenue of £275 millions -- would come from estate duty, probate, land tax, etc.

  11. While the above policy would still involve a very heavy absolute load of personal income tax, the burden relative to the pre-war or wartime burden would, in all probability, not be so great as the actual figures indicate.  First, the size of the working population, and therefore the number of taxpayers, after the war will be increased by the natural growth of the total population, the return of service men and women to industry, and the tendency for an increasing proportion of women to enter commercial and industrial life.  Second, it would be reasonable to assume that technical progress will result in an increased productivity per head of the working community and that this will reflect itself in higher real incomes.  This would mean that the average taxpayer will have a larger gross income with which to pay his taxes.

  12. Taxation policy should aim at reducing personal income tax to levels roughly comparable with those of other English-speaking countries.  Otherwise, three results will almost certainly follow --

    1. The nation will suffer from the loss of some of its most enterprising and ambitious men -- talent, which any, but particularly a small, country can ill afford to lose -- to countries overseas where wider opportunities offer.
    2. Australian businesses planning new developments will find it difficult to obtain the essential services of overseas experts and technicians.
    3. The investment of overseas capital in Australia will be restricted, in view of the fact that British or American companies desiring to establish subsidiaries in this country would naturally wish to place in control of such ventures top-ranking men from within their own organisations.
  13. Personal income tax on lower incomes should not be so high as to reduce the income of the taxpayer below that which will provide a decent standard of livelihood.  On the highest incomes it should not be so heavy as to discourage the more enterprising and ambitious individual from undertaking great commercial or industrial ventures.  It is this type of person on whom we have depended in the past, and must continue largely to depend in the future, for economic and social progress.

  14. Between these two extremes of income personal income tax should not rise so steeply as to make the extra rewards -- after payment of tax -- obtainable from harder work and the carrying of greater responsibilities seem not worth the effort.  The extra rewards of high professional qualification or specially acquired skill should not be largely eliminated by a line of progressive taxation rising too sharply.

  15. The simplest and most effective means of financing the improvement and expansion of the capital equipment of industry is through business reserves set aside out of profits.  The taxation of company income should be framed with this cardinal fact in mind.

  16. In the post-war period -- both for the short-run tasks of economic reconversion and the longer range necessity of speeding of the rate of growth of the nation's capital equipment -- industry will require greater financial resources than before the war.  The possibility that industry as a whole lias not suffered so severely from high wartime taxation, as is sometimes claimed, does not therefore provide any guide for post-war policy.  The conclusion is inescapable that industry is at present poorly equipped to meet its national responsibilities of the future.  The whole system of company taxation requires expert examination preparatory to its adjustment in the light of the consideration just expressed.

  17. As an instance, there is the strongest of cases, especially in view of American practice and of steps recently taken in Britain, for more liberal depreciation allowances than those permitted under existing legislation in Australia.

    In view of the probability of a precipitous decline in some stock values after the war, caused particularly by the changeover from wartime substitute to normal merchandise, there must be no departure from recognised practice of making provision for losses resulting from falls in value in the year to which the losses relate.  Failure to make such provision could result in the levying of taxation on profits represented by unsold stocks, which are not "realised" profits, and which in fact may never be realised.

    Industrial research would be encouraged if all expenditure on research were allowed as a charge against profits before the assessment of tax.

  18. Super Tax and Wartime Company Tax should be abandoned as soon as possible -- almost certainly before the date of termination provided for in the Act -- and Undistributed Profits Tax on private companies reviewed with the object of making its incidence more certain of estimation and more equitable as between individual businesses.  Double taxation of company income should be modified by a return to the pre-war principle whereby a rebate of tax was granted to the shareholder on account of taxation already paid by the company.

  19. Business adventure and risk-taking would be encouraged if income earned on new capital investment or in new enterprises were taxed at a special low rate.  This may be found to be impracticable, but it should receive the closest examination.



STATISTICAL APPENDIX

The following tables comprise the main data from which the estimates of post-war government expenditure and revenue used in the text have been constructed.  Figures, other than post-war estimates, are based on those published by the Commonwealth Statistician.


TABLE I.

COMMONWEALTH AND STATE EXPENDITURE FROM REVENUE
(excludes expenditure from Public Loans and Credit Expansion)

1938/391943/44Post-War
Estimate
£m.£m.£m.
Social Payments31     77     100     
Interest on Public Debt52     77     110     
War (1939/45)8     141     30     
Other Expenditure64     73     85     
Total (excluding expenditure
in Business Undertakings)
£155 m.£368 m.£325 m.

HOW FINANCED

1938/391943/44Post-War
Estimate
£m.£m.£m.
Income Tax41     185     132     
Capital Taxes10     14     13     
Indirect Taxes    73         126         130     
124     325     275     
Net Income from Business
Undertakings and Other Revenue
    28         45         50     
Total Revenue£152 m.£370 m.£325 m.


TABLE II.

DETAILS OF COMMONWEALTH AND STATE EXPENDITURE FROM REVENUE SOCIAL PAYMENTS

1938/391943/44
£m.£m.
Commonwealth
  War Pensions (1914/18 war)
  War Pensions (1939/45 war)
  Invalid and Old Age Pensions
  Widows' Pensions
  National Welfare Fund
  Child Endowment
  Maternity Allowances
  Funeral Benefits
  Administrative

8.2     
-     
16.0     
-     
-     
-     
.4     
-     
.3     

9.3     
1.7     
21.7     
2.8     
25.5     
12.3     
2.3     
.1     
.4     
State
  Unemployment Relief

5.7     

.9     
£30.6 m.£77.0 m.

INTEREST ON PUBLIC DEBTS

Commonwealth
  Interest and Sinking Fund (1914/18 war)
  Interest and Sinking Fund (1939/45 war)
  Sinking Fund on State Debts

9.6       
-       
1.5       

9.2       
24.8       
1.5       
State
  Public Debt Charges

40.2       

42.1       
£51.3 m.*£77.6 m.*

* Approximate.


WAR, 1939/45

1938/391943/44
£m.£m.
Commonwealth (only)£8.0 m.£141.3 m

OTHER EXPENDITURE

1938/391943/44
£m.£m.
Commonwealth
  Departments
  Territories
  New Works
  Relief to Primary Producers
  Payments for States (n.e.i.)

8.6     
1.1     
6.6     
2.0     
4.6*    

10.8     
1.0     
4.7     
1.9     
1.6*    
State
  Education, Hospitals, etc.
  All other

22.2     
18.7     

25.2     
28.3     
£63.8 m.£73.5 m.

* Approximate.



TABLE III.

DETAILS OF COMMONWEALTH & STATE REVENUE

TAXATION

1938/391943/44
£m.£m.
Income Tax --
  Commonwealth
  States

11.9     
    29.8     
£41.7 m.

183.8     
    1.5     
£185.3 m.
Capital Taxes --
  Commonwealth Land Duty
  Commonwealth Estate Duty
  Commonwealth Gift Duty
  State Probate Duties
  State Land Tax

1.5     
1.9     
-     
5.0     
    1.5     
£9.9 m.

3.8     
2.8     
.2     
6.0     
    1.3     
£14.1 m.
Indirect Taxation --
  Commonwealth Customs
  Commonwealth Excise
  Commonwealth Sales
  Commonwealth Pay-Roll
  Commonwealth Flour
  Commonwealth Entertainments
  Commonwealth Gold
  State Motor
  State Stamp Duties
  State Entertainments
  State All Other

31.2     
16.5     
9.3     
-     
1.8     
-     
-     
7.0     
3.5     
1.9     
    1.9     
£73.1 m.

20.6     
46.7     
27.9     
10.9     
1.9     
4.7     
.3     
5.9     
3.0     
1.5     
    2.2     
£125.6 m.

OTHER REVENUE

1938/391943/44
£m.£m.
Commonwealth --
  Interest, etc
  Coinage and Note Issue
  All Other Items

1.1       
.8       
.9       

1.2       
4.6       
3.1       
States --
  Land Sales, etc
  All Other

4.1       
7.5       

5.0       
9.2       
£14.4 m.*£23.1 m.*

GROSS INCOME FROM BUSINESS UNDERTAKINGS

1938/391943/44
£m.£m.
Commonwealth17.9     30.3     
States55.7     91.9     
£73.6 m.£122.2 m.

* Approximate.



TABLE IV.

COMMONWEALTH AND STATE TAXATION -- POST-WAR AND PRE-WAR

1938/391943/44Post-War
Estimate
£m.£m.£m.
Taxation on Personal Income25     133*    100     
Taxation on Company Income16     52*    32     
Capital Taxes10     14     13     
Indirect Taxation73     126     130     
£124 m.£325 m.£275 m.

* Approximate.


For the year 1944/45 taxation from all sources will approximate £355 m. made up as follows:

Income Tax£210 m.*
Capital Taxes£14 m.*
Indirect£131 m.*
Total£355 m.*

* These figures are estimates only.



ENDNOTES

1.  To finance these benefits Australia has adopted the non-contributory method of raising the necessary funds, almost entirely, from taxation.  This course disregards well-accepted thought and practice overseas and violates the rulings of finance, economics and equity.  Under the contributory system, every income earner is required to make a specified contribution to a social insurance fund out of which he is entitled to draw specified benefits under certain eventualities.  The fund is financed, in part only, from taxation proceeds.