Saturday, May 30, 2015

Skewed policy ensures size matters in small business sector

Criticism of corporate welfare shouldn't be reserved for recipients from the big end of town, but should extend to small businesses thriving on government largesse.

As illustrated by the glitzy website accompanying the 2015-16 federal budget, a showcase of the fiscal plan delivered by Treasurer Joe Hockey was a new package of small business tax and spending measures.

These include an immediate tax deduction for low-value asset purchases until June 2017, estimated to cost $1.8 billion over the next four years, a lower company tax rate for small companies and a tax discount for unincorporated small businesses costing another $3.3 billion over four years.

These explicitly neo-Keynesian measures, designed to stimulate small business to "have a go" at producing and hiring more, already follows estimated total federal budgetary assistance to the small business sector in the order of $1 billion in 2012-13.

The budget proposals providing explicit tax benefits to small businesses have not gone entirely unchallenged.

Critics have pointed to the obvious fiscal discrimination opened up by reintroducing company tax progressivity, and that the proposals needlessly bolster smaller businesses when firms with lower turnover pay less tax, in any case, under the arrangements which presently stand.

It is well known that vested interests acting on behalf of certain small businesses have long succeeded in wrangling regulatory concessions from the government, effectively shielding them from competitive forces.

For many decades newsagencies benefited from closed-shop regulations affording them exclusivity in the distribution and sale of newspapers and magazines to other retailers and households.

It took deregulatory reforms to belatedly abolish anti-competitive authorisation for newsagents to exclusively distribute periodicals, and the fruits of those changes can be seen today with newspapers and magazines, not to mention books, gifts, and stationery, readily sold by grocers, petrol stations, and others.

The retailing of pharmaceuticals is another notorious area in which small businesses have effectively organised in a contrivance to suppress competition and raise prices at the expense of the general public.

To this day, only registered pharmacists are permitted to own, establish and operate chemist outlets.

These arrangements, and the Byzantine restrictions on where chemists may be located, have prevented supermarkets and other retailers to take advantage of their economies of scale to provide Australians with cheaper prescription drugs and medicines.

While small businesses are often lauded as a highly dynamic segment of the Australian economy, and whose participants are resilient in the face of structural change, there are several high-profile policy flashpoints which appear to contravene such claims.

Representatives of small business, especially bricks-and-mortar retailers, continue to campaign against the corroding effects of online shopping upon their profit margins.

This is reflected, for example, in the praise from the small business community in response to Treasurer Hockey's war on downloads, in the form of the recent announcement to extend the GST on imported digital goods and services.

Even within the Australian bricks-and-mortar retailing set there are intense policy battles being waged between large supermarkets and the small business sector.

With new, low-cost outlets such as Aldi and Costco entering the Australian market and threatening present market positions, it is most ironic that independent stores and small retailers keep crying foul over alleged abuses of market power by the likes of Coles and Woolworths.

As my 2013 research had noted, Australians are among the most price-sensitive retail consumers in the world, with nearly 60 per cent of customers prepared to change grocery retailers on account of a 5 per cent reduction in offered prices.

The extraordinary reach of the small business sector into the Australian political realm does not end with the procession of subsidies, tax breaks and regulatory favours, with small business even having its own government ministers at federal and state levels.

There is clearly much political effort expended, by both major parties, in attempting to appease small business owners and their representative industry organisations, but sound economic rationales for privileging small businesses in a policy context over other firms are lacking.

A longstanding political argument for assistance to small business is that they find it more difficult to access finance.  However, this is not in itself proof that capital markets are failing, since the degree of risk attached to each proposed venture will necessarily differ and this will be duly reflected in varying borrowing costs.

In any case, small businesses tend to be prone to relatively higher rates of business failures, especially early in their lives, even in the presence of corporate welfare and other government preferment.

It may be so that small businesses are, in the aggregate, major employers of labour in Australia, but if policymakers are interested in job creation they should wish to promote a better all-round business climate to encourage employment right across the board.

It is also desirable to be mindful of the adverse economic consequences of small business corporate welfare, including the fact that assistance to one sector of the economy increases costs for others, and some managers might deliberately restructure their firm's affairs to attain specific benefits directed to small businesses.

None of the preceding discussion should be taken to imply there are no legitimate problems facing small business, and indeed many of these problems result from government interventions themselves.

To take one example, heavily regulated labour markets have inflated the costs of employing staff, particularly on weekends and public holidays, ironically countering the effects of trading hours liberalisation, as small business owners feel compelled to shut their doors to remain viable.

However, it would be a mistake to conceive that the problems afflicting the small business community can be effectively addressed through a further entrenchment of the economic roles of government.

The best way for governments to assist business, great or small, is to do away with the political fetishism over business size, and respect the most fundamental rule against doling out corporate welfare and other specific advantages in the first place.

And that rule is that if a business cannot stand on its own two feet economically, attaining profits through exemplary service to customers, it is pointless for the taxpayer to keep the concern afloat.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, May 29, 2015

Orwellian language infects Canberra's tax debate

George Orwell wrote wise words about many things.  Animal Farm and 1984 are two of the most perceptive books about politics and power ever written.  The Road to Wigan Pier is a searing social commentary on the living conditions of the working class in 1930s England.  What Orwell said about the human cost of unemployment still stands.  He invented the terms "Cold War" and "Big Brother".

Orwell was a man of the left but his work is so nuanced he can be claimed by both sides of politics.  Dennis Glover, a fellow at The Chifley Research Centre and once Julia Gillard's speechwriter, wrote Orwell's Australia, a thoughtful book about Orwell's influence in this country.  And at the same time I would include Animal Farm on my list of the 100 most important books on liberty.


THE DANGERS OF LAZY LANGUAGE

Orwell was a prolific essayist.  His best and most important essay is Politics and the English Language, published in 1946.  It is just 10 pages long and is widely available free on the internet.  His argument is simple.  The use of lazy language is a symptom of the decline of clear thinking — and it has political consequences.  Lazy language produces in those exposed to it a "reduced state of consciousness [that] if not indispensable, is at any rate favourable to political conformity".

Lazy language is dangerous because it obscures the actual meaning of what's being said.  "When there is a gap between one's real and one's declared aims, one turns as it were instinctively to long words and exhausted idioms, like a cuttlefish spurting out ink".  Euphemisms can "fall upon the facts like soft snow, blurring the outline and covering up all the details".

Orwell may as well have been discussing the debate on taxes and superannuation in Australia in 2015.

Idioms and euphemisms run riot in Canberra.  The rot started a few years ago when governments started describing tax increases as budget "savings".  To any normal person "saving" money is not spending it.  But to the government "saving" money is taking money from someone else.


TRUE MEANING OF "SAVINGS"

For example, in his 2012-13 budget, Wayne Swan increased the tax on superannuation contributions from those earning over $300,000.  In the budget papers the measure was described under the heading of "Major savings" as a "reduction of higher tax concession[s] for contributions of very high income earners".  Last year when the Abbott government imposed a "deficit levy" and increased the personal income tax rate from 45 to 47 per cent for those earning over $180,000, it should have learned from Labor.  Instead of admitting it was a tax rise the Coalition should have labelled its measure as a "reduction of the personal income tax concession for high income earners from 55 to 53 per cent".  This would have been a perfectly true statement.  Before the deficit levy individuals earning more than $180,000 got to keep 55 per cent of their income;  after, they got to keep 53 per cent.


TAX "CONCESSIONS"

Worse than this is the habit of politicians and the Treasury department to describe the absence of a tax as a "cost to government".  This is exactly what Labor's shadow treasurer Chris Bowen did last week in a speech at the National Press Club.  Admittedly he was only doing what everyone else does who wants higher taxes.  Bowen expressed the view that because tax on superannuation was at a flat rather than progressive rate, wealthy superannuants receive a benefit from the government in the form of a tax "concession" that was a "cost" to the budget.

The idea that when the government doesn't tax you it is somehow doing you a favour completely subverts the relationship between the citizen and the state.  It implies the state has a claim to all of a person's income and when it doesn't take all that income it is making a "concession".  In fact we should think of it the other way around — tax is something we allow the government to collect from us.

Anyone talking about tax "concessions" is using a euphemism of the left.  Coalition ministers and MPs should stop using the term immediately, and then they should go and download a copy of Orwell's essay.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, May 26, 2015

A welcome mutiny against protectionism

It's sometimes thought that the economic disputes that characterised the 1970s and '80s are finished.  The debate over protectionism, for instance, has been displaced by more modern debates over inequality and the environment.

Two issues raised by the Government in the last week show how untrue that is.

On Wednesday, Warren Truss outlined the Government's plan to deregulate Australia's coastal shipping industry, and yesterday the Australian Financial Review reported the Government was considering opening up domestic air routes in the north to foreign airlines.

I was critical of the Government last week for being reform-shy, but these proposals are very, very good.

Both coastal shipping and airlines are governed by cabotage rights — a peculiar 19th century term that refers to the right to transport passengers and goods between two points within a single country.

The issue here is whether foreign-registered or owned or crewed ships and planes have cabotage rights.  For instance, can British Airways fly domestic routes in Australia?  Under Australian law, only in emergencies.  Are Chinese registered vessels allowed to ship goods between Brisbane and Sydney?  Under highly regulated conditions designed to dissuade them from doing so.

Australia's cabotage restrictions are protectionism by another name.  They are restrictions on what economic activity foreign firms can conduct in Australia.  And, as with any protectionist policy that limits competitive pressure, they raise costs to consumers and hinder economic growth.

Let's start with coastal shipping.

Over the last few decades, the number of Australian registered ships used in coastal shipping has been in a dramatic decline.  In 1996 there were 75 Australian registered ships in the coastal trade.  Truss told a conference last week that number was now just 15.  This is mostly due to the heavy burden of Australian industrial relations laws that apply to maritime workers on Australian vessels.

In 2008 a parliamentary committee declared the industry was in "crisis" and "many in the Australian maritime industry (believe) Australia would benefit from a revived and expanded coastal shipping sector".  One of those voices, of course, was the Maritime Union of Australia, whose members were losing out from the decline of Australian coastal ships.

So in 2012 the Gillard government passed a large package of reforms to the shipping industry that dramatically increased restrictions on what foreign vessels and foreign-crewed vessels could do in Australian waters.

Anthony Albanese, then infrastructure minister, made plain the protectionist purpose of the reforms:  "Australian vessels paying Australian wages and providing jobs to Australians will be given preference to carry Australian goods on the Australian coast."

As the former Productivity Commission head, Gary Banks, pointed out at the time, the government admitted these reforms were "strictly inconsistent" with the principles of competition policy that have driven economic liberalisation for the last few decades.

It's worth recalling that those competition policies were originally established by Paul Keating's Labor government.  Labor now is, of course, opposed to any deregulation.  For once that old commentary canard about the modern Labor Party having "betrayed the Hawke-Keating legacy" actually holds true.

Like shipping, aviation has avoided the comprehensive liberalisations of the last few decades.  Not many travellers pause to question why domestic air consists almost entirely of Qantas and Virgin.  Australia is a rich country.  Surely some foreign airlines might want a piece of the busy Melbourne-Sydney corridor?

The Government's proposal to allow foreign airlines to fly domestic routes is limited to northern Australia.  It's being sold as a "develop the north" strategy.  But these sort of region-specific liberalisations are usually meant to be experimental tests for nation-wide reform.  If airline deregulation works in the north — if it provides better, cheaper services — then there will be little reason not to roll it out across the country.

Liberalisation is always accompanied by the bleatings of those whose privileges are being taken away.  "Qantas and Virgin are fighting a rearguard action behind the scenes" against the proposal, one report said yesterday.  More publicly, Albanese complains deregulation would be "unilateral economic disarmament".

It's true that granting cabotage rights to foreign airlines is very rare around the world.  But so what?  Australia used to be a leader in market-oriented reform.  A northern experiment would be good to prove these fears are nonsense.

In a sense these proposed Abbott Government reforms feel like the calm before the storm.  This is cabotage liberalisation by choice before cabotage liberalisation becomes a necessity.

We are on the brink of an unpredictable yet certain revolutionary change in transport technology.  Just as autonomous cars will challenge regulatory frameworks that assume every car has a driver, autonomous ships and autonomous planes will completely change the regulatory — and political — dynamic of these industries.

It sounds all a bit cringingly futurist but the pilotless ships are already seen by Australian unions as a threat to cabotage protectionism.  No labour costs means pilotless ships can travel slower, thereby using less fuel.  This is good for cheap shipping and the environment.

Likewise, when pilotless commercial aircraft become accepted, the old alliance between air services unions and airlines that underpins Labor's opposition to deregulation is going to break down.

When this technological revolution occurs, limits on foreign firms operating in Australia are going to look like the 20th century anachronisms that they are.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, May 24, 2015

Cutting corruption helps the poor the most

The Modi government's war on corruption will create a freer and more prosperous India.  And it's the poorest who stand to benefit the most.  In March, Modi said his government would be a "corruption-free government".  He also said that he would like to see India enter the top 50 of the World Bank's Ease of Doing Business Index.  India's current ranking is 142, out of 189.

India also sits a mediocre 85th on Transparency International's Corruption Perceptions Index.  A recent survey carried out by the Indo-German Chamber of Commerce found that 45 per cent of German executives said that corruption was the biggest obstacle to doing business in India.

But since November, authorities have arrested 19 people for buying and selling stolen documents from ministries relating to foreign investment proposals and energy infrastructure projects.


Helping the poor

Whilst anti-corruption measures are good for big business in India, they are also good news for the almost 300 million people who live in extreme poverty.  Firstly, this is because big business provides large amounts of employment for the poor, which improves living standards rapidly.  Further, reducing corruption is a boon for the hundreds of millions of small entrepreneurs in India, many of whom are extremely poor.

Bribes can be a huge extra cost for any business.  Moreover, the prospect of the appropriation of business profits by corrupt officials and departments is a massive disincentive for small entrepreneurs to take the risks necessary to expand their businesses.

According to the Ease of Doing Business Index, it takes a small- to medium-sized enterprise 30 days to register a business in India and costs 16.3 per cent of annual per capita income.  For individual entrepreneurs operating micro-enterprises the obstacles to business registration undoubtedly constitute an insurmountable barrier in the majority of cases.  Indeed, according to a Credit Suisse report from 2013, 75 per cent of businesses in India are in the unlisted and informal category.

If businesses aren't legally registered they are unable to utilise their assets to acquire finance from banks.  It means entrepreneurs aren't able to buy and sell business assets as effectively.  And it means that small entrepreneurs aren't able to enforce contracts through the judicial system.

The judicial system itself is another major hindrance to doing business in India.  The UN estimates that there are 30-40 million pending cases in India.  All of this makes it difficult for poor Indian entrepreneurs to lift themselves, their families and their communities out of poverty.


They are the solution

Often all it takes to tackle corruption is to shine a light on it.  For example, in Uganda, a report from researchers Ritva Reinnika and Jakob Svensson found that corruption was occurring in the country's education department.  The ensuing media storm was sufficient for a dramatic reduction in corruption to take place.

Furthermore, research from the Peruvian organisation, the Institute of Liberty and Democracy, estimates that the world's poor own $10 trillion worth of assets and enterprises that are currently unregistered.  Indeed, Credit Suisse estimates that 50 per cent of India's $1.85 trillion economy is informal.

The economic potential of accommodating all this value in the formal economy is huge.  Poor people are not the problem, but the solution to poverty as Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto says.  Ending corruption and streamlining business regulation will make life better for all, especially for those living in deprivation.


ADVERTISEMENT

Thursday, May 21, 2015

Party time for unions under Queensland's Palaszczuk government

The use of taxpayer resources to increase union membership is a fundamental attack on freedom of association, but it shouldn't come as a surprise to the public.

According to news reports, the Queensland Labor government has granted unions extensive access to state government resources — including phones, computers, emails and office space — to "encourage" union membership in the state's public service.

This decision was part of a secret deal between the union movement and Annastacia Palaszczuk's newly elected government.

The agreement states that government agencies must take a "positive, supportive role" in recruitment by unions.

This is an outrageous breach of trust.

Rather than acting in the public's interest, Palaszczuk has chosen to use people's hard-earned money to empower a special interest group.

In doing so, the government arguably has violated international treaty obligations by pressuring employees to join a union, a clear violation of the human right of freedom of association.

Palaszczuk is deeply indebted to the unions, which provided most of the funding for her election campaign.  The unions are collecting on their investment.  No doubt they will be grateful for this taxpayer-funded patronage and will repay it at the next Queensland election.

The sense of ownership that the unions have over Palaszczuk's government was highlighted last month by TheCourier-Mail.

The newspaper reported the Queensland secretary of the left-wing union United Voice, Gary Bullock, was bragging about the union's role in the election of seven state MPs, two of whom are now in cabinet.  Bullock was quoted as having referred to politicians as "United Voice MPs" — which will surprise constituents who thought they were voting for Labor candidates.

This is a level of influence unimaginable for any other interest group.  The special treatment is the symptom of a much deeper, interconnected relationship between the unions and the ALP.  This relationship is enshrined in the structure of the Labor Party, and exists throughout the organisational and parliamentary wings.

The ALP's structure is set out in its national platform, which outlines the party's principles, organisational structure and constitutional framework.  The national platform contains a staggering 169 references to unions.

These references range from mere statements of support to measures granting the unions constitutional power — such as the requirement that 50 per cent of all delegates to state conferences have to come from affiliated unions.

This level of influence is replicated throughout the party structure.

In the national executive — the party's chief administrative organisation — 73 per cent of the 26 members are current or former trade union officials.

At a parliamentary level, this influence can be seen in the fact 42 per cent of lower house MPs and a staggering 71 per cent of ALP senators previously have held a paid position in a trade union.

This means that, despite the fact only 12 per cent of Australia's voting-age population consists of trade union members, 51 per cent of federal ALP parliamentarians are former union officials.

The Queensland government's actions are merely the result of this union influence.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, May 19, 2015

Is this Government going to be Fraser Mark II?

By retreating from attack to defence in just 18 months the worry is the Abbott Government has given up on economic reform and will be remembered as another missed opportunity like the Fraser project.

The Liberal Party is not as obsessed with its own history — and its role in Australian history — as the Labor Party is.

But they do still care about the past.  Coalition governments measure themselves against the hero governments of Robert Menzies and John Howard and against the missed opportunities of Malcolm Fraser.

There was quiet, worried chatter before the 2013 election that Tony Abbott's Government, if it didn't grasp the nettle of economic reform, might be a similarly missed opportunity.  It might be Malcolm Fraser Mark II.

So you could see what the Government was thinking with the 2014 budget.  Don't worry — there will be no missed opportunity under our watch.  The budget was aggressive and transformative.  It was all very un-Fraser.

By contrast, last week's budget is the opposite of reformist.  It adopts the same hold-the-ship-steady-and-hope-the-tides-will-wash-us-back-to-surplus approach that Wayne Swan took.  And in other areas of reform — like tax or the federation or the financial sector — it's hard to see any enthusiasm in the Abbott Government for substantial change.

The about-face on fiscal repair between last year's budget and this year's effort has to rank with one of the largest ideological turnarounds in Australian politics.

In part this is because the Abbott opposition went into government with two different stories about its historical role.  First, it wanted to fix the budget emergency.  Labor had left Australia's public finances in crisis.  Tough decisions, fortitude and spending cuts were required.  The age of entitlement was over and so forth.

But they also told another story:  that the Abbott Government would be the restoration of the old Howard order;  stable, secure, "adult government".  Abbott would bring long term continuity rather than change.  Hence the emphasis on old Howard ministry hands.

The Abbott Government has swung wildly between these two extremes.  From September 2013 to May 2014 it marketed itself as adult stability.  Then it had a turn at radical reformism.  Then, with the turn to national security in August last year, it grasped its way back to adult stability again.  Last week's budget is the end of that process.  All of last year's problems have been stowed away or thrown overboard.  Equilibrium has been reached.

Within the Liberal Party, the Fraser government has a reputation for slovenliness.  But it too had some substantial early ambitions.  In many ways the Fraser government has been unfairly maligned.

For instance, Fraser's new federalism remains the best attempt to resolve the problems and contradictions of Australia's federation.  The Fraser government temporarily indexed income tax rates, getting rid of the bracket creep through which inflation lifts us all into a higher tax bracket without adding to our real incomes.

In hindsight, these things look pretty good.  Abbott expressed some interest in reform of the federation, evolving from his anti-states position in his 2009 book Battlelines to a more interesting devolution position in recent years.  There's even been intermittent chatter about returning tax powers to the states.  But the federation white paper process has dropped off the face of the earth.

Joe Hockey's tax review is likely to enter history as just another pointless tax review.  Far from eliminating bracket creep, the Abbott Government is relying on it to raise taxes.  And nobody thinks that Abbott's Murray inquiry into financial regulation will do anything like what Fraser's Campbell committee did for the Australian economy.

The Fraser project died a slow death.  Particularly in its latter years the government reverted to simple tax and spend politics.  The Campbell committee's report languished, leaving the opportunity for financial deregulation to the Hawke government.

But this is the natural way of things.  Governments tend to atrophy.  They get lazy and comfortable.  They move from critics of the status quo to its most loyal defenders.

The worry is that the Abbott Government has accelerated its own decay.  It's retreated from attack to defence in just eighteen months.

One of the central ideas in the Labor tradition is that the Labor Party is the agent of change in Australian history.  Labor is the party of action and initiative (the party of Chifley and Whitlam and Keating) and the Coalition is the party of reaction and resistance (staid old Menzies and Howard).  Julia Gillard's former speechwriter Michael Cooney restates this idea in his recent book.

It's hard to begrudge Labor its own self-serving mythology.  But the trajectory of the Abbott and Fraser governments show how useless the initiative-versus-resistance story is.

We've spent the last year listening to Bill Shorten defend the status quo against the extreme "Tories".  Labor has done its fair share of resistance.  And the Coalition has offered its fair share of radicalism.  But it might be many years before a Coalition government offers bold economic reform again.

Saturday, May 16, 2015

No good comes of taxing the rich

Recent experiences have shown that "tax-the-rich" redistribution policies often end in failure, and are usually politically unpopular.  In 2013 the English translation of Thomas Piketty's voluminous book, Capital in the 21st Century, caused a policy sensation by pointing to what he described as long-run trends towards more severe income and wealth inequality.

Indeed, Piketty, a neo-Marxist, conceived the increasing skewness of income and wealth distribution favouring the wealthy as an inherent feature of capitalist economies, in that returns of capital had an inbuilt tendency to exceed overall economic growth rates.

According to the Frenchman, "the future could hold in store a new world of inequality more extreme than any that preceded it".

For Piketty and his many supporters, who ironically turned Piketty's book into a bestseller, further entrenching him in the global "1 per cent", the threat of an ever-continuing escalation in inequality called for a response.  And a central component of a package of anti-inequality responses ought to be, from this standpoint, new and increasing taxes on income and wealth.

"The ideal policy for avoiding an endless inegalitarian spiral and regaining control over the dynamics of accumulation would be a progressive tax on capital," Piketty said.

Over the last few years political leaders across the Western world have taken the Piketty high-tax prescription to policy heart.  And the results have been decidedly mixed, at best.

Arguably the most iconic example of taxing the rich policy of recent years was the temporary French "supertax" of 75 per cent for earnings exceeding €1 million a year, an idea heavily promoted by Francois Hollande during the 2012 presidential election.

The supertax had a short and much-fraught history, ruled out in its original form by the French high court in late 2012, introduced in an amended form in 2013, but abolished in quiet disgrace this year.

An important reason why this attempt to sop income from the rich failed was that the policymakers who introduced it insufficiently recognised the profound ease with which the wealthy could relocate themselves, and the income-earning capacities embodied within them, across borders.

And no shrill accusations by the big-spending French government that mobile rich people were "unpatriotic" would dissuade them from packing up and leaving for more hospitable tax climates.

Most prominently, actor Gerard Depardieu renounced his French citizenship to reside in Russia which imposes a general flat tax income rate of 13 per cent, with Depardieu paying less under Russian entrepreneur tax offset rules.

Meanwhile, the then richest man in France, Bernard Arnault, packed his bags and opted for Belgian citizenship in response to the high-tax measure.  Depardieu and Arnault were only two of an estimated 2.5 million French diaspora who reside in Belgium, Britain and other jurisdictions in which governments provide greater reward for income-earning effort through lower taxes.

For those who did not leave there were anecdotal reports of widespread variations to executive salary arrangements, in which salary growth during the years of the supertax imposition were restricted with future growth in salaries rebounding later.

This measure was part of a broader package of redistributionist measures introduced during the initial period of the Hollande presidency, and the totality of those tax exactions, including a new 45 per cent income tax rate, raised about half the revenue that was initially expected in 2013.

Given the high degree of mobility for skilled labour and ability to vary employment conditions, at least at the margins, it should have come as no surprise that the expectations of sizeable revenue collections fell short.

It is telling that over the last few months the French socialist government, under Prime Minister Manuel Valls, has gone on something of a charm offensive to reverse the error of the tax-the-rich experiment, by now more openly speaking the language of supply-side economics.

Despite the clear political populism associated with quick-fix revenue-raising schemes which disproportionately target those most well off, it is not always certain that such notions will draw sufficient weight of support from voting electorates.

Despite polls showing a very tight electoral contest between the British Conservative Party and its main Labour Party rivals, Prime Minister David Cameron romped to victory, winning 331 seats in the 650-seat House of Commons.

In stark contrast to the tax cutting, public spending restraining program of Cameron, Labour under (now former) opposition leader Ed Miliband offered the British voters a "mansion tax" on homes over £2 million ($3.9 million), and returning the top income tax rate to 50 per cent, to fund his big-spending promises.

The National government in New Zealand, led by John Key, recorded a resounding win in a general election in which the opposition Labour Party proposed a 15 per cent capital gains tax on wealthy asset sellers.

The former Rudd-Gillard government in Australia vigorously sought to package its mining tax policy as a means of ensuring a fairer distribution of national resources, however such emotive arguments were insufficient to discourage voters from opting for a change in government.

The temptation to extract easy tax revenue gains from the wealthy are not restricted to the political left, but the electoral outcomes remain just as uninspiring.

The Progressive Conservative Party of Alberta was unceremoniously removed from office very recently, after four decades in power, after imposing new and increased taxes, including moves toward a progressive income tax to alleviate a self-induced provincial budget crisis.

Although it is questionable that tax-the-rich initiatives will yield the desired outcomes, namely an alteration in income or wealth distributions which raises sufficient government revenues, there are nonetheless more effective ways to address inequality.

All of these concern the promotion of upward mobility for the poor through removing obstacles to enrichment, without unduly harming the productively wealthy.

Measures to facilitate greater enrichment for those on lower incomes include abolishing anti-job minimum wages, ending prescriptive occupational licensing standards, or attempting to regulate the new "sharing economy" out of existence.

Initiatives that dissipate wealth which has been underpinned by government preferments include ceasing corporate welfare handouts, addressing land-use laws which keep property rents and prices artificially high, and ending monetary policies which have suppressed savings and bolstered global sharemarket values.

These alternatives, in various ways, would certainly encourage more inclusive, broadly based economic growth, starkly contrasting the often tried, but often failed, discriminatory tax-the-rich strategies which merely appeal to the base politics of envy.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, May 15, 2015

Budget 2015:  No big new taxes is a small win

Just as important as what was in Tuesday's federal budget, was what was not in it.  Unlike last year there were no new income taxes.  Nor was there a tax on bank deposits.  Nor was the GST extended to items costing less than $1000 from overseas.

Not imposing these sorts of new taxes is a good start towards the Coalition regaining its economic credibility.  And promising no new taxes — and no higher taxes — is what distinguishes the Coalition from Labor (or at least it's what should distinguish the two sides).

Last year's deficit tax did the Prime Minister and his Treasurer enormous damage.  In one fell swoop the Liberals sacrificed their mantle as the party of lower taxes.  In the end, it was all for nothing anyway.  The hope of the Coalition that in exchange for higher taxes on the wealthy, Labor would somehow be prompted to accept spending cuts, was misplaced.  There have been few bigger miscalculations in recent Australian political history.  Labor and the Greens supported the tax increase and opposed everything else.

A few years ago it would have sounded slightly bizarre to suggest a Coalition budget would ever need to be congratulated for not raising taxes.  But such is the world we live in.  Reform is a game of inches and any win, no matter how small, is a win nonetheless.  In Australia these days the call for higher taxes is inexorable.  Tony Abbott and Joe Hockey did as good a job as could be expected resisting those voices.  Unfortunately, the government didn't completely hold out.  It succumbed to the "Netflix" tax on digital products and it continued its quixotic pursuit of multinational companies.  These measures, together with things such as the imposition of new fees and more regulation on overseas purchasers of property, reveal just how alluring populism can be.  (It's unfortunate the Coalition's commitment to cut red tape doesn't apply to foreigners or real estate agents.)


NO SUPER SURPRISES

Most pleasing of all on the tax front is something else that was not in the budget.  On Wednesday the Prime Minister promised no new taxes on superannuation.  "There will be no changes to super, no adverse changes to super in this term of Parliament, and we have no plans to make adverse changes to super in the future," Tony Abbott said.

Increasing taxes on superannuation would have been the final straw for many Coalition supporters.  The claim from a myriad of left-leaning economics commentators that "the rich" somehow get a special advantage from superannuation, is simply wrong.  As has been said many times — "the rich" pay exactly the same taxes on superannuation as everyone else.  Not changing superannuation is not just a matter of principle.  There's practicalities.  To avoid any potential changes operating retrospectively, the superannuation accounts of millions of Australians would have to be grandfathered.  A complex system would become even more complex.  The surest way to discourage anyone from putting more money into their superannuation than required by law, is for politicians to fiddle with the tax rates as they attempt to take more money from whoever is unlucky enough to be defined as "the rich".

Abbott and Hockey have learned from their mistakes.  Last year they talked about the budget as "fair".  In this country "fair" is usually code for redistributing income.  There was no way the Coalition was ever going to win a debate about "fairness" — and it didn't.

The treasurer's description of his second budget as the "have a go" budget is corny — but good.  If the public spent a bit more time pondering what's needed to allow people to "have a go" it might dawn upon them that some of the things stopping Australians from having a go are the rules and regulations that encourage exactly the opposite sort of behaviour.  Fewer Australians are having a go at starting a small business.  My research identified that the rate at which small businesses are being started in Australia is now at the lowest it's been in a decade.

This week Abbott and Hockey have been talking about growth — as they should be.  It's a lot easier to be fair if the economy is growing than if it's shrinking.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, May 12, 2015

An analogue budget meets the digital world

Budgets are a matter of light and shade.  You have to get the balance right.  And so having spent the weekend talking about its wonderful childcare plans, yesterday the Government paraded Treasurer Joe Hockey in front of cameras to formally announce some of the budget's so-called "tax integrity measures".

Yes, tax integrity measures.  Treasury's spinners would have worked hard on that little catchphrase.  Funny how measures to strengthen the integrity of a tax system always seem to deliver more tax to the government.

First, the Government plans to adjust anti-avoidance laws to crack down on multinationals shifting their profits to lower taxing jurisdictions.  Second, the Government is going to introduce a Netflix tax — that is, try to impose the GST on digital downloads like books, music, videos and so on.

These two are linked, and in an important way that perhaps even Hockey does not realise.  Analogue tax system, meet digital world.

Let's start with profit shifting.  I've tackled the claims that multinationals are evading taxation by shifting their profits across borders on The Drum before.  Long story short:  it's a beat up.  But the Government wants a budget that sounds fair and nothing sounds fairer than beating up on big companies.  The corporate tax is a diffuse and confusing tax.  It's designed that way.

We are told Australian Taxation Officers have been "embedded" in 30 different multinational companies.  We're not told which companies.  And at the press conference yesterday the treasurer didn't want to tell us how much revenue the new anti-avoidance measures might raise.  "It's billions of dollars, obviously."

This should be a red flag.  It's true that Treasury doesn't have a good track record for estimating how much money new taxes will raise — recall the embarrassingly low take from the mining tax.  But this looks less like prudence and more like a lack of confidence.  Running a media or political campaign against corporate tax avoidance is easy.  Trying to reverse engineer the tax accounting of the world's biggest firms is hard.

The Government's crackdown has a certain Sisyphean quality.  In a world where much value is tied up in intangible intellectual property, it is borderline nonsensical for politicians to command that economic activity occurs in this jurisdiction or that jurisdiction.

It used to be the case that big firms had capital assets you could see and touch.  Factories, vehicles, equipment, land.  What mattered to firms were things like location, infrastructure, access to markets, the price and skills of the labour force and so on.  But now the assets of the biggest firms can be placed anywhere in the world instantaneously.  So they tend to be clustered in low tax jurisdictions with established and reliable legal systems.  Like Ireland and Singapore.

What isn't obvious is why this is a bad thing.  Yes, higher tax countries like Australia would prefer that firms book their intellectual property here so Treasury could skim some cash off the top.  But treating big firms to a publicity focused "crackdown" only harms what we should be trying to improve:  the Australian investment environment.  Firms should want to put their assets here.  Implicitly, the Government's profit shifting claims suggest they do not.

There is almost exactly the same issue with the Netflix tax.  Once again, the Government is trying to shoehorn a national tax better suited for an analogue era into the age of digital globalisation.

"It is plainly unfair that a supplier of digital products into Australia is not charging the GST whilst someone locally has to charge the GST," Hockey said at the press conference on Monday.

But why?  The GST is a tax that the Australian government has chosen to place on Australian businesses.  If there is an unfairness here it is an unfairness imposed by the government when it chose to introduce the GST.  It is not "unfair" that other countries do not charge the Australian GST.

When we import goods from other countries — real or intangible — they are priced free of the burden of the many taxes and regulatory costs imposed by the Australian government.  This does not make international trade unfair.  In fact, all those institutional, regulatory and geographic differences between different trading partners are why international trade is so beneficial.

And — as with the profit shifting debate — the Government's rhetoric is running far ahead of its capabilities.  It is absolute fantasy that Hockey and the Australian Treasury will be able to impose our taxes on international digital goods providers in any meaningful way.

Yes, they might be able to convince a few of the big firms to play ball.  But many already are playing ball.  Apple, for instance, already charges GST.  Those online firms with no Australian base and few Australian interests are unlikely to sign up to this new impost.  What's the Government going to do?  Censor them?

It was reported last week that the Abbott Government has scotched many of the tax increases on the table in order to free itself to attack Bill Shorten for wanting to increase tax.  That's good, as far as it goes.

But it would be better if they opposed tax increases because they find increasing tax inherently objectionable.

Ultimately, the tax "integrity measures" announced yesterday have to be seen in the context of a Government that thinks the only viable way back to surplus is more revenue.


ADVERTISEMENT

Wednesday, May 06, 2015

Taxi industry will suffer if it refuses to embrace Uber

Sometimes the loudest opponents of innovation should simply be ignored.

Threatened by the growing popularity of ride-sharing app Uber, the Australia taxi industry has resorted to a campaign of misinformation to protect its market share.

In a response to state Opposition Leader Matthew Guy, who has called for the Government to embrace the service, the Victorian Taxi Association raised the prospect of safety concerns to attack its competitor.

Victorian Taxi Association CEO David Samuel remarked that he was "concerned that a senior member of Parliament would associate himself with a dangerous and illegal service".

Samuel's comments mirror the message from the Australian Taxi Industry Association, which last month claimed to be concerned with community safety, because of the dangers of this "imitation taxi service".

The problem with this party line is that it's just not credible.

As users of Uber can attest, the service — which is based in San Francisco, operates in 55 countries and more than 200 cities across the globe and which is predicted to generate more than $10 billion in revenue by the end of the year — provides a cheap and convenient method of transport, which is considerably safer than traditional taxis.  And it's only the first of a raft of similar services.

Taxi drivers have a dangerous and often difficult job.  They carry large amounts of cash and pick anonymous customers up off the street.

That can create risks for both drivers and passengers.  Passengers can be assaulted and drivers robbed, and there is no guarantee that the offender can be identified when a crime is committed.

Uber has significantly reduced those risks.  The ride-sharing app facilitates a cashless transaction and both the driver and passenger know the other's details before the ride begins.

If a crime does occur, then all of the perpetrator's personal information is available and can be sent directly to the police.  That means that anyone stupid enough to assault an Uber driver, or a driver stupid enough to assault a passenger, will effectively be leaving a copy of their driver's licence and credit card with the victim of the crime.

Uber's rating system provides an additional mechanism for quality assurance.

Both the driver and passenger are able to rate the experience after each ride occurs.  Drivers who fail to keep a high rating — a 4-star rating, according to one Uber driver — are kicked off the platform.  Customers with a poor rating are unlikely to be able to find a ride.

There are, of course, anecdotal examples of dangerous Uber experience, because no system is perfect.  But a simple Google search also turns up several news reports of taxi-related crimes this year alone.

Recently the Herald Sun reported that a bureaucratic mistake had allowed a Melbourne taxi driver to continue driving for two years, despite having being found guilty of groping a teenage girl.

According to Victoria Police, there were 51 assaults committed in taxis in 2013-14 and 60 assaults in the year before.

Those statistics highlight the hypocrisy of the taxi industry.  If the Victorian Taxi Association and the Australian Taxi Industry Association were truly concerned by public safety, and the safety of their drivers, then they would embrace the innovations that Uber has provided.

Unfortunately, they appear to be too afraid of the increased competition and instead are calling for the Government to shut Uber down.

Hopefully, the Andrews Government managed to resist what is an anti-competitive approach when it met with industry and community representatives recently.

Ultimately, however, Uber's success will be determined by the public.  If recent trends continue, then Uber will continue to grow and the taxi industry will be forced to adapt or die.

Uber is safer, cheaper, and more convenient than traditional taxi services.  But don't take my word for it, try it for yourself.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, May 05, 2015

The undone tasks of deregulation

Back in 2007, Kevin Rudd thought he could make a big political statement by outflanking John Howard as a free marketeer.  He claimed to be the true "economic conservative", and attacked the Howard government's "reckless spending".  But that was just half of Rudd's pitch.  A headline in the Australian Financial Review in October that year screamed, "Labor blasts PM over red tape burden".  Readers learned that Rudd had "savaged" the Coalition for the regulation that was "strangling" business.  "Stand by for the Regulation Revolution," said the Sydney Morning Herald;  "cutting back the maze of business regulation and red tape" would be one of Rudd's "top policy priorities".

They say the past is another country.  Campaigns are another planet.  Once handed power by the Australian voters, the practice of the Rudd government was light years away from its soaring campaign rhetoric.  Yes, true to Rudd's promise, Lindsay Tanner was appointed Australia's Minister for Finance and Deregulation.  Yet one of Tanner's first acts as minister was to preside over a vast increase in regulatory control over the finance sector, adopting new federal anti-money-laundering and counter-terrorism-financing laws that had been prepared by the Howard government.

This was just a taste of things to come.  Tanner was our first deregulation minister and the experiment was a failure.  Just as he was unable, as Minister for Finance, to prevent the massive splurge of government spending instigated by Rudd, Wayne Swan and Treasury Secretary Ken Henry, he was unable to hold back the tidal wave of new regulation that came with an interventionist government.  By the twilight of the Labor government, this wave of regulatory interventionism had become a flood.  Rudd's professed disdain for the red tape burden strangling business was forgotten.  Vast new regulatory frameworks were being imposed on labour markets, financial markets, employment conditions, child care, hospitals and health, aged care, competition law, health and safety laws, higher education, charities, coastal shipping, and of course the environment.

These increased the regulatory burden on individual sectors, but also the economy in general.  For instance, the cost of regulation imposed on the mining and energy sectors flow through to raise the costs of downstream products.  Just as taxes — like the carbon and mining taxes — reduce economic growth and living standards, so can regulation imposed on these vital sectors.

Some of the most egregious new regulations were not successfully implemented.  Communications Minister Stephen Conroy was unable to pass his large-scale attempt to regulate fairness in the press.  Attorney-General Nicola Roxon was unable to pass her attempt to create a right not to be offended on everything from race to politics in the workplace.  Roxon did however manage to pass that manifestly absurd and deeply symbolic instance of regulatory over-reach — plain packaging on tobacco products.

These new regulations became a source of pride for the Labor government.  Trying to combat the sense that parliament under Julia Gillard's minority government was chaotic, Anthony Albanese used to brag about just how many pages of legislation Gillard had ushered through parliament.  As the months ticked by the number grew ever larger.  In six years, Labor passed a whopping 975 acts, adding up to 38,874 pages of legislation.

It's true that the volume of legislation is an imperfect measure of the growth in regulation, for a number of important reasons.  It is indicative rather than demonstrative.  It does not take into account the effect that each new piece of legislation will have, nor does it take into account the fact that some legislation might repeal existing law, thereby reducing the regulatory burden.  On the other side of the ledger these figures do not include subordinate legislation nor any state laws and council bylaws.  But it is extremely suggestive.  And constant legislative change imposes its own costs, as I shall discuss below.  In 2012 I calculated that there were 103,908 pages of Commonwealth legislation on the books.

Rudd's deregulation push may have been brazen, but every government comes to power promising to cut red tape.  The Howard government had its own promise to reduce the regulation which was "enveloping small business" but the fruits of that labour are hard to see.  Australia was more regulated after the Howard years rather than less, as was pointed out in the 2009 book The Howard Era.  For all the stability and good governance that the Coalition offered between 1996 and 2007 it did little to stem the growing tide of regulation.  Rudd wasn't wrong when he diagnosed the red tape problem in 2007.  It's just that he wasn't the person — and his party wasn't game — to fix it.

So how does the Abbott government shape up?  There are positive early signs.  On the headline figure of legislative activity, 2014 was a good year.  There were just 135 acts constituting 4607 pages of legislation passed through the Commonwealth parliament last year.  This is a drop from the more than 5000 pages passed in 2013, and happily well below the 8150 passed in 2012.  No doubt this is in part due to the trouble that the government has had passing its bills through a hostile, unpredictable Senate.  But it is also due to the efforts of the Coalition's own deregulation minister, Josh Frydenberg, and the emphasis that the Abbott government has placed on its deregulation agenda.  Abbott and Frydenberg made deregulation one of the central features of its economic message in the Gillard years, leaning heavily on reducing the regulatory burden as part of its plan to revive the economy after years of sluggishness.

And yet.  While the Abbott government repealed 57,000 pages of legislation in 2014 — and claims to have saved the economy a whopping $2.1 billion a year — much of that which was repealed was already defunct.  The real work of deregulation, if it is to occur, hasn't started.

Indeed, the Abbott government's deregulation experience shows why this agenda is so hard to pursue.  In 2013, the much-publicised "Repeal Days" — a single parliamentary day every six months dedicated solely to repealing law rather than introducing it — were important but, as they came around, their agenda items kept disappearing.  For instance, the proposal to eliminate the entirely unnecessary gender-equality reporting requirements imposed on businesses with more than 100 employees had to be dropped, apparently for political reasons.  The reforms to the Labor government's Future of Financial Advice program, which would have taken the edge off some of the most extreme regulatory controls but nevertheless left the previous government's regulatory framework largely in place, were implemented by regulation.  In a surprise upset the Future of Financial Advice reforms were reversed by the Senate at the end of the year.  Other deregulatory proposals — such as the deregulation of higher education — have floundered as well.

Every regulation, even the most absurd, has a unique justification, and its own constituency.  Gender-equality reporting is "not an issue of red tape", according to Claire Braund, the head of an organisation called Women on Boards Australia.  But it is the epitome of red tape — it imposes no other compliance requirements on firms except paperwork, and paperwork that has no other purpose except informing government.  It should be the low-hanging fruit of regulatory reduction.  There is not a single person in the country, except perhaps the bureaucrats that administer the program, who would be materially worse off if this requirement was abandoned.  Yet gender reporting could not be repealed.

In some areas the government seems intent on going backwards.  The Abbott government started 2015 with a stalled budget and by talking up a range of regulatory increases.  It's clamping down on foreign ownership in property.  It's introducing new country-of-origin labels to food products.  It's talking about lowering the GST threshold on imports and digital products, which would require enormous new regulatory infrastructure for retailers and importers alike.  It has passed legislation to impose new controls on social media websites to clamp down on cyberbullying and to require internet service providers to keep vast amounts of information on every Australian's online activities just in case they are in the future suspected of a crime or regulatory violation.

We can bat the pros and cons of these proposals around.  They ought to be debated earnestly.  But they illustrate that even a government as apparently dedicated to deregulation as the Coalition under Tony Abbott is nevertheless unable to resist the steady creep of new economic controls.  There's something much deeper going on here than traditional party ideology.  While it is clear that Labor's approach to regulation was worse than what we saw under the Howard government and what we have seen so far under Abbott, we're talking about differences in degree, not kind.  There is a deep and seemingly inexorable logic of modern democratic government that pushes it towards regulatory excess.  Recognising we have a problem is the first step to solving it.

And it is a problem.  Each year the World Econ­omic Forum publishes a Global Competitiveness Report which rates world economies according to a large range of indicators that would help facilitate business.  Australia does relatively well overall.  We rate well on things like education, the soundness of our banks, the health of our population, the depth of our financial markets, the professionalism of management and so on.  But we are catastrophically bad when it comes to "burden of government regulation" — a terrible 124th in the world, sharing a spot with such economic powerhouses as Iran, Spain and Zimbabwe.  Our competitors rate much higher.  The United States is at eighty-second, while Canada is twenty-ninth.

The Australian Industry Group surveyed 241 CEOs in Australian businesses.  The number of executives who nominated government regulation as one of their top three impediments to growth has grown from 9 per cent in 2011 to 11 per cent in 2014.  This figure may seem relatively small in isolation, but given that it competes against other factors like the global economic and investment climate, it is strikingly high.  Fully 83 per cent of CEOs believe they face a medium to high level of regulatory burden — particularly in the areas of industrial relations and health and safety.

The Minerals Council of Australia commissioned a review of legislative controls on the mining industry.  It found that the number of primary pieces of legislation overseeing project approvals nation-wide increased from ninety-four to 144 between 2006 and 2013.  Subordinate legislation increased even more:  from sixty-six in 2006 to 119 in 2013.  As they told the Productivity Commission's 2013 review into mineral and energy resource exploration, the largest mining states, Western Australia and Queensland, have some of the most onerous regulatory burdens.  Hancock Prospecting's Roy Hill iron ore project in the Pilbara has required a staggering 4000 licences, approvals and permits — much of them imposed by the state government.

The cost burden of regulation is well known.  But more important — and harder to test — is how regulations shape and constrain the economy itself.  A modern economy is subject to constant shocks.  Technologies change.  Preferences change.  New business models supplant old business models.  Political events in distant countries can have unpredictable ricochet effects for Australian firms.  Foreign price changes suddenly render existing ways of work unprofitable, or open up new opportunities.  Firms have to constantly shift their operations, their ways of doing things, even their entire business models sometimes just to stay afloat.  Economic change does not just occur in boom-bust cycles, nor in the long-term technological revolutions that have characterised the last two centuries.  Tiny changes to supply lines, seemingly minor legislative changes in distant countries, and modest but constant adjustments to consumer goods mean that the economic ground is constantly shifting under the feet of the business sector.

Contrast this unstable economic dynamism with the political system that proposes to regulate it.  Statutes reflect the nature of the world only at the moment of their passage through parliament.  Legislation is static — black words in leather books that can only be altered through fraught and complex political negotiation.  Even minor, uncontroversial legislative amendments can take months.  Serious change can take years, from green papers to white papers to exposure drafts to committee inquiries to law of the land.  Each of those legislative changes that the Gillard government was so pleased to have overseen was a long time in the making — the fruit of months and years of bureaucratic busywork.  As a consequence the economic environment depicted in statute is almost always long out of date.  Embedded in each statute are assumptions — about the shape of industry, technological ability, the force of competition — which do not last.

In other words, no matter how active the government is, the law is a static instrument.  The economy it governs is dynamic.  This creates serious problems.  As rock beats scissors, law trumps business needs.  Firms facing economic headwinds find that their ability to adjust is limited by the legislative environment they operate in:  legal constraints are constraints on business flexibility.  In a paper published in December 2014, I demonstrated the perilous decline in entrepreneurism in Australia.  Where new businesses constituted 17 per cent of total businesses in 2003-04, in 2012-13 new businesses were just 11 per cent of total businesses.  Unsurprisingly, the relative decline in business entry is greatest in those states that are the least economically free.

The burden of regulation is most obvious when we look at individual firms — the time spent on paperwork, the business opportunities not pursued.  But all these little disincentives and distractions add up.  Regulatory excess can have serious macro-economic consequences.  In an important paper published by the Swedish think-tank Research Institute of Industrial Economics in January 2015, the economist Christian Bjørnskov looked at the relationship between standard measures of economic freedom and economic crises.  As Bjørnskov finds, a high degree of economic freedom does little to prevent countries from suffering an economic crisis.  But the degree to which an economy is free is a very important factor in how quickly a country recovers from a crisis.  The things that matter here are not whether taxes are low, government spending is modest, or whether the rule of law is strong, but how efficient the regulatory environment is.

Economic crises necessitate a large-scale reallocation of resources, away from troubled sectors and into more stable ones.  At the individual level, a person who has lost a job in an economic crisis needs to move rapidly into new employment — perhaps even new employment in a new industry — before the harm of unemployment becomes too manifest.  Regulations like occupational licensing and industrial relations laws that raise the cost of employment act as a handbrake on the necessary economic adjustment.  All regulation in some way prevents resources from being used alternatively — even if it is just the opportunity cost of time spent filling out gender-reporting forms.  Even when regulation is desirable, we have to recognise that all regulation makes for a less flexible economy, and one less able to adapt to change.

One possible answer to the problem of legislative immobility is for parliament to grant a certain amount of discretion to adjust and interpret regulations according to changing circumstances.  This is what we do when we hand decision-making power over to regulatory agencies.  Yet vesting unelected regulators with discretionary power does more harm than good.  It exacerbates regulatory uncertainty, with serious consequences for the private plans of individuals and firms.  It facilitates regulatory "capture".  And of course it has a democratic legitimacy problem — under whose authority do regulators make what are effectively public-policy decisions?

Nevertheless, policy-makers today lean heavily on delegation to regulatory agencies, handing them quasi-legislative power.  In an important book, Is Administrative Law Unlawful? (2014), the Columbia Law School professor Philip Hamburger traces the origins of such delegated legislative power back past the creation of regulatory agencies at the beginning of the twentieth century — where most scholars' history stops — all the way to the pronouncements of medieval kings.  Hamburger draws a distinction between administrative pronouncements by executive governments that are intended to bind officers of the executive and those that are intended to bind society more generally.  The former form of pronouncement is obviously necessary for government to function.  Bosses need some way of instructing their employees.  But pronouncements that affect the public more generally ought to be the purview of the legislature, not the executive.  These are more akin to the exercise of the royal prerogative than democratic law.

We often imagine that our modern concerns are distinct from those of the past.  But how much legislative power the executive could exercise without parliamentary approval was one of the great contests in the lead-up to the English Civil War.  The seventeenth-century English historian Roger Twysden declared that "the basis or ground of all the liberty and franchise of the subject" was "this maxim, that the king cannot alone alter the law".  Yet through executive pronouncement and delegation governments have vested vast legislative power in what scholars call "non-majoritarian" regulatory and bureaucratic agencies.

We are yet to work out the long-term democratic significance of this approach to governance.  But the economic consequences are dire.  Friedrich Hayek argued that the rule of law had three requirements.  Laws had to be general, that is, they applied not to specific circumstances and individuals but to society as a whole.  They had to be equal — they had to apply to all people in society equally, without discrimination.  And finally they had to be certainCertainty is a strange word to be used in connection with economic life, of course:  there is nothing certain about the future.  But the challenge of economic uncertainty is exacerbated by political uncertainty.  Hayek wrote:

I doubt whether the significance which the certainty of the law has for the smooth and efficient working of economic life can be exaggerated, and there is probably no single factor which has contributed more to the greater prosperity of the Western World, compared with the Orient, than the relative certainty of the law which in the West had early been achieved.

So laws ought to be clearly spelled out.  They need to be "known".  Their consequences and significance ought to be discernible to all those who are expected to follow them.  We ought to limit the discretion that administrators and bureaucrats have in applying the law.

But does this black-letter approach to law really create certainty?  What is certain about black-letter law that is subject to constant revision?  Or black-letter law that is constantly being supplemented, complemented and expanded?  The volume of legislation currently being pushed through parliaments, state and Commonwealth, Labor or Coalition, and invented by regulatory agencies, is itself a challenge to the certainty of the law.  As Bruno Leoni wrote in his classic study Freedom and the Law:

The more intense and accelerated is the process of law-making, the more uncertain will it be that present legislation will last for any length of time.  Moreover, there is nothing to prevent a law, certain in the above-mentioned sense, from being unpredictably changed by another law no less "certain" than the previous one.

Thus, the certainty of the law, in this sense, could be called the short-run certainty of the law.

For anybody who had a time horizon longer than that short run, the law was anything but certain.  Leoni's book was published in 1961.  His lifetime (Leoni was born in 1913) had seen enormous economic and technological change, but the scale of those changes pales in comparison to the shifts in technology and business that we are seeing today.  In just a few years entire industries have shifted out of the terrestrial world into online.  Ubiquitous communications have made older traditions of work obsolete.  It is absurd that we have shop trading-hour regulations, as still exist in Western Australia, co-existing alongside always-on mobile internet shopping.  While firms like Uber and Airbnb are revolutionising transport and accommodation respectively, they present a competitive threat to the taxi and hotel industries that have been lumbered with long-standing and costly regulation.  Stretching our view slightly further into the future, today's regulatory assumptions are going to be challenged by new technologies like 3D printers, consumer drones and digital cryptocurrencies like Bitcoin.  No matter how manic is the legislative activity that characterises our political system, it is nevertheless unable to keep up with social and technological change.

Despite the small but important successes of the Abbott government in reducing some regulation and clearing the statute books of anachronisms, it is obvious that the deregulation movement has stalled.  Deregulation is now more a political slogan than a serious public-policy project.  Politicians have ceased trying to justify the purposes of deregulation and now treat deregulation as a good in-and-of-itself.  This is a testament to the intellectual success of the deregulators of the past — who made the case for lower regulation a virtual self-evident proposition — but it has left the political class with little appetite to actually argue the case for needed reform.  When each side has committed itself to deregulation, all that remains is a rule-in, rule-out game.  Unfortunately, in the nature of politics, rule-outs are more common than rule-ins.  The populist pressure for new law is far greater than the intellectual pressure for less.

Thus the deregulation stalemate, a stalemate more pernicious as we move towards an unpredictable economic future and hyper-innovations in technology.  The issue is not how many "repeal days" are scheduled in a year.  The issue is how the government sees its relationship with the economy.  We do not lack alternatives to the over-regulation path we have taken.  Leoni was an advocate of the common law — the system of private, particular and iterative law-making vastly superior to the statutory law which now dominates our legal systems.  Rather than expecting politicians to play constant catch-up with economic and technological changes, the common law would allow legal issues to be solved when they arise.  Law can be discovered, rather than imposed.

Hayek spoke of "generality" as an ideal of the rule of law.  In modern regulatory parlance this is akin to "neutrality".  Four decades ago the Fraser government's Campbell Committee into financial regulation spoke of "competitive neutrality", just as the Rudd government's Convergence Review into media and communications regulation spoke of "technological neutrality".  The idea is that products or services that compete with each other should face the same regulatory burden.  Deposits in building societies should be regulated the same way as those in banks.  Video broadcast over television channels should be regulated the same way as video served over the internet.

Neutrality has proven to be more of a catchphrase than a policy program.  This is because genuine regulatory neutrality undermines some of the most fundamental assumptions of government economic management.  To regulate is to control.  Every advocate of new regulation has an idea of the world that their proposal would create.  Regulation is always purposeful — it has a goal, a vision of a fixed future.  For all the valuable discussion of technological neutrality, Labor's Convergence Review collapsed into absurdity when it was unable to shed a fundamental belief in the ability of governments and regulators to shape the world around them.  Rather than reducing the burden on highly regulated television services, it proposed to expand those regulations onto the ungovernable internet.  Neutral, yes.  But also absurd.

The Convergence Review offers a microcosm of the broader regulation problem.  Regulatory excess is the result of governments trying to impose their values on the economy — using law to shape the economy according to their own preferences rather than allowing the economy to flow unpredictably according to consumer demand and entrepreneurial experimentation.  In that sense, it is a reflection of the political system from which it emanates.  If the Abbott government wants to go down in Australian history as a significant reform-driven government, then the "deregulation agenda" is not enough.  It needs to start a serious rethink of the relationship between the dynamic, entrepreneurial economy and the static but over-energetic regulatory state.


ADVERTISEMENT

Is the looming internet filter justified?  Not yet

Is intellectual property "property"?  Kinda.  Sorta.  Not really.

That question might seem a bit abstract, on par with how-many-angels-can-fit-on-the-head-of-a-pin.  But it matters.  Because how Parliament sees the fundamental nature of one form of intellectual property — copyright — is almost certainly going to determine whether we are subjected to a new internet filter.

A bill now before Parliament, the Copyright Amendment (Online Infringement) Bill 2015, would give courts power to require internet providers block access to foreign websites whose dominant purpose is to facilitate copyright infringement.

In practice this means that Time Warner, which owns the copyright to Game of Thrones, could go to a judge and demand Telstra or iiNet block access to the Pirate Bay.

There are lots of problems with this bill.  Its language is absurdly vague and broad.  What counts as "facilitating" copyright infringement?  Maybe it would block sites that offer virtual private networks, perhaps — those VPNs that Malcolm Turnbull has been encouraging us all to use.

But these are legislative technicalities.  More importantly, blocking websites is censorship.  The bill is an internet filter, no matter how stridently the Abbott Government rejects the comparison.

Supporters of the bill argue that technicalities and censorship aside, the real issue is that property is being stolen, and the Government — whose job it is to protect property — needs to act.  After all, private property is a human right as much as free speech is.  (Check out Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights.)

It is true that intellectual property shares some of the characteristics of property.  Like tangible property, intellectual property can be owned.  It can be traded.  So it's property in those senses.

But, unlike tangible property, the use of intellectual property is not exclusive.  When one person listens to a song or watches a movie they do not prevent others from doing so.  It can't be "stolen" in anything but a metaphorical sense.

This is why the law hasn't treated intellectual property like real property.  We don't have a moral right to perpetual ownership and unimpeded exclusive control over the songs we write or movies we produce.  For instance, copyright lasts 70 years after the death of the creator.  Real property has no such time limits.

The scholar Tom W. Bell says that intellectual property would be better called intellectual privilege.  This privilege is conferred for a specific purpose — to provide an incentive for the creation of new works.  The theory is if we don't confer that privilege people will supply less creative work than is socially desirable.

But that privilege has costs.  For instance, copyright also stops us from using our other, real property as we see fit — we can't use our computers, printing presses or internet connections as we would like.  And we can't build on the cultural capital created by others.

Thus the Howard government's Ergas Report into Intellectual Property and Competition Policy argued that "over-compensating rights owners is as harmful, and perhaps even more harmful, than under-compensating them".

So will the proposed Copyright Amendment (Online Infringement) Bill 2015 inspire the creation of new works?  Even if placing a block on the Pirate Bay successfully stops internet piracy (please bear with me on this fantastic hypothetical) will artists go out and create more art as a result?  And would enough new work be created to compensate for the restriction on free speech?

Many economists theorise about an "optimal" level of copyright protection — a sweet spot of enforcement and rules where the benefits of copyright are maximised and the costs are minimised.

Yet it is very hard to figure out where that sweet spot is.  Even impossible.  And the political system isn't looking for the optimal policy — it's looking for the most politically palatable policy, the one where the benefits are being maximised for politicians, not consumers.

In the United States, every time Mickey Mouse threatens to fall into the public domain the Walt Disney Company lobbies hard to extend copyright term limits.  Nobody really thinks that maintaining Disney's exclusive rights over Mickey for another decade or two will lead to more creative works being produced.  But these are decisions made by politicians, not blackboard economists, so the extensions get granted.

The Australian Parliament has been considering copyright enforcement changes since last year.  We've heard a lot of pontificating about "theft" and digital access and global release dates.

But the only policy question is whether website blocking would inspire the creation of enough new content to make up for the fact that the Government is censoring the internet.

And, so far, nobody has shown that would be the case.

Monday, May 04, 2015

New laws will impact Sydney apartment sizes

Sydneysiders are now even more restricted in what size they may build their own apartments, given the latest minimum apartment size restrictions, laid down by the NSW Land and Environment Court last month.  They will only stifle innovation and increase already ballooning house prices.

The controversial April 9 court decision deemed the current established rule of thumb for apartment sizes too low.  Minimum sizes in Sydney are now given by an adjacent table in the Residential Flat Design Code.  This code requires new apartments to be up to 35 per cent larger.

The latest rules in Sydney mean one-bedroom apartments must be 58 square metres.  Last year in Melbourne 40 per cent of apartments had a floor space under 50 square metres.  These regulation changes mean more people will be priced out of the Sydney market who will be forced to live further from the city.

Local governments will now have more power to reject apartment applications too.

The original guidelines were introduced in 2002 and focused on improving design quality.  Among other measures, these State Environmental Planning Policy No. 65 (SEPP 65) rules mandated the role of registered architects in multi-residential development, included provisions around minimum amenity standards, and established design review panels.

These planning restrictions set a worrying precedent in this country.  Pointing at these rules in Sydney many other jurisdictions are facing pressure from lobby groups.  For example, in Victoria last year a leaked document outlined plans for similar restrictions on Melburnians.

Artificially limiting the size of apartments will bring higher prices at a time when most argue we are in an already inflated market.  New housing affordability numbers tell a bleak story:  even taking into extremely low interest rates, credit agency Moody's showed the share of household income needed to pay off a typical home loan is at a 10 year high.

My recent research shows that an individual receiving an average wage now needs to spend a full eight years of income to cover the capital city median house price.  This is the least affordable housing in some 130 years.

Increasing minimum apartment sizes will only worsen this problem.  Basic microeconomics suggests that any reduction in supply — unless arguing for a highly unlikely corresponding fall in demand — will increase prices.  Minimum size restrictions mean fewer apartments.  Couple this with growing demand as more people want to live in the city, means apartment prices skyrocket.

Innovation will also suffer from these new rules.  Minimum sizes provide no incentives to better use small and valuable amounts of space.  Without this market pressure, developers are shielded from testing, experimenting and optimising with innovative methods.  Around the world architects have been forced to optimise small space design and this has resulted in profound innovation.  These innovations much be encouraged.

As Australian cities face population constraints — especially with the geographical make-up of Sydney — developers must be left to innovate and discover new ways to increase population density.  The answer to an increasing population is not to restrict the number of houses in the CBD and hope for a greater urban sprawl.  It is to allow the market to develop new ways of utilising existing space;  free from government prescriptions.

These new restrictions also have a clear nanny-state mentality.  By regulating both the minimum size and the composition of private property, local governments are suggesting individuals are incapable of determining their own acceptable living conditions.

The government has no place — even if it be in the rhetoric of sustainability or quality — to encroach on how we may organise and use our own property.  If an individual wishes to trade additional space for a convenient location, then they should be free to do so.

In the year to March Sydney house prices rose by 13.9 per cent.  Climbing out of this housing affordability mess requires the NSW government to abolish all minimum apartment-size restrictions.  These restrictions only drive up prices and prevent individuals from discovering new ways to optimise the space we have.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, May 02, 2015

Abbott government at the budget crossroad

In our high-cost, slow-growth economy, the litmus test for the second Abbott budget is its laying out a credible plan for fiscal repair without relying on tax increases.

For much of this year the Abbott government appears to have engaged in vigorous retreat over the need to alleviate quickly the core budget overspending problem.  The fiscal consequences of reversing previous decisions to reduce spending are significant.

Late last year, the government's Mid-Year Economic and Fiscal Outlook statement indicated, somewhat darkly, that the impact of Senate refusal to allow the passage of measures to consolidate the budget would cost at least $10 billion over a four-year period.

The Intergenerational Report released in March provided something of a longer term picture of the cost of the Abbott government's political retreat from budgetary repair, with a budget deficit under a "policies currently legislated" scenario stretching as far as present generations will live.

Backing down on the Medicare co-payment proposal;  reversing the previous decision for a lower rate of Defence Force pay increases;  and even continuing subsidies to an economically retreating automotive industry are some cases in point.

What this has meant, politically, is that the likes of "bust the budget" protesters and a recalcitrant Senate appear to have prevailed over the government, and now every interest group in the country possesses the magic formula to retain their treasured policy or program.

And that formula is to cry out, for long enough, that specific fiscal consolidation measures are unfair, with the expectation that government will back down later.

The policy capitulation has also been evident with regard to the taxing side of the fiscal equation, with several new and increased taxes already having been implemented, and still more envisaged in the forthcoming Budget.

In its first Budget the Abbott government reintroduced fuel indexation and imposed a "deficit levy" income tax surcharge, estimated to collectively raise about $7.1 billion over four years.

Before that, the government announced it would also keep the additional revenues pick-pocketed out of the wallets of smokers, in the guise of increasing rates of tobacco excise.

Since its decision of late last year to remove barnacles from its political hull, the federal government has floated an astonishing array of new and increased taxes so as to ensure that revenue takings further increase to already overinflated expenditure levels.

High on the speculative agenda include suggestions to further increase the burden of our already uncompetitive direct taxation system, including the winnowing of superannuation tax concessions, an end to corporate tax dividend imputation arrangements, eliminating negative gearing provisions, and the further repression of savings through a bank deposits tax.

Many of those interest groups opposing expenditure reductions are voicing their support for tax rises with equal vigour, wagering that their supporters will likely be spared the brunt of additional taxation especially if they are targeted toward those with relatively greater incomes or assets.

What the proponents of such plans for even greater taxation ignore is that existing arrangements are, more often than not, in place to avoid the incidence of "double taxation" for example if a company paid tax on profits yet dividends to shareholders were also taxed.

To invite double taxation in our fiscal affairs would be a strategy rather conducive to economic penury in the long run, not least because of the great injury that such punitive tax impositions upon incomes, investments, and savings would cause to productive activity.

Some figures within the government have rationalised the pro-taxation strategy as an integral part of a so-called "balanced approach" to fiscal consolidation.

This approach effectively treats tax increases and expenditure reductions as symmetrical in a public sector financing accounting sense, but ignores the differing effects of these approaches to fiscal contraction upon economic performance.

As the works of economist Alberto Alesina have illustrated, expenditure reductions can help achieve the desired budget recovery outcomes with the least adverse economic effects, particularly if spending cuts are targeted to areas in which unproductive expenditures are being undertaken.

Alesina suggests that expenditure-based fiscal adjustments are associated with smaller economic downturns, if at all, than tax-based adjustments, and that spending cuts especially when combined with deregulation have, in some circumstances, supported economic growth.

Reinforcing the basic findings, based on studies of fiscal consolidation episodes in advanced countries, an emphasis upon tax increases has strong and negative effects on investments, thus dragging down economic growth rates.

As it stands, Australia is far from a low-taxing economy, certainly when taking into account policies, such as compulsory superannuation, that exude financial impositions for similar policy purposes found elsewhere in the OECD.

From this perspective, additional taxation increases run the risk of further knee-capping the robust economic growth required to furnish the public treasury with sufficient "growth dividend" revenue to help abate our budget emergency.

Incidentally, slower growth rates will also keep aggregate government spending higher than it could otherwise be, including due to higher rates of welfare dependency.

The sour reactions by sections of the community to even printed suggestions of very modest spending reductions, at least in aggregate terms, indicates that there are constituencies that swiftly organise in a quest to validate past spending decisions, irrespective of their economic and social consequences.

Calls for a heavier taxation burden should be viewed in this vein, being ambit claims to financially ratify often poor-value governmental expenditures, thus entrenching larger government as a fact of life.

A great tragedy of Australian politics is that centre-right politicians all too often fall spellbound to the pro-taxation agenda of their adversaries, in an erroneous application of the noble act of fixing the financial messes centre-left governments leave behind.

The recent past has demonstrated centre-right governments have, also, been most amenable to tax system changes rendering it easier for the public sector to collect more revenue, in the name of "efficiency" which, incidentally, constitutes the abuse of the very term itself.

The federal budget, much like the Australian economy more generally, is at a crossroads.

With spending galloping away at an exorbitant rate, to collect even an additional dollar through discretionary increases in the tax burden would represent a dereliction of economic policy of the highest order.

There is only one way to fix our budget emergency, and that is through expenditure reduction, and this will serve as the ultimate litmus test for credible fiscal consolidation.


ADVERTISEMENT