Thursday, November 30, 2006

Lucky Australia hasn't avoided mistakes

Australia has been relatively lucky.  The "tyranny of distance" has isolated us from the disastrous wars of Old Europe.  Our huge land can support many times our population, and throughout history its resources have supplied our economy with boom after boom.

As a consequence, Australia entered the 20th century with the highest living standards in the world.

But by the 1970s, we couldn't even crack the top dozen.

Australians are an entrepreneurial, creative and diverse people.  The blame for this fall can be placed solely at the feet of government decision makers, propelled by ideology, the lust for power, or unfortunate ignorance of the consequences of their actions.

Some of these mistakes are obvious.  In 1935, the Queensland Government introduced cane toads into Australia to combat pests in sugar cane crops without full understanding of the consequences.  Cane toads are now considered one of Australia's worst environmental disasters, breeding freely and poisoning native animals.

Many of the most harmful policies were the earliest ones, and have been the hardest to repeal.

The Immigration Restriction Act was the first bill passed in the new Federal Parliament and inaugurated the national White Australia Policy.  This terrible policy gave bigotry the legislative blessing it was to enjoy for more than half a century.

Another early policy established the doctrine of wage fixing in Australia, rigidly setting workers' salaries to enable a man with an average sized family to live in "frugal comfort".  Sounds like a good thing, unless you are one of the workers who, through no fault of your own, are suddenly priced out of the market and condemned to unemployment.

Centralised wage fixing has been devastating for low-skilled and migrant workers, and it is only recently that it has been substantially pruned back.  Even now, many politicians still don't understand that government can't set wages, only the market can.

The Australian media also provides an example of disastrous government policy.  If it wasn't for political control over the airwaves, which the government also gained quickly after federation, perhaps media policy could've avoided a century-long comedy of errors.

Over the last century, with their power over the broadcast media governments, have held back the introduction of AM radio, television, FM radio, subscription TV and now digital television.  Never mind the consumers, media policy since the signing of the 1905 Wireless Telegraphy Act has been designed to protect the established media from so called "harmful competition".

If a service like YouTube required government-managed airwaves to operate, rather than the free-for-all internet, there is no chance it would have been given a license to operate in Australia.

Patrick White's Nobel Prize in 1972 was a notable success for Australian literature, and the government speedily inaugurated the Australian Council for the Arts.  But by isolating artists from their commercial audience, they may have condemned much of Australian art to mediocrity.

How would Charles Dickens's have novels read if he had not been exposed to the demands of a fickle public?

The steady production of publicly funded Australian films, so many unwatched, is not a failure of Australian taste, but of government policy.

When we failed to win a single gold at the Montreal Olympics, the government's response was, unfortunately, predictable.  The Australian Institute of Sport, modelled on similar institutions behind the Iron Curtain, spends an enormous sum of taxpayer's money on elite athletes, despite the huge commercial power of sport in this country.

After both success -- Patrick White's Nobel -- and failure -- the Montreal Olympics -- the government has responded by creating vast new bureaucracies.  This steadily increasing burden upon the economic and cultural life of Australia is not consequence free.

How has all this occurred?

Perhaps the worst mistake was Canberra itself.  The invention of Canberra moved the bureaucracies and regulators away from the economic and cultural powerhouses of the nation, and dropped them into a new, meticulously planned "garden city" in the middle of nowhere.

As the historian Keith Hancock wrote, "Canberra is a document of Australian immaturity".

Isolated from the people they were supposed to be governing, it is little wonder that these vast Canberra bureaucracies increased their own size and influence.  Many of the mistakes made in Australian history are a consequence of this.  A lesson may be learnt for new and developing countries -- never move your government away from your citizens.

Thankfully, steady reform since the 1970s has partly reversed some of the worst mistakes.  But if we'd had a strong, liberal, free-trade party in Australia that embraced individualism and economic and social freedom throughout the course the twentieth century, perhaps we could have avoided some of these disastrous policies.

For a long time it has been common to talk about market failures.  Let's start talking about the failures of government.

Wednesday, November 29, 2006

No umpire needed in sport media

The AFL, with its of salary caps and draft restrictions, is one of the most regulated sports in the world.  Unfortunately, the Australian media is just as regulated, and the regulations punish clubs, consumers and players.

Protectionism may no longer dominate as an economic ideology, but it lives on in the Australian Government's approach to the media.

Invariably, from the artificial limitation on the number of television licences, to the banning of advertising on the ABC, to the digital transition debacle, each and every media regulation and reform proposal seems designed to protect incumbent free to air (FTA) broadcasters and penalise their competitors.

Anti-siphoning laws, which give FTA broadcasters first rights over a huge range of premium sporting content, are some of the most egregious examples of this protectionist approach.

FTA broadcasters are granted the privilege by government of not having to compete for broadcast rights in a fair and open market.

Like all protectionist rhetoric, advocates of the current system couch their arguments in the "public interest" and "protecting the consumer" terms.  But preventing pay television from bidding for broadcast rights is not without cost.

A modern sporting competition is an extremely expensive affair, and, like any other business, its producers strive to appeal to demanding consumers.

To do so, the sports have evolved, not only in the manner in which they are played, but also through technological innovations that alter the experience for consumers.

Coaches utilise better communications and analysis tools to manage their teams.

Players utilise more powerful -- and more expensive -- medical advances to prevent injury and enhance performance.

And consumers utilise a variety of print, electronic and broadcast media to access statistics and interactivity to enjoy their game more.

But all this requires money.  By restricting pay television from the market for broadcast rights, sporting codes are deprived of a potentially lucrative source of funds.

Competition is intense between the FTA broadcasters, but by banning alternative broadcasters, the final price that broadcast rights are sold at is likely to be lowered.

Anyone that doubts that this is a problem should identify any sporting code or club that wouldn't be able to use the extra money.  Many sports on the anti-siphoning list, like netball and the IndyCar series, do not command the enormous audiences that the big football codes do.  Restricting the market for the broadcast of these sports punishes fans -- it doesn't protect them.

With the larger sports, problems are just as evident.  The demise of the Fox Footy Channel, a casualty of the lopsided negotiations between FTA, pay television and the AFL, has been a loss for consumers.  Die-hard fans are denied the opportunity to enjoy a channel dedicated to the sport to which they are devoted.

If the AFL had been able to negotiate with Foxtel directly, this may have not occurred.

As Justice Ron Sackville, judging a Federal Court case over AFL rights this month, stated:  "The poor old AFL is denied the opportunity of a fair and competitive process to get the best price for its product ..."  He continued:  "Now, that seems odd".

Exempt from anti-siphoning restrictions, Football Federation Australia has been able to sign a deal with Foxtel to show all Socceroos, A-League and Asian matches.  These rights were sold on mutually agreeable terms, and should help the code establish itself in the mainstream.

The anti-siphoning laws punish consumers and sporting codes, but the larger objection is philosophical, and one shared by the codes themselves.

Those who make a product, own it.  The sporting codes should be able to determine to whom and under what condition those rights are sold.

The anti-siphoning laws confiscate the property rights of the producers of sport.

A better approach would be to treat content broadcast on television or radio neutrally.  Governments should not be making a determination of the relative importance or merit of certain forms of entertainment.  Doing so punishes the very consumers that these laws profess to protect.

The Government's media reform bills have not tackled with any rigour the Government's regressive approach to the media.  Unfortunately, its penchant for protectionism does not appear to be abating.

Sports are supposed to be competitive, why can't broadcasting be the same?

Saturday, November 25, 2006

All hail to the new godless religion:  environmentalism

Labor is indignant that the Liberals are apparently siphoning green voters away from them.  They even look likely to lose a seat as a result and, more worrying, the Greens party looks set to win the balance of power in the Upper House.

Both major parties are dancing around the edge of the ardent followers of environmentalism, the new godless religion.  Green-inclined voters mostly have no allegiance to the conventional left/ right dichotomy.  Comprising an estimated 12 per cent of the electorate, their political stance is one of "rational ignorance".

"Rationally ignorant" voters see little need to familiarise themselves with the details of the mainstream political parties, especially since those parties have converging policies that are underpinned by fiscal conservatism.

Indeed, as the next government is certain to be Labor or Liberal, some "rationally ignorant" voters feel they can cross the two-party abyss and vote for the Greens.  In doing so they are able to indulge their moral virtue knowing their votes will not elect a green government.

The ALP has traditionally looked to harvest most green-leaning votes as preferences.  As such, it has traditionally been more generous in heisting the taxpayer and consumer dollar and allocating those funds to voter-friendly causes.

The Al Gore fictional scenarios and the exaggerations of the Stern report have reinforced the environment as the most profitable venue for such expenditures.

The Switkowski report on nuclear power has added further noise into the energy and environment dimensions of the Victorian election debate.  But any nuclear plant in Victoria is decades away, even if there is a fully fledged carbon tax.

For its part, Labor is firing environmental salvos from all cylinders.  It even introduces its energy policy with the absurd claim that the state's energy use has brought temperature increases, less rainfall and increased bushfire risk.

It has announced a new $1 billion-plus energy tax in the form of increased renewable requirements and will foist additional energy-saving costs on new buildings.

Labor will not have a bar of a new dam, and tries to keep a straight face while it claims its water policies will provide 50 years of security.

The Liberals have responded by engaging in environmentalist talk backed up by dollops of taxpayer and regulatory-driven funding.  Examples of these are subsidies for solar power, clean coal, water recycling, rain water tanks, and new regulations for container deposit legislation.

The Liberals say they will build the much needed dam but feel the need to sweeten the pill with expensive water-recycling policies, an unnecessarily self-indulgent desalination plant and yet another new national park.

Liberal leader Ted Baillieu has not gone as far as the British Conservative Party leader in environmentally outflanking Labor.  Instead, Baillieu has picked policies designed to waste as little money as possible and to prise away some additional "rationally ignorant" green voters while minimising the consequent economic harm.

But no politician can doff their hats to the new environmental gods without incurring economic costs.

All this bidding for votes means hitting people in the pocket while pretending not to do so or trying to persuade the target voters that their own pockets will be immune.  This makes the democratic auction system an unsavoury business.

And even though the major parties recognise a budgetary constraint on spending, the GST bonus and increased taxes as a by-product of house-price inflation have mightily eased those pressures.

In all Australian states, Labor, once it abandoned its uncontrolled pandering to interest groups, quickly mastered the rules of the new democracy auction.

As a result, Labor has established itself as the normal party of power at the state level.  It basically only expects to lose state office when it goes too far in accommodating special interests, or gets mired in scandals.

It is yet to be seen whether a conservative leader can break this mould.  Baillieu thinks he can do so.  Saturday will reveal if he can successfully couple his political personableness with appeals to the "rationally ignorant" green-inclined voter using versions of Labor's wasteful spending and taxing measures.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, November 24, 2006

Mighty Murray will cope

I wonder what will happen if the Murray River runs dry next year?  I don't mean completely dry, but rather, if it is reduced to a series of billabongs as it was in 1914 and 1923.

For so many years we have been told that the river environment is in a desperate state because irrigators take too much water, when, in reality, water levels in the river have been kept artificially high.  Indeed irrigators in South Australian have been receiving fully 80 percent of their water allocation from storages at the top of the catchment, from water stored in Lake Hume and Dartmouth Dam.

But the past year really has been dry -- it didn't rain or snow much in the Australian Alps in winter and the Murray Darling Basin Commission has been releasing a lot of water as environmental flow.

In October, 2005, the NSW and Victorian governments -- the same governments who this year are complaining their dams are empty -- made the world's largest delivery of environmental water.  They let the equivalent of a Sydney Harbor of water flood the Barmah-Millewa red gum forest which straddles the Murray River upstream of Echuca.

The joint release saw 513 gigalitres of water delivered to the forest and the inundation of more than half of the forest floodplain, resulting in greatly improved conditions for wetland vegetation and breeding activity for key wetland fauna according to a Victorian government report.

"Wetland vegetation, including moira grass and the threatened wavy marshwort, responded with significantly improved condition and the flooding waters provided for new growth and canopy regeneration in stressed river red gums", the report said.  "The release also triggered large reproductive events in important native fish species such as golden perch and the threatened silver perch as well as in many water bird species, including the great egret, darters, spoonbills, grebes, ibis and cormorants, and the critically endangered intermediate egret".

All this, during one of the worst droughts on record.

Then there is the water being sucked up from regrowth (following the January 2003 bushfires in the upper catchment), new timber plantations, groundwater licenses being activated for the first time, improved on-farm water use efficiency, water recycling, water being evaporated by the Murray Darling Basin Commission's salt interception schemes and also low precipitation.

Given all of these factors, it's perhaps not so surprising that the region has a chronic water shortage.

Prior to this month's Canberra water summit, National Farmers Federation (NFF) executive director, Ben Fargher, said the priority should be to ensure that towns which support regional communities have certainty over water supply.  NFF also wants a strategy to "effectively manage core breeding stock, permanent plantings and other production issues in order to protect Australia's agricultural base".

But that's impossible if there is no water.

If the Murray does run dry, farmers and rural communities that draw water from the river will be devastated, but it will not be a disaster for the environment.

Australian rivers have run dry before and the Murray cod will survive in the billabongs.


ADVERTISEMENT

Thursday, November 23, 2006

Give voters what they really want

On Saturday, most Victorians will probably struggle to remember a single election policy from either Labor or the Liberals.  Voters will be aware that the parties are promising to spend a lot more money on a lot more things, but this will be the full extent of their knowledge.

Regardless of who becomes premier, the majority of the electorate will be relaxed about the outcome.  Sometimes in elections, the parties attempt to be different from each other.  During this campaign we've had the reverse.

The fact that we are in such a situation is not necessarily something to complain about.  We're lucky that for the moment, at least, our economic and political circumstances are such that to many voters the election is irrelevant.

The question for the future is whether state elections will ever be relevant.  State elections don't matter any more because the traditional policy battlegrounds of health, education and transport are now outside the control of state governments.

The decline and fall of state elections is not only the result of the centralisation of power in Canberra.

Since the 1980s, state governments around Australia have allowed the private sector, competition and market forces to play a much greater role in the provision of key social services.  Although Spring Street still provides the funds for services, how that money is spent is increasingly outside the authority of public servants.

Health services are delivered by autonomous hospital boards.  In education, while the curriculum is still determined by the government, self-management in the government sector and the growing non-government sector restricts the ability of education ministers to direct what actually happens in classrooms.  Nearly every aspect of public transport has been privatised, with transport policy now being almost exclusively about new road building.  Policing is one of the few areas that has remained relatively unchanged.

During the election campaign, the parties have been happy to tinker at the edges of health, education and transport policy.  In the years ahead, the driver for improvement of these services will be more competition and more privatisation, measures that as yet no party is willing to contemplate.  And of course, more competition and more privatisation will take services even further out of the reach of government.

It's quite likely that in the future, state elections will matter even less than they do now.  This is because state elections are about what state governments do or not do.  However, the answers to many of the problems governments try to solve rest with individuals and communities, not government.  Often the answer is less government, not more.

For example, the "obesity crisis" is not the fault of the state government and it is not within the power of the state government to fix it.  Labor has promised to give students from prep to grade 2 fruit every Friday.  (How the Education Department will get the students to eat their fruit is not clear).  The responsibility for overcoming obesity in children rests with their parents and their families, not with government.  Talking about free fruit on Fridays is easier than explaining hospital waiting lists.

Another case is mental health, with both major parties making major commitments to the issue.  The ALP has said it will appoint a mental health minister and will spend an additional $130 million, while the Liberal Party will spend an extra $222 million.  These policies are fine as far as they go.  But the reality is that some of that money will merely go towards attempting to fix the tragic problem that state governments themselves have created.

De-institutionalisation was a bipartisan policy motivated by the best of intentions.  However, it was implemented without adequate resources and without acknowledgement of the pressures it would place on the community.  The product of the policy can be witnessed daily on our streets and in our jails.

Overwhelmingly, it is family members who provide the care for their loved ones suffering from mental illness.  State governments are failing because they continue to impose a one-size-fits-all approach to mental illness.  Giving families what they want has its political perils.  Families might not want a new health centre that can be opened by the local MP in a blaze of publicity.  Instead, they might want additional funding for extra hours of specialist medical treatment.  Unfortunately, empowering individuals and families with both resources and the choices that resources provide, isn't the neat solution beloved of bureaucrats.

No party has ever tried to be elected with a slogan of:  "Don't trust us to fix your problem -- because we don't know how".  Voters are wise enough to realise the limits of government, and across a range of policy areas they are looking for answers that go beyond what governments have the capacity to do.  When the political parties learn this lesson, state elections will start to be relevant.


ADVERTISEMENT

Wednesday, November 22, 2006

Friedman's success is based on his passion for freedom

Freedom lost one of its foremost soldiers last week.  Until his passing, Milton Friedman remained committed to the causes he championed.  He is best known for his work on monetarism and its adoption by Reagan and Thatcher, but his success stemmed from his commitment to freedom.

I met Friedman last year.  As a young and enthusiastic free marketeer, I took the chance to contact him when I was in the US.  He invited me to his home on Knob Hill, San Francisco.

Friedman and I discussed global trade, the European Union, and his workload.  What struck me was the depth of his understanding of contemporary issues.  Most 93-year-olds would be enjoying their twilight years.  But Friedman said he spent most of his time keeping on top of events, and literature.  He was cogent and analytical and still contributing to intellectual life.

Until the day he died, he was senior research fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University, a position he held since 1977.  This office contrasts from the days he influenced the Oval Office or No. 10.  Yet it is largely representative of how he conducted his life's work.  He never sought high office, and used the power of ideas to sway government policy.

Critics have tried to rewrite his history.  During the ceremony for his Nobel prize in 1976, protesters attacked him for working with the Pinochet government of Chile.  What they ignored was his purpose and achievements.  Pinochet brought Friedman to Chile to slay the dragon of hyper-inflation.  It was bankrupting the country due to the communist inflationary policies of Salvador Allende.  Friedman successfully argued that reducing state intervention in the economy would slow inflation and promote growth.  For Friedman, his aim was as much to slow inflation as it was to promote economic freedom.

He believed that by promoting economic freedom, social and political freedom would follow.  History shows he was right.  In an interview for the 2002 television series Commanding Heights:  The Battle for the World Economy, he pointed to the link between the return of democracy in Chile to the economic liberty he was responsible for.  He can also take much credit for Chile's wealth that embarrasses neighbouring socialist economies.  Not surprisingly, his help to structurally reform an oppressive Chinese communist state did not attract the same ire.

In the 1962 book Capitalism and Freedom, he argued for economic freedom to protect social and political freedoms.

He convinced a generation of Americans that free markets were under attack from the false promise of socialism and the welfare state.  When governments take responsibility for economic security they must use its coercive authority to direct resources to achieve this goal.  The nightmare of 1984 is shared by Orwell and Friedman.

Free markets trade security for liberty.  Friedman argued the most successful societies were those that unleashed the maximum potential of individuals, rather than trying to suppress it for equality or stability.

Free markets also curtail the excesses of government by promoting individual power and responsibility.  This comes to the core of his faith in freedom and the individual, and that "underlying most arguments against the free market is a lack of belief in freedom itself".

To have faith in free markets, you have to have faith in freedom;  to have faith in freedom you need to have faith in humanity.  He did.  His faith in humanity is the essence of his contribution and attitude.

Many have cited his preference for the Republican Party as evidence of a conservative.  Friedman was a radical.  He often said he was philosophically a classical liberal and for pragmatism, a Republican.  Yet he championed causes that riled many of his Republican contemporaries, such as the decriminalisation of drugs, his opposition to conscription, and the US invasion in Iraq.  Friedman had what so many other self-anointed radicals don't -- a consistent framework that he saw the world through.  He saw everything through its impact on human freedom.

This is what drove him to establish the Friedman Foundation.  Its charter remains the promotion of school choice for parents.  Friedman believed vouchers would marry the benefits of choice with the need for universal access to education.

Despite his work, teacher unions resisted any push for increased demands in an education market.  They used the weapons of class envy to promote fears parents with privilege would top-up the value of their children's education.

Friedman remained undeterred.  He said when parents used money to buy alcohol and cigarettes no one complained.  When it was spent to top up the financial contribution of their children's education, parents were charged with anti-egalitarianism.

Compared with fighting back the tide of Keynesian economic policy, his work on school vouchers remains unfulfilled.  But trials have been held, and the idea has moved from the fringes to the mainstream.  In 2000, then governor Bush announced his support for a school vouchers program as part of the platform for the presidency.

We have lost one of freedom's greatest advocates.  Yet his legacy is not the sum of his individual contribution, but the promise of the benefits of his life's work extending to those who do not now enjoy them.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, November 21, 2006

Losing our cheap energy birthrights

Politicians are adept at talking through both sides of their mouths at the same time.

Morris Iemma had no difficulties in doing this when simultaneously announcing a major deregulation initiative and on the same day, November 9, announcing a major new regulatory explosion by the energy department.  Mr Iemma could comfortably ride two horses pulling in different directions.  But he could not also accommodate a media frenzy into the Orkopoulos child sex and drugs story.

The deregulatory report was by the Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal (IPART).  It was a 308-pager promoting more rigorous reviews of regulatory proposals and a sterner oversight of proposals by a central regulation review agency.

Perhaps wisely, with its deregulation initiative the New South Wales Government is not following the path planned by its Victorian counterpart.  The Bracks Government has committed to a 25 per cent reduction in Victoria's regulatory burden and is requiring departments to rescind one regulation for every new one introduced.

The NSW Government had been sitting on the IPART report for a month before releasing it concurrently with plans for an increased Renewable Energy Target that massively increases the cost imposition on the state.  Those plans seek to shift the renewable component of NSW energy from its current 10 per cent to 15 per cent.  The plan is accompanied by the sort of consultant's report on which governments squander public money to veil the real costs of their actions.

Notwithstanding snowfalls in Canberra as we approach Christmas, the current greenhouse hype is forcing every politician from the prime minister down to bow towards carbon reducing measures.  Even so the NSW proposals break new ground.

The consultant's report employs an economic "model" appropriately named WHIRLYGIG.  Whether or not this includes flying pigs among its rides is not stated.  However, the outcome of the "modelling" is that moving from 10 per cent to 15 per cent renewable energy would bring the "efficient cost for average households (at) approximately 30 cents each week".

If that is all it costs what is the fuss about?  Based on these calculations could we not have 100 per cent renewables for an additional $6 a week and go beyond the widest ambit of the state-financed green groups?

We are presently in the wake of the hype from the Blair Government's Stern Report on climate and the calumny of incomplete factoids in Al Gore's film An Inconvenient Truth.  Given the brouhaha that these PR pieces have created, many governments have decided to jettison all leadership aspirations.  Bowing to opinion polls that appear to show overwhelming support for more greenhouse action, they are now fabricating data to dampen concerns that there may be a price tag to this.

NSW and Australia generally enjoy the lowest cost energy in the world.  Not only does this translate into cheaper power bills for households but it has been the fulcrum on which our industry structure rests.  Take away cheap power and we take away Australia's processing industries.  These have assumed vital importance to this country ever since the 1970s oil crises banished forever the cheap oil that once fuelled processing industries in Japan and other countries not blessed with our reserves of coal.

The NSW and to a lesser degree Victoria Governments are intent on embarking on a great equalisation program -- hobbling our own energy sector to reduce its efficiency to the level of other countries.  Fortunately for Australia, Queensland is standing firm and readying itself to fulfil its "destiny" as the lowest cost source of energy in the world, with all this implies for economic growth.

The southern states, in rejecting their cheap energy birthrights, are consigning themselves to dinosaur status.  Not only will politically imposed higher energy prices mean energy intensive industries no longer being attracted to their states but it will mean the progressive migration of those industries and their jobs to other jurisdictions.

Perhaps -- and this brings us back to the WHIRLYGIG -- we can replace the lost employment with jobs in economic consultancies.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, November 19, 2006

Open competition means playing to win

A key reason why Australia has enjoyed prosperity over the past dozen years is the opening up of the economy to greater competition.

One part of this was reform to abolish monopolies held by government businesses and private companies protected by government regulations.

Businesses that were integrated, such as a railway that owns track as well as trains, had to allow their bottleneck track facilities to be used by competitors.

Industries with similar structures included electricity, gas, ports and telecommunications.  Unscrambling bottlenecks allowed new and more efficient players into the market.  This forced all suppliers, new and old, to look to more efficient ways of meeting consumers' needs.

The dividend for Australia has been higher standards of living as under-performing facilities became better used.

However, requiring companies to allow their facilities to be used by competitors creates tensions.  You can imagine Holden's reaction if it was told it must allow Ford to use its vehicle assembly line.  It would be like telling a homeowner rattling around in a large house that she must let others use some of her spare space.

Faced with such requirements pretty soon investors would start avoiding the controlled assets.

On top of this, policing laws that require facility sharing spawns new bureaucracies and, like all bureaucracies, these will seek to expand their roles.

For these reasons, throughout the world, governments and courts have confined facility sharing requirements to very specific and rare circumstances.  Less so in Australia!

Governments normally require private companies to share only those facilities that cannot be duplicated.  In Australia our laws provide applicants an easier path.

Rupert Murdoch has complained about the slowness of the Australian internet.  This is an outcome of regulations requiring Telstra to share any high-speed investments it makes with its competitors.

A legal case is presently being fought about access to rail lines serving iron ore mines in the Pilbara.

A small new producer wants to force BHP to allow it to piggyback on its rail lines.  BHP is resisting this because it wants to retain control of its assets.

As a result, it and Melbourne's other giant iron ore miner Rio are being deterred from expanding their vital rail network to take advantage of the China-led boom in iron ore.

They are unsure about whether the law will take away their control of any new or existing rail lines which they see as an integral part of their production process.

Predictably, the responsible regulatory agencies led by the National Competition Commission are assisting the company seeking piggyback access.  For the NCC the case offers considerable potential to open up its area of its influence and employment.

However, such jobs are precisely the ones we want to avoid.

Opening up access to these sorts of facilities provided a lightning rod to increased prosperity.  But its downside has always been recognised -- indeed the Productivity Commission has remarked about potentially chilling effects on new investment of forcing companies into unwanted contracts.

We have made the gains from unscrambling former government monopolies.  Now is the time to adopt the more restrictive framework for such requirements that are seen in other similar countries.

Saturday, November 18, 2006

Industrial Relations and the struggle to build in Victoria

Occasional Paper

OVERVIEW

Politics in Victoria revolves heavily around impressions about which political party and leader is better at "getting things done".  Jeff Kennett established his reputation as a "doer", whereas the previous Cain and Kirner Labor Governments were denigrated for being controlled by unions who blocked development projects.  This benchmark of apparent political capacity to "get things done" applies, in particular, to major infrastructure construction projects.

Victorian unions are a dominant factor in determining whether construction projects in Victoria are completed on time and on budget.  The unions that hold sway are the Construction, Forestry, Mining and Energy Union (CFMEU), the Electrical Trades Union (ETU) and, to a lesser extent, the Australian Metal Workers Union (AMWU) and the Australian Workers Union (AWU).

It is well recognised and commented upon that the Cain/Kirner ALP Government was destroyed because of Victorian unions.  The Bracks/Brumby ALP Government has been determined not to allow Victorian unions to destroy its period in office.

This briefing paper looks at the success (or otherwise) of the Bracks/Brumby efforts to have major public and private projects completed on time and on budget.  The focus of this paper is the impact of industrial relations on those two measures.  It case studies, in particular, the largest construction project ever undertaken in Victoria -- the EastLink Tollway.


RELEVANT TIMELINE

Late 1999Bracks/Brumby Government elected:  Does not control Upper House of Parliament.  Federal Workplace Relations Act (WRA) governs Victorian industrial relations.
Apr. 2001Saizeriya plant begins construction.  Melton.  Completion target:  February 2002.
2002-03Cole Royal Commission inquiry into the construction sector.  Finds that Victorian commercial construction is 20 per cent plus more expensive than housing construction because of industrial relations factors.
Oct. 2002Federal Building Industry Taskforce begins.
Nov. 2002Bracks/Brumby Government re-elected.  Gains control of Upper House.
Feb. 2003Saizeriya plant remains uncompleted.
2003-04Commonwealth Games construction starts/occurring.  MCG, Games Village.  Southern Cross Railway Station development.  Contract for EastLink let (November 2004).
2004Howard Government strengthens its Building Code.  (This is a federal code applied to all new federally funded or part-funded construction projects.  Any builder/contractor who wishes to undertake federally funded construction must have industrial agreements and practices consistent with the code on all government work.)
Oct. 2004Howard Government re-elected.  Controls Senate.
Nov. 2004EastLink construction begins.
Sept. 2005Federal legislation passed creating the Australian Building and Construction Commission (ABCC) with the task of policing industrial activity in the commercial construction sector.  ABCC also empowered to police the Federal Building Code.
2005Building code strengthened further with requirement to comply on private-sector work.
Dec. 2005Federal WorkChoices legislation passed.

THE BRACKS/BRUMBY PERIOD

The Bracks/Brumby period in government began badly as far as important infrastructure projects were concerned.

The first major problem which occurred entirely within their period of government was the Saizeriya food manufacturing plant in Melton.  Saizeriya is a giant restaurant chain in Japan serving Italian food.  Like the McDonald's chain, Saizeriya manufactures its food externally to its restaurants.  Saizeriya had decided to consolidate all its food production in one giant plant in Victoria.  Plans were drawn up for an eight-factory complex costing some $400 million on a massive site in Melton which would eventually employ some 500 people directly.  All the food produced was to be exported to Saizeriya's restaurants.  The additional infrastructure investment required to support and supply the plant with raw ingredients was projected to be over a billion dollars in new abattoirs and vegetable gardens.  It was the largest planned food manufacturing investment in Australia's history.  The first phase of the manufacturing complex involved one factory at a projected cost of some $40 million.

The Bracks/Brumby Government inherited the Saizeriya project plans from the Kennett Government.  Saizeriya was the first major project in which the Bracks/Brumby Government had total input into the industrial relations arrangements.  They guided and advised Saizeriya.  It was a problem from start to finish.  The Government advised Saizeriya to sign an industrial agreement for operations with the National Union of Workers.  This infuriated the AMWU, which asserted that it had rights to control labour at Saizeriya's manufacturing operations.  The AMWU teamed up with the CFMEU during construction.  The CFMEU delayed the construction phase and the AMWU delayed the machinery installation phase.  The construction project ran more than 18 months over time.  Saizeriya's restaurant expansion plans in Japan were heavily disrupted and Saizeriya's share price dropped.  The Victorian Government advised Saizeriya in Japan that the problems lay with Saizeriya's Melbourne-based management team.  The reality, however, was that a factional union war was the cause.  This was linked to broader factional disputes inside the Victorian ALP.  The facts were revealed in the Cole Commission Inquiry into the construction industry.

The outcome of the entire sorry situation was that Saizeriya was caught up in a union-ALP factional battle over which Saizeriya had no control.  The first factory was eventually completed, but Saizeriya then announced that the rest of the project would not proceed.  Saizeriya subsequently sued the Victorian Government for $42 million in damages.  An out-of-court confidential settlement was reached.

Not only did this industrial relations fiasco cost Victoria the largest food investment project in Australia's history but it has done untold damage to Victoria's and Australia's investment reputation throughout Asia.  There are apparently several Saizeriya-type businesses in Asia that might well have considered investing in Australia -- in Victoria, in particular.  That possible investment has now been shelved.

The Saizeriya scenario has been repeated in Victoria during the Bracks/Brumby period on many occasions.  The dynamics of each situation are always different and specific to the projects in question, but industrial relations are always a key factor.

  • The Holden engine plant upgrade ran over time and significantly over budget as a result of industrial relations problems.
  • The redevelopment of Federation Square was an industrial relations fiasco resulting in extra costs and significant delays.
  • The redevelopment of the MCG had such high-profile industrial relations problems that the Federal Government refused to contribute $80 million to the project because of an unacceptable industrial situation.
  • The Commonwealth Games village was built with CFMEU workers and industrial agreements instead of using standard housing construction work arrangements which involve neither unions nor industrial relations agreements.  The Games Village, consisting of 115 permanent and 115 temporary housing units, was essentially no different from a standard housing development that would occur in Victoria, except for the temporary security and other Games-related requirements.  The 2002 budgeted cost for the project was $144 million.  The Government has not released comparative data but estimates indicate that the additional cost of the housing construction at the Games village was in the order of 25 to 30 per cent over normal housing costs.  This is consistent with comparative estimates arising from the Cole Commission inquiry into the construction sector.
  • The Geelong Freeway upgrade was afflicted with cost overruns and delays due to industrial relations issues.
  • The Austin/Mercy Hospital development was badly affected by industrial relations problems.  The Government has not made financial data available that would indicate the consequent cost overruns.
  • The redevelopment of the Southern Cross Railway station was also a cost and delay scandal attributable to access difficulties, design issues and industrial relations problems.  Although it opened in time for the Commonwealth Games, it is in fact still unfinished.  The original contracted price for the job was $286 million, but it actually cost $341 million.  The construction company announced a loss on the job of $122 million and sued the Victorian Government.  The claim was settled for $32 million to compensate for contract variations and other related issues.  Industrial relations problems with the project were particularly severe and reported widely.  On the foregoing figures, it could be estimated that delays due to industrial relations problems cost the construction company up to $90 million.  This figure is again consistent with the findings of the Cole Commission Inquiry into the construction sector.  This amount would be in addition to industrial relations contingencies which the company would have factored into its original contract price.
  • The Commonwealth Games swimming pool upgrade was known to have suffered from significant industrial relations delays and cost overruns.  The budget blew out from $50 million to $60 million.  It could conservatively be assumed that $5 million was attributed to industrial relations issues.

The projects mentioned above were started, committed to or wholly undertaken with industrial arrangements that pre-dated the WorkChoices and ABCC legislation.

In each of these cases, the full costs of the budget overruns is unknown because of government and private company secrecy about relevant information.  However, there is enough information in the public domain to indicate that the cost overruns are in the many hundreds of millions of dollars and could even approach half a billion dollars just on these identified projects.  A conservative estimate, however, would be as follows:


Private additional costs

Saizeriya
  Estimate $30 million

Holden Plant
  Estimate $ 4 million

Southern Cross Station
  Estimate $90 million

Public costs

Federation Square
  Estimate $40 million

MCG
  Estimate $100 million

Austin/Mercy Hospital
  Not sufficient information to assess.

Games Village
  Estimate $20 million

Geelong Freeway upgrade
  Estimate $15 million

Games pool
  Estimate $5 million

Total probable cost:  $304 million


In each of these cases, project redesign and other technical issues will have been contributing factors to the costs being greater than the original planned estimates.  This is common to many large construction projects.  But what has been by far the biggest contributor to cost overruns and delays is the nature of the industrial relations situation in Victoria.  Further, the foregoing figures are for areas of known delay and overruns.  That is, they do not take into account the fact that standard construction budgets in Victoria build into the cost estimates a significant allowance for anticipated industrial relations problems.  This is normally estimated to contribute at least an additional 15 per cent and is added to budgets.

The principal unions involved in this have been the CFMEU and the ETU, with the AMWU involved in manufacturing developments and anywhere significant metals fabrication is required.  The scale of these costs can be better appreciated by looking at the EastLink project in some detail.


EASTLINK CASE STUDY

The EastLink project is the largest single infrastructure project ever undertaken in Victoria.  It is a 40-kilometre road construction project linking Mitcham and Frankston and the Eastern, Monash and Mornington Peninsula Freeways.  A $2.5 billion project (2004 figures), it is expected to take four years to complete.  This compares with the CityLink construction which cost $1.8 billion.

It is a project that is a good case to comparative costs of different industrial relations approaches:

  • It is a physically and financially large project and therefore any costs differentials associated with industrial relations issues come into stark relief.
  • A comparison can be drawn between CityLink and EastLink.  CityLink was constructed entirely before the federal reforms to industrial relations occurred with the passage of the WorkChoices and the ABCC legislation.  EastLink, on the other hand, is being constructed under an IR regime heavily influenced by those federal industrial relations reforms.  In other words, CityLink was constructed using industrial agreements under the old WRA.  EastLink is being constructed using industrial agreements and laws arising from, or influenced by, WorkChoices together with the enforcement agency of the ABCC.  It is the first major project in which industrial relations differentials can thus be highlighted.
  • Several of the companies involved in the consortium that won the EastLink tender were heavily involved in the CityLink project.  The technical, engineering and management competencies involved with East-Link are similar to those used on CityLink.
  • As of July 2006, EastLink construction is reported as running a year ahead of schedule substantially as a result of industrial relations peace.  (The Age, 11/7/06) CityLink was known to have suffered significant industrial relations problems, particularly as a result of spurious OHS campaigning by unions.  This was reported in the Cole Commission Inquiry.

We have undertaken a general analysis of CityLink's industrial relations arrangements and compared them with EastLink's industrial relations arrangements.  This has been possible because:

  • The Cole Royal Commission into the Building and Construction Industry placed significant details in the public domain on CityLink's industrial relations issues.
  • We have developed considerable knowledge about industrial relations agreements as a consequence of its Capacity to Manage Index project (CMI).  This project ran for over four years, during which it studied and rated the impact of pre-Work-Choices industrial agreements on managerial capacity.  The CMI project analysed some 315 industrial agreements and awards.  In particular, it examined some 40 agreements and awards from the construction sector, including agreements entered into by companies involved in the EastLink and CityLink projects.
  • Further, we collected date from operators in the construction industry.

This combined knowledge has been used in this assessment.

The core of this assessment can be posed as the following central questions:

If EastLink had been constructed under industrial agreements that were outside of the WorkChoices and the ABCC environment, would there have been additional costs to the project?  If so, what would those costs be?

Significant cost differentials have been found, amounting to $295 million on very conservative scenarios and estimates.

The estimate of $295 million was arrived at by considering the industrial relations costs that were imposed on CityLink which do not appear to have been imposed on EastLink.  In other words, if EastLink had been forced to be constructed under CityLink-type industrial arrangements, EastLink would cost at least $295 million more to construct.  This figure comprises direct costs and toll revenue losses by not opening on time.


THE NATURE OF THE INDUSTRIAL AGREEMENTS

The major agreement at Eastlink is one involving both the AWU and the CFMEU.  The way in which this agreement was reached is important to understanding the productivity and cost benefits delivered to Eastlink.

The AWU has limited presence on Victorian construction projects, which are normally dominated by the CFMEU.  The Cole Commission revealed that the bulk of industrial militancy in Victoria related to the CFMEU.  Originally, the Eastlink construction consortium entered an agreement with the AWU.  When this became public, the CFMEU became highly agitated and would have used their industrial muscle on other sites in protest at being locked out of the agreement.  A settlement was ultimately reached in which the key enterprise agreement involved both the AWU and the CFMEU.

This time, unlike the Saizeriya situation, the inter-factional war between unions was played to the advantage of the consortium's construction needs.  In addition, the agreement was reached in a political environment where the Federal Government's labour reforms were looming large both before, and after, the 2004 Federal election.

The outcome was an agreement which was a marked improvement upon standard industrial agreements for construction projects in Victoria.


Some basic EastLink facts

Total contracted cost of EastLink:  $2.5 billion.

Federal Government was to contribute $540 million if the road were toll-free.

Cost to Victorian budget if built toll-free:  $1.96 billion.

Anticipated traffic per day is 250,000 vehicles.

Toll charges are capped at $4.33 per car.  Heavy vehicle charges are higher.

Revenue for Eastlink when opened will "comfortably" be $20 million a month -- $4.6 million a week.  (The Age, 11/7/06)

Monthly construction expenditure is around $50 million, peaking at $100 million, with the largest cost being labour, involving a workforce of around 1,600 to 2,000 (The Age, 11/7/06)

Wage cost estimates

(from AWU/CFMEU Agreement : rounded)

Full-time weekly employee$900
   Add 19 per cent for hols/leave$170
   Add site allowance$5
   Add Incolink redundancy fund$63
   Add other allowances$5
   Add superannuation$140
Base benefit to F/T employee$1,283
per week

This does not include double-time on Saturdays and other shift allowances of 50 per cent.

Average packaged value of each full-time job would exceed $70,000 per year.

Add payroll tax of around 5 per cent and workers' compensation (of around 11 per cent in the construction sector).

Total cost per year for each full-time employee:  around $82,000 plus.

Not all 2,000 employees will work full-time for the full project.  But assuming that construction will involve the equivalent of about 1,000 full-time enterprise agreement paid people (excluding managers/engineers, etc.), the cost of labour for the project would be about $328 million.  ($82,000 x 1,000 x 4 years.)

This gives average weekly labour costs of around $1.56 million.

On the same assumptions, the total number of working days required for the project from a costs' perspective would be about 880,000 (1,000 people x 220 available working days x 4 years).  (NB:  "Working days excludes weekends, holidays etc.)

Number of working hours required:  around 6.3 million (880,000 days x 7.2 hrs).

Note:  The CFMEU/AWU Agreement allows for 26 rostered days off [RDOs], with half of those days at times to be decided in discussions with management, and half at the discretion of individual employees in consultation with management.  This is very different from normal Victorian construction, where RDOs are set days requiring total construction close down.  The Eastlink project allows for flexible RDOs thereby avoiding construction close down.

Weekly site overheads:  If work stops on any project, the construction company has locked-in site cost overheads which continue to accrue.  This is a significant cost factor in assessing the impact of lost construction due to industrial action.  The weekly site overheads for the Eastlink project are unknown but can be assumed to be high.


UNION DELEGATES EMPLOYED BUT NOT WORKING

Standard commercial construction agreements before the introduction of WorkChoices and the ABCC required construction companies to employ union delegates who did no work on sites.  This was particularly so in Victoria under industry-enforced pattern enterprise agreements.  The delegates simply oversaw the industrial agreements to enforce compliance.  They were the unions' eyes and ears on worksites.  They organised industrial activity against companies and were the instigators and organisers of industrial disputes.  Oddly, these people, whose job it was to work against the interests of companies, were on companies' payrolls.  The CityLink consortium partners typically had such requirements for non-working union delegates.

It is not clear if the Eastlink industrial undertakings require non-working union delegates.  However, the likely cost impact of such delegates can be assessed.

The number of non-working delegates that could have been expected on EastLink would have been fifteen or more.  The cost of these delegates' direct wages and benefits is estimated at $5 million plus.  This assumes wages, benefits and on-costs of at least $82,000 per union delegate per year over four years.

With non-working delegates on site, Victorian construction companies normally factor a disruption cost into their budgets.  That is, based on experience, it is assumed that the project will take longer than might otherwise be the case because of industrial disputes.  From the Cole Commission Inquiry a figure of around 5 per cent more work time could have been expected from industrial relations problems if non-working unions delegates had worked on EastLink.

This would have added somewhere near 315,000 work hours to the project's cost, which equates to around 8.7 additional weeks to complete the project.  This would create substantial additional site overheads which cannot be estimated.  Eight weeks plus of delay would cost around $40 million in lost toll revenue.  A further $13.5 million would be incurred in direct labour costs of the working workforce.


Probable additional costs

Union delegates' direct wages$5 million
Additional employees' direct wages$13.5 million
Site overheadsnot estimated
Toll revenue forgone$40 million
Total$58.5 million

NON-WORKING AND NON-PRODUCTIVE DAYS

In 2004, standard industry practice enforced through union industrial agreements prohibited overtime being scheduled on certain days.  The Victorian industry had an organised calendar with which everyone was supposed to comply.  These lock-down weekends were linked to holidays and Rostered Days Off to effectively extend days on which work on sites was stopped or restricted.

The days rostered as non-working days and/or restricted working days in the industry included:

Public Holidays10 days
Union picnic days1 day
Christmas close down9 days
RDOs26 days
Lock-down days12 days
Total58 days

These unproductive days, imposed on the industry through industrial agreements, delayed project completion times, thus escalating costs considerably.  Since Work-Choices came into effect, these restrictions have been largely removed.  The ABCC has been particularly active in policing Federal Building Code compliance in this area.  Further, these restrictions were largely eliminated in the AWU/CFMEU agreement.  In particular, RDOs are not set on prescribed days but can be arranged by the construction consortium to fit in with construction schedules.

This creates significant advantage to the construction job.  It means that construction activity on EastLink can theoretically occur 365 days a year (assuming rostering arrangements can be put in place and the contractors are willing to pay loadings, etc).

Over the four years of the project, this 365-day-a-year potential operation probably adds an additional 242 days of potential productive work days when compared with standard 2004 arrangements.  (50 Sats, 1 union picnic, 9 Xmas close down, 26 RDOs, 12 lock-downs) This should enable the project to finish and open some 40 weeks or more earlier than under the 2004 arrangements.  The fact that the construction timetable is reportedly already 12 months ahead of schedule (The Age, 11/7/06) after less than two years of construction tends to validate this assumption.  In fact, the speed with which the project is progressing is almost unheard of in the history of construction in Victoria over the last 20–30 years.

Multiply this by an estimated toll revenue of $4.6 million per week and the additional potential revenue available to the operators of EastLink is $184 million.  Early completion of the work would create significant overheads' savings to the contractors -- certainly in the tens of millions of dollars, although this figure cannot be estimated with accuracy.

Assuming continuous construction, the total estimated differential advantage to EastLink is at least $184 million.


DISRUPTION TO AGREEMENTS DURING PROJECT

Before WorkChoices, the ABCC and Federal Building Code came into effect, Victoria had an unregistered industry agreement, the Victorian Building Industry Agreement (VBIA), which was in force and to which all builders were expected to adhere.  The VBIA was the principal agreement by which Victorian unions were able to secure their control of worksites.  Non-adherence to the VBIA by any builder would result in builders' sites being closed down by unions.  The VBIA was due to be renewed around November 2005, that is, a year into the Eastlink construction.  Under WorkChoices/ABCC, the VBIA has effectively been neutered -- some would argue outlawed.

If EastLink had been required to operate under pre-WorkChoices/ABCC arrangements, it would have found itself in new enterprise agreement negotiations with unions in 2005 (VBIA renewal) in spite of the fact that it had project-specific agreements through until 2008.

It is standard practice in the construction industry to budget for significant industrial disruptions during agreement renewals.  Renewal of the VBIA has a long history of creating industrial turmoil in the Victorian construction sector.  EastLink would have been faced with this problem under pre-WorkChoices/ABCC laws.

When agreements are renewed, it is common practice in Victorian construction to assume at least five weeks of production disruption and productivity decreases during negotiations.  This could have delayed the opening of EastLink by, say, two weeks.  This would create a loss to revenue of $9.2 million ($4.6m x 2) and additional unknown overheads.

Total estimated differential:  $9.2 million plus.  This does not take into account additional labour costs as a result of wage increases under the agreements.


SPURIOUS OHS CLAIMS

The Cole Commission analysed the incidence of sham OHS claims and disputes on the CityLink project.  It was found that OHS excuses were used extensively by unions to conduct what were, in reality, industrial relations campaigns.  Significant delays to CityLink arose as a result.  The Commission's data suggest that the OHS shams may have contributed as much as 10 per cent to the total programme hours of CityLink.

If WorkChoices/ABCC had not been implemented, it could be reasonably assumed that EastLink would have suffered from at least a 3 per cent increase in programme working hours (and that is a conservative estimate).  This would add an additional 190,000 working hours to the project, with an additional (say) $8.3 million in direct labour costs.  The delay in completion would be around 5 weeks, leading to an unknown increase in overheads and a loss of toll revenue of $23 million.

Cost differential:  $31 million.


BAD WEATHER

The industry standard before WorkChoices was to "down tools" on entire sites for even the smallest amount of rain.  Melbourne has a rainfall pattern which is not consistent across the city.  Rain frequently falls in one part of the city but misses suburbs quite close by.  With EastLink being a 40-kilometre project, small amounts of rain could routinely be expected somewhere along the route but not on other sections.  Industrial practices in place before Work-Choices would have caused work to stop on the whole route.  The CityLink project was known to suffer from this problem.

Assuming that misuse of allegations of inclement weather added just 1 per cent to programmed working time, this would equate to 63,000 labour hours, delaying the project's completion by two weeks.  This would add an unknown amount in overheads, cost $9.2 million in forgone revenue and cost (say) $3.1 million in additional labour costs.

Cost differential for "bad" weather:  $12.3 million.


TOTAL COST DIFFERENTIAL

Adding all these factors together, the size of the possible cost differential between CityLink (that is, before Building Code/WorkChoices/ABCC) and EastLink (with Building Code/WorkChoices/ABCC environment) can be given a likely figure.

Non-working union delegates$58.5 million
Unproductive days$184 million
VBIA Agreement disruption$9.2 million
Sham OHS disputes$31 million
Sham weather disputes$12.3 million
Total$295 million

This figure is meant only to demonstrate how the industrial arrangements and behaviours that preceded the WorkChoices/ABCC environment adversely impacted on construction in Victoria.  The figure demonstrates a scenario applying to EastLink and the possible scale of advantage to EastLink by operating under the post-WorkChoices/ABCC environments.

The figure of $295 million could be too high or low, but on Victorian experience, is likely to be conservative.  The Cole Commission indicated that industrial behaviour and industrial agreements in Victoria pushed up the costs of construction by at least 20 per cent compared with housing construction costs.  The $295 million advantage to EastLink posited above, however, represents only 11.8 per cent of the total construction cost.  The picture painted here should, therefore, be considered at the mid-range of possible scenarios.


EASTLINK:  A TOLL-FREE POSSIBILITY?

If the EastLink scenario is combined with the projects discussed in the historical overview at the beginning of this paper, the total difference in Victorian construction costs between the pre-Building Code/WorkChoices/ABCC regime and that which replaced it would come in somewhere around the $500 million mark.

EastLink$295 million
Discussed projects$304 million
Total$599 million

This cost differential covers a six-year period and is conservative.  It only covers some major projects and does not include any medium or minor ones, such as schools, hospitals and police station construction to name just a few.

In July 2005, the Bracks Government announced that it had spent $10 billion on capital works in the previous five years and planned to spend $20 billion in the following five years.  (Media Release, Treasurer, 21 July 2005) This $30 billion of spending over a decade is significant.  Giving the scenarios contained in this briefing paper, the cost differential could quite conceivably reach well into the several billions of dollars.  Adding private-sector costs into the figure would make it much larger.

This starts to give an idea of the scale of the benefit of the Building Code/WorkChoices/ABCC reforms to the State of Victoria and to the Victorian Government.  If Eastlink had been built without tolls, the cost to the Bracks/Brumby Government would have been $1.96 billion after Federal contributions.

It is more than likely possible that if Building Code/WorkChoices/ABCC had been in place at the beginning of the Bracks/Brumby period, the net benefit to Victoria could have enabled the Bracks/Brumby Government to build EastLink as a toll-free project.

Federalism is a safer way

"Does the end justify the means?" is one of the oldest of philosophical conundrums.

The objective of Work Choices, to liberalise the labour market, is a worthy one.  It's an objective consistent with the principles of the Liberal Party and with the principles of liberal democracy itself.

The right of individuals to sell their labour under the conditions they choose is as inalienable as their right to own property (although whether the bureaucratic regime established by Work Choices actually does what is intended is debatable).

The problem is the means the Liberal Party has used to achieve its objective.

On Tuesday, when a majority of the High Court upheld the constitutional validity of Work Choices, the judges sanctioned a further body blow to federalism.

Federalism was once a principle of the Liberal Party.

Managing conflicting principles is part of the art of politics.  In the reality of the day-to-day practice of power in the corridors of Parliament House, principles come and go -- but a senate majority comes around once in a lifetime.  The temptation to take advantage of the electoral fluke of 2004 which delivered the coalition the control of the Senate was not able to be resisted by the Howard government's ministers.

Prime Minister John Howard was absolutely sincere when he said he had no desire "to embark upon some orgy of centralism" -- but others might not be so reluctant.  The statement by the federal Attorney-General, Philip Ruddock, the day after the High Court's decision was not a good omen.  He said that if the states did not regulate the legal profession the way he wanted then the Commonwealth would do it.

One of the great benefits of federalism is that it doesn't discriminate.  It imposes the same limits on all politicians, regardless of whether they are acting from the best of reasons, as Howard is, or the worst of reasons, as Gough Whitlam did.

The point that the coalition will not be in government forever has been well made in the past few days.  A government under Kim Beazley, Kevin Rudd or Julia Gillard with a sympathetic senate could undo Work Choices with the stroke of a pen.

Another thing that hasn't been lost in the discussion is the capacity of the Commonwealth to intervene in a wide array of new areas.

As Michael Kirby, one of the two dissenting judges, identified, everything from town planning to gaming is now within the purview of the Commonwealth.  He's absolutely correct when he labels this a quite "radical" outcome.  If a conservative High Court (four of the five judges in the majority were appointed by the coalition) is willing to undertake this sort of constitutional reconstruction, one can only wonder what would happen if ever the court wasn't conservative.

What's been ignored so far is the potential of the decision to produce an outcome that is the exact opposite of what Australia needs.  Instead of accelerating the process of economic and social policy reform, the High Court's decision might reverse it.

The task of reform cannot be left to just one level of government.  Any process of change works best when it is carried by a critical mass that can support and critique what is happening and that can sell the benefits of reform.

State premiers will no longer need to risk their political capital on reform if they expect the Commonwealth to bypass them anyway.  The days of a Nick Greiner or a Jeff Kennett are over.

It has been assumed that because Australia has been lucky enough to have two decades of federal Labor and then coalition governments committed to reform, we will always have national governments of this character.  This is naive in the extreme.  It's that sort of thinking that leads people to fantasise that because the stockmarket is going up it will always go up.

Tragically, just as the rest of the world is discovering the limits of standardisation and uniformity, Australia is moving in the opposite direction.  That great experiment in centralisation, the European Union, is a financial and political failure.  Meanwhile, the United States, with all of its competition and diversity, prospers.  In that country the states are getting more power, not less.

In a federation, if one level of government fails there is the opportunity for another level to fix that failure.  In Australia that chance is now gone.

After last Tuesday, the consequences of a failed federal government won't just be bad.  They'll be disastrous.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, November 17, 2006

Impact and Outcome of Regulation on the Economy

Address to the Monash Law School's Rethinking Regulation Forum
15 November 2006


MARKETS VERSUS REGULATION

REGULATION AND LAW

There are two means by which regulation is effected.  One comprises laws that simply require things be done and the other is the expenditures of governments -- the taxes and subsidies that shift activities from where they would otherwise be.  Subsidies are no less regulations than compulsive measures, since they rely on government for the funds they employ.

Both these forms of regulations differ from the fundamental role of laws which protect and define the property of individuals.  Laws that protect and define individuals' property are at the heart of the reasons for government and derive their legitimacy from common law.

In addition to these regulations are other laws, which are more akin to conventions, like driving on the left hand side of the road or agreed units of measurement.  These are best thought of as common sense measures that disadvantage nobody while facilitating interaction.  They are not normally considered as coercive and therefore not included within the costs of regulation.


REGULATION AND MARKETS

There is no longer theoretical support for the political paradigm where markets and competition play anything other than the primary role.  No respected authority nowadays maintains that state planning delivers more efficient outcomes than the interplay of producers and suppliers within competitive market conditions.  Nor is there any practical example of a society that has achieved success whilst eschewing the market economy.

Competition allied with property rights is the source of economic efficiency.  Competition forces suppliers to constantly look to market tastes and needs and to constantly review their costs out of fear that a newcomer will usurp their market position.

Regulation stops people spending their money, offering their services, building, playing and so on in the way they might otherwise choose.  It therefore must be presumed to bring reduced welfare since it diverts activities from those that people would otherwise prefer.  It means some individuals have to accept less favoured goods, services and activities than those they would have opted for thereby obtaining less pleasure per ounce of effort.

Regulation therefore confronts the Adam Smith benefit maximising process and as well presents a challenge to the liberty of the individual.  A highly restrained role of government, the only means by which regulation can be enforced, is the defining condition of this.

Even so, the application of the free market approach is heavily qualified in practice.

Markets are popularly seen as being necessary to be overridden because of three sorts of reasons:

Monopoly which allows him to profit by restricting supply below the levels that would prevail under competitive conditions

Yet in fact, cases of monopoly where products are concerned e.g. IBM, Microsoft, Standard Oil, are never likely to prevail;  the monopolist must always operate as though it is in a competitive market because a new technology or upstart is always waiting in the wings.  More problematic is the case of the "natural monopoly" like power lines, or ports or roads.

Product or work complexities which are seen as too difficult for people to make rational decisions about;  the trade-offs between risk and cost are seen as too complex and, moreover, the risk itself will mean some intolerable psychic and perhaps monetary costs imposed on the rest of the community if poor choices are made.

This has led to minimum safety standards on products, pre-reviews of safety by governments and workplace safety regulations

Externalities are the spillover costs that are imposed on third parties.

This has spawned the great array of environmental regulations.


TYPES OF REGULATION

It is useful to distinguish two types of regulation:  economic and social.

  1. Economic regulation has previously received most attention because it most blatantly flouts the rules of sound economic policy.  It is regulation of prices or access to markets, which is always likely to bring increased costs by distorting product offerings, denying the lowest cost competitors an ability to offer their services and reduce the competitive pressure on the existing suppliers.
  2. Social regulation is normally targeted at externalities;  it requires suppliers to incorporate a more comprehensive set of features in their goods and services than they might have chosen to offer (e.g. impact resistant car panels) or it may require them to build to a higher specification (e.g. low energy using refrigerators) or it may forbid certain activities (like mining in natural parks, or logging or other activities where there are thought to be endangered species present) or it may require buyers to avoid the cheapest products especially with energy in pursuit of sustainable ecological development.

DEVELOPMENTS IN REGULATORY REVIEWS

LONGER TERM TRENDS

Regulation policy like many political processes moves in waves.

Nurturing the growth of modern living standards was regulation reform founded on a critical analysis and eradication of regulations, most notably in England from the Middle Ages onwards.  The 200 years to the 1870's marked a systematic culling of laws and regulations.  Of the 18,110 Acts passed since the Thirteenth Century, over four-fifths were repealed.  The great majority of the repealed acts were constraints on competition.  Naturally, with the observed economic success of England and its Colonies, other countries followed suit.

There followed a period, which lasted up to the last thirty years or so, when socialism and statism triumphed in public policy circles.

This led to market regulation, including its ultimate form nationalisation of many industries in countries other than the US.  In Australia we had rail, buses, gas and electricity, telecommunications, shipping, insurance, banking, ports, gambling, brought under state ownership -- in some cases even excluding any rival private sector suppliers.  Other countries saw the nationalised industries extended to steel, automobiles, coal mining.

Gradually though observed productivity levels demonstrated the greater efficiency of private ownership and of industries with competitive entry.

The push for deregulation was initiated in the US in the 1970s.  Its greatest early focus was on the economic regulations rather than the social regulations that were even then increasing rapidly.

In Australia, the enthronement of deregulation remarkably came from a Labor Government, most of the members of which had railed against the inefficiencies and inequities of capitalism for a great deal of their public lives.  Prime Minister Hawke, kicked the ball off in addressing the Business Council of Australia in September 1984 with a strong deregulatory message -- perhaps the clearest such signal previously given by an incumbent Government in Australia.

Chart 1:  Pages of Legislation and Regulations Passed:
Commonwealth vs States, 1962-2004Source:  Annual publications of statutues and subordinate legislation.  Pages of legislation and regulations for some years in some jurisdictions based on estimates.  Does not include legislation or regulations from the Northern Territory or the Australian Capital Territory, and does not include regulations for South Australia or Western Australia.

Since then as the Banks Committee into Rethinking Regulation has observed there have been 20 reports on the issue, with less than spectacular outcomes.  There are many ways of measuring this, all imperfect but it seems a development towards increased regulatory control is a rarely challenged finding.  Chart 1 is the measure of annual new pages of legislation, very little of which is actually repealing extant regulation.


RECENT REGULATION REVIEW ARRANGEMENTS

Concern about regulatory excesses in the 1980s led to further reviews of "competition policy", particularly with the 1993 Hilmer Report.  The report formed the basis for National Competition Policy, the key measures of which were:

  1. government owned businesses which compete with the private sector now enjoy no special advantages and suffer no disadvantages as a result of public ownership ("competitive neutrality")
  2. public monopolies were reformed, with their commercial and regulatory functions separated and their pricing policies subject to oversight
  3. all regulations which restrict competition were to be reviewed in order to determine whether regulation delivers a net benefit to the community.

Outcomes have been a substantial freeing up of regulatory restraints on competition in airlines, ports, electricity and gas, rail, and telecommunications.  This has been accompanied by a deal of re-regulation in what has been over-ambitiously defined as the "essential service" components.  But the net result has been positive.

National competition reforms extended the work of the Productivity Commission, which was largely directed at tariffs.  Gradually governments have come to accept the benefits of lower levels of protection.  Twenty five years ago, tariff protection in Australia was the highest in the OECD area today it has been reduced to the average 3 per cent or so seen in most other mature economies.

The ORR within the PC has been useful in highlighting problems with regulation.  At the state level, Victoria has brought in some ostensibly strong regulatory oversight arrangements in the form of the Competition and Efficiency Commission.  This has strong powers to assess new regulations and is being given commissions by the government to review wide areas of existing regulation.  Although the new Commission failed its initial test -- the government allowed new regulations favouring renewable energy -- it may yet breathe more power into regulatory downsizing.  The Victorian Government has set itself a target of reducing regulation by 15 per cent over three years and by 25 per cent over a longer period.  It has also apparently committed to a one-in-one-out regulatory rule.

In this respect, with the reduction of economic regulation, State governments are more significant since their role tends to be greater in social regulations.  NSW is about to implement some more rigour in regulation review following the report by IPART.


BENEFITS OF ECONOMIC DEREGULATION

Australia's deregulatory flourish, with all its shortcomings, has been accompanied by a vast increase in economic growth.  From being one of the laggards in the Western world from 1972 to 1990, the Australian economy has been transformed to be the second highest growth rate of the mature economies.

In the case of the deregulated industries, massive gains have been seen.

For electricity and gas this is readily estimated.  Electricity generation for example has seen labour productivity more than double.  In some states the increase has been even greater five and three and a half fold respectively in the privatised Victorian and South Australian systems.  (Chart 2)

Chart 2:  Generator Labour Productivity:  GWh / employee

At the same time, notwithstanding the fewer people they now employ, the power stations have improved their availability to generate, as can be seen in Chart 3.

Chart 3:  Power stations availability to run

Chart 4:  Container terminal productivity

Prices have remained low by world standards.  On average in Australia prices to household consumers are only one third of those seen in the more expensive countries like Japan and Germany and are similar to those of Canada (US prices on average are about 30 per cent higher).

The sorts of productivity increases seen in electricity as a result of deregulation, including labour market reforms are seen in other industries.  One notoriously inefficient Australian industry has historically been the wharves.  Chocker block with Johnny Friendly union types and having the romantic image of the tough working guy, together with a great deal of monopoly power, reform of the ports was particularly difficult in Australia and was only achieved in the teeth of a bitter and lengthy strike during the course of which union power was smashed.

Port movement rates are well documented throughout the world in terms of TEUs based on 20 foot container equivalents.  Notwithstanding considerable government blandishments and employment buy-outs, this level was under 20 per hour in 1992, whereas rates of 30 per hour were seen in the most efficient ports in our region.  The TEU rate actually fell over the course of the next few years.

According to left wing think tanks, "(Federal Minister) Reith's dream of a 25 container per hour average across Australian ports is probably technically impossible." In fact the average rate exceeded 28 in the June quarter 2004.

The productivity rates are illustrated.

In terms of costs this has brought a real reduction of over 25 per cent.


NEW AREAS OF REGULATION

The deregulatory reforms have been confined to "economic" regulation.

What remains of this type of regulation is rump of price controls over "essential facilities" and the growing array of social regulations to protect the environment, workplace safety, and consumers.


ESSENTIAL FACILITIES

The most entrenched monopolies–perhaps the only ones with durability–are those supported by government.  The central purpose of the Australian competition reforms was to smash these.  In part, this meant hiving off the clearly contestable areas (e.g. generation of electricity).  What is left is a set of residual apparent monopolies covering wires, pipes, ports and roads.  Most of the recent policy debate has focused on the price and access conditions.

With perfect knowledge, the wise and incorruptible bureaucrat could devise a transmission system that would prevent monopolistic waste and could also bring about a great many of the dynamic gains achieved with commercial rivalry.  However, these conditions are not present.  Producers and carriers will be reluctant to reveal to competitors and customers alike the extent of their costs;  and they too have imperfect knowledge of these.  Buyers will seek to keep options open to the maximum degree, and will not reveal the full extent of their demand, their alternative means of having it supplied and their preferred means of supply.

Requiring private firms to provide access to competitors or others will diminish their incentive to build a facility or will distort the nature of that facility if built.

Control over essential facilities has brought considerably more regulatory intrusion than had been envisaged.  At the time of the competition reforms the term "light handed" was in universal use.  This has not been the outcome.

In electricity lines, telecoms and elsewhere, the regulatory authorities have been pre-occupied with preventing monopolistic gouging.  This has led to extraordinary complex submissions being required, highly legalistic appeals of decisions and so on.

Although the ACCC argues to the contrary, the Productivity Commission found that the regulatory conditions were preventing investment in gas pipelines.  Any new gas pipelines constructed under the present regime where open access is required and prices are determined by a regulator have incorporated costly inefficiencies to avoid regulatory control.  The SEAGAS pipeline delivering Bass Strait gas to Adelaide for example is deliberately sized to avoid any spare capacity which non-participants in the ownership could use to recruit the ACCC to require access be given at a price not acceptable to the participants.  This is a clear economic waste as designing in spare capacity can be achieved at a low cost.

Similar adverse outcomes can be seen as stemming from the regulatory control over the Dampier to Bunbury natural Gas Pipeline.  The regulator's insistence of a price that the owner, Epic Energy, considered too low led to its bankruptcy.  In addition, the low price made it uneconomic for Epic to expand capacity, an outcome of which was shortage of gas to allow increased electricity capacity with resulting black-outs.

Issues have arisen with other controls over essential facilities.  One which became highly topical at the start of 2005 was Queensland's Dalrymple Bay Coal Terminal.  This is regulated by the Queensland Competition Authority which set a charge of $1.53 per tonne in a draft decision compared to the current rate of $2.08 per tonne.  The facility's owner, Prime, decided that it would be unprofitable to expand capacity with the result that the port is unable to cope with increased demand.

Similar restraints on the dominant telecommunications carrier, Telstra, threaten to constrain investment in that sector as well.  Indeed, as a result of being unable to enjoy exclusive rights to new investments, Telstra has abandoned its fibre-to-the-node roll out.  In addition, to avoid having its ADSL2+ assets declared an "essential service" Telstra is carefully ensuring its roll out only covers areas already serviced by competitors ADSL2+ networks.

Litigation under Part IIIA to force BHP and Rio to open their Pilbara rail lines to third parties is being pursued by the NCC.  This is preventing the businesses from augmenting their systems to meet the expanding Chinese demand.

The Productivity Commission has been a useful counterweight to the ambitions of the regulators to maintain control.  It recommended, against their advice, the deregulation of airports which the government accepted (the monopoly features of airports comprising landing charges account for only 10-15 per cent of their revenues and can be left to negotiation given the powerful players involved).  Similarly, and in association with the analysis undertaken by the appeal body to the ACCC, the Trade Practices Tribunal, the regulatory controls on gas pipelines have been pinned back somewhat.


THE HOUSE BUILDING INDUSTRY

Land Availability

The open nature of the Australian housing market and its network of extensive sub-contractors has served the consumer well over the years and clearly contributed to low prices, especially compared with the heavily unionised commercial building sector.

But house/land prices have risen massively over the past year or so.  Since 1973, houses have kept pace with inflation but land has outpaced average prices by four to eightfold.

The price of the land itself is a trivial component of the overall cost of housing -- less than $500 per block.  To actually provide land for development with the roads, sewerage levelled blocks and so on costs between $35,000 and $60,000.  Land for this purpose is almost infinitely available -- urban areas are only 0.3 per cent of Australia's land area.

A sufficient and flexible supply of land can alleviate demand pressures as evidenced by the experience of South East Queensland during the mid-1990s.  A Rapid increase in the demand for housing due to inter-state migration was accompanied by a supply response possible due to the availability of land.  The net result was a major jump in new housing activity with little pressure on prices either in the new or established housing markets, especially on the urban fringe.

Regulation therefore imposes an additional cost on housing of between $50,000 and $300,000 per block and represents a massive transfer of wealth from the have-nots to the haves, from those without homes to those with homes who are benefiting from the regulatory induced shortage and consequent price inflation.


Building Costs

Regulators are also doing their utmost to increase building costs in other ways.  A favourite nowadays is a greenhouse inspired set of requirements for energy and water saving devices on new houses.  NSW has an array of measures that must be incorporated into new houses and which involve the unfortunate new home buyer with unwanted costs.  In Victoria, similar such measures were introduced with the Plumbing (Water and Energy Savings) Regulations 2004.  Under these regulations, people buying new houses must install low pressure water valves.  In addition, they have a choice of installing a 2000 litre rainwater tank or a solar heating system.

Often these regulations are introduced alongside phony Regulation Impact Statements (RIS).  That in Victoria for the Five Star Energy regulations cited (but failed to quantify) savings from reduced greenhouse gas emissions.  It made no attempt to quantify the reductions in consumer satisfaction that the RIS admits will result from the implementation of the proposals, or to acknowledge them via a sophisticated integration of quantitative and qualitative elements.  In addition it relied on Keynesian multiplier effects (e.g. increases in employment, gross state product etc) to reach its conclusions, when these "benefits" are not accepted as a legitimate element of economic and/or cost/benefit analysis by a great many experts.  The increased activity from regulatory forcings was considered as a benefit, whereas in fact such measures merely involve a transfer of expenditure into areas that would not be preferred absent the regulatory coercion.

The new home buyers' best regulatory choice, solar heating, involves an up-front outlay of $2000.  This is for an unreliable energy supply that costs three times as much as conventionally generated electricity.

Hopefully, the Victorian Competition and Efficiency Commission's inquiry into building rules will be the prelude to a much needed bonfire of these regulatory measures, and will flow on to other states.

There are other disturbing increases in regulation and evidence of regulatory barriers being erected to new competition.

In New South Wales, builders are now required to ensure that all power tools used on a building site are checked for safety by a qualified electrician every three months.  It is hardly necessary to have expensive checks on 50 or more tools, some of which are used only once a year.  It is even more doubtful that "tools" like portable radios and the kettle for morning tea should be as regularly and rigorously tested as heavy equipment.  The home buyer pays for this nonsense.

Builders are supposed to meet every visiting contractor on site and discuss their work practices with them, no matter how experienced the tradesperson or how simple the job to be done.  Builders and site managers are even expected to be responsible for ensuring their workers protect themselves against the sun.

Chart 5:  New Land and House Package Costs

1973198319932006Price Increase Multiple 1973 to 2006
Sydney
Land$9,100$29,400$107,100$460,60049.6
House$18,900$43,200$121,500$128,2505.8
Melbourne
Land$6,900$15,800$49,000$107,00014.5
House$14,000$35,000$75,000$112,0007.0
Brisbane
Land$7,000$27,000$60,000$135,00018.3
House$16,000$37,000$70,000$112,0006.0
Perth
Land$6,500$17,300$80,974$270,00040.5
House$12,000$28,000$60,000$109,0008.1
Adelaide
Land$2,000$12,000$35,000$140,00069.0
House$12,000$20,000$40,000$90,0006.5
CPI20.561.6108.9150.66.3

Barriers to Entry

Other measures have been taken that will adversely impact on house prices.  In the main these have been the result of regulatory "capture" and a symbiosis between regulators and the occupations they control.

In the past, the house builder was normally a tradesman who gained sufficiently wide experience to take on a management role in the project.  The system of sub-contracting greatly facilitated this.

More recently there has been a rise in credentialism.  Unlike in the past, builders now have to take written tests and demonstrate to the authorities a knowledge of the system that have not proved to be necessary in the past.  One outcome has been an increase in people purporting to be "owner-builders" to escape the regulatory restraint.

This is turn has led to a vast expansion in the so-called owner builder applications which accounted for 37 per cent of building permit applications in Victoria last year.  One facet of this has been the considerable limitations on the ability of an owner-builder to construct new houses and major extensions.  As a result, provisions have been introduced in Queensland, NSW and recently in Victoria that are targeted against the owner-builder.  In some cases they require the would-be owner-builder to attend a completely useless building course to force up the regulatory costs of opting for this method of building.  These provisions have no effect in terms of the safety or functionality of the work (mandatory insurance is necessary in any case and there is no evidence that owner builder work is any less satisfactory than that built by registered builders).  In fact, owner-builders are based on the same sub-contracting principles that prevail throughout the industry -- no owner builder actually lays the bricks or installs the roof trusses.


Regulation of Access to Buildings

An example of regulations that are motivated by the best of intentions concerns those under consideration to improve access into commercial buildings for people with handicaps.  The proposals involve hundreds of additional requirements covering matters ranging from access ramps to hotel swimming pools passing space and installation of wheelchair friendly lifts.

The estimated building cost increases due to the implementation of the proposed standard of around $1.5 billion annually.  The annual value of all new non-residential building approved is around $15 billion with a further $8 billion in alterations and extensions.  It was estimated that the regulatory costs would add nearly 5 per cent to the cost of new buildings and over 10 per cent to the costs of upgrades for existing buildings which would need retro-fitment and see some loss of usable space.

In addition there would be costs stemming from the change in the nature of buildings constructed.  For example, the cost impact is greatest on smaller offices and shops since the adaptations required of the regulations are more easily spread across larger building structures.  This would mean a work and shopping environment less well suited to business and consumer needs.  It is also likely to lead to premature scrapping of existing building which is more expensive to convert than building from scratch.  And the higher costs that need to be passed on to customers would bring an overall reduction in building activity.

Nor is it clear that the outcome will bring an increase in employment of those with disabilities.  Analyses undertaken of the Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA), which was passed in 1990 and is the blueprint for Australian proposals has seen a drop in the number of individuals with disabilities employed to 29 per cent in 1998 compared with 34 per cent in 1986.

Improving the access of disabled persons is a regulatory proposal with seemingly innocuous costs and targeted at relieving the discomfort and improving the work prospects of a highly meritorious group of people within society.  Yet a careful analysis of the costs shows them to be far in excess of what most would regard as being reasonable, while an empirical analysis of the outcomes of similar regulation elsewhere indicates that the positive impacts envisaged are not easy to achieve.


AGRICULTURE AND FARM REGULATIONS

Regulatory framework for innovative food crop technology

The use of modern genetic technology to develop better crop varieties is recognised globally as a dynamic current area of technological innovation.  The total land area sown to new genetically modified (GM) crops developed from biotechnology continues to expand globally.

Nevertheless, State Governments have banned the commercialisation of GM varieties that had previously passed stringent Federal government regulatory requirements to assure they pose no risks to the environment or to human health.  The technology allows a marked reduction in the use of fertilizers and weed control chemicals as well as reduced labour use in the application of these chemicals.

These prohibitions and the long time lags in plant variety improvement mean that genetic technology used already for ten years by Australia's international trade competitors including in Canada and Argentina are denied Australian farmers.  The competitiveness of the industries themselves and of those that use the products in food and other agricultural processing is impeded by the measures.  In addition, Australian consumers will fail to gain the benefits of the lower prices that will emerge from the lower costs.

Moreover, as a result of this legislation and of the political risks posed towards plant biotechnology, some innovative plant breeding research groups have now been disbanded.  This poses a longer term threat to the industry remaining ate the technological cutting edge where it needs to be to fulfil government and industry aspirations for agriculture and agricultural processing.


Regulatory "Takings" in water

Much of agriculture in Australia is generally on irrigation, especially in the Murray Darling Basin which contributes some 40 per cent to Australian.

Regulatory takings of water in pursuit of ill-founded but oft-repeated claims that water is needed to remedy environmental degradation are likely to have significantly impact economically on rural Australia while delivering little if any environmental benefit.  Nonetheless, prompted by militant green NGOs, governments are attempting to take water allocations back from farmers.

Farmers need to have confidence about fair play with future decisions.  Irrespective of the merits of the water allocation decisions and water rights acquisitions that have taken place over the past century or more, the status quo of de facto rights needs to be the starting point of any reformed system.


Native vegetation

Legislation on flora and fauna is similar in most Australian States, and prevents clearance of native vegetation.  Specific issues are many.

Among these is an inconsistency in application.  The reason is that regulations are devised at a high policy level and administered by local authorities, case by case, often by unqualified staff with no means of cross checking.  Moreover, officials often have little experience in or knowledge of the pressures and requirements of practical farming.  This is not helped when the Government changes the rules to reverse particular cases such as novel restrictions which have been on vermin control activity.

Provisions for compensation are either non-existent or inadequate where decisions are made that affect the income-earning capacity or capital value of assets.  Such provision places a valuable discipline on government.

Because the rules are more stick than carrot, there are powerful incentives for landowners to undermine the purpose of the regulations.  This is reinforced by the increasingly popular but farcical requirement for Net Gain of native vegetation cover whenever an application to clear is made.  This principle inappropriately values native vegetation as an absolute good.  The results are predictable:

  1. Many sound, beneficial clearing proposals are not put forward as the costs of regulation exceed the benefits to the farmer.
  2. Farmers tend to favour exotic species in tree planting to avoid future reservation for environmental purposes.
  3. New native forestry activities are discouraged for the same reason.
  4. Rare and endangered species of vegetation are concealed to avoid quarantining of productive land.
  5. Poor management practices (overgrazing of native vegetation) are encouraged in an effort to circumvent the restrictions.

ESTIMATING THE OVERALL COSTS OF REGULATION

In many ways regulation in Australia is less intrusive than in many other successful economies.  Indeed, a recent World Bank analysis placed Australia as having the world's least intensive regulatory environment for starting a new business.  Such measures, while useful are only partial and cannot incorporate all the facets of regulation that confront businesses.

Nobody seems able to come to grips with the total national expenditure on regulation in Australia.  It is especially difficult to estimate the impacts of local rules and ordinances that impose massive indirect costs on farmers, miners and individual householders who want to build an extension or carport.

We do have regulatory review bodies, especially in Victoria and the Commonwealth that are trying to assemble compilations of the total number of regulations.  From this the agencies will be able to move over time to estimating the change in regulatory intrusion and perhaps put some reasonable costs on the imposts.  At present however, we have to rely on less direct measures.

Some estimates of the costs of US federal regulation have been made over a great many years by the Office of Management and Budget.  For the latest year the gross cost was estimated at around 8 per cent of GDP.

Analyses of the cost of regulation in Canada and Mexico have shown comparable (though slightly lower) levels of costs as a share of GDP to those estimated for the US.  Hence measures of the total cost of regulations in an economy like Australia's is likely to amount to around the 8-9 per cent of GDP seen in similar economies.  Of course, regulation that more comprehensively stifles the market, as in the former Communist countries, has a far greater effect and brought GDP levels to only one third of those that might have prevailed.


CONCLUDING COMMENTS

There are disciplines that should be in place to ensure regulation is carefully considered and that a regulation once in place is neither the foothill for a new regulatory empire, nor even something that remains indefinitely.

On past evidence, these disciplines have not had much effect, at least on the overall level of regulation.  It does seem very difficult to staunch the increase in social regulation.  Risk aversion and a feeling on the part of most people that the direct impacts will be trivial contribute to this.  Among the most pressing areas of new regulation is greenhouse with almost all academics and many politicians telling us we need to do more.  One sobering aspect of the debate, which intensified with the recent release of the UK Stern Report, is that it comes on the heels of calls for insulating the Australian petrol market from world trends.  Popular demand for action in one area often confronts the reality of implications elsewhere.

There are now increasing requirements for reviews prior to introduction of new regulations and for sunsetting.  It does seem that these regimes are being increasingly taken seriously -- bureaucrats and politicians no longer argue that the market is faulty whenever it fails to accord with their expectations but the momentum especially for regulations with an environmental rationale is clearly very strong.  The following are some recommendations that should be required prior to new regulations being introduced:

  1. Require a review to ensure the new regulation is fully consistent with the letter and spirit of the freedom of inter-state commerce provisions of the Constitution
  2. Introduce the regulation under a two stage process approach:  the first simply setting out the issues in a dispassionate and non-committal, manner and the second seeking comment on the agency's preferred approach.
  3. Require an independent analysis to verify that the regulation is merited.  This might be a scientific review in the case of measures mooted that guard against health or environmental externalities.  And it may use formalised and independent economic analysis to review alleged economic benefits from an externality.
  4. Establish disciplines that ensure the regulatory burden does not increase.  In this respect a useful approach would be that of the UK Prime Minister's direction to the Better Regulation Task Force to look at:
    • First measuring the administrative burden then setting a target to reduce them (the Dutch approach) and
    • A "one in, one out" approach to new regulation, which forces a prioritisation of regulation and its simplification and removal.

The Commonwealth Government has announced in response to the Rethinking Regulation report that it is stiffening its regulatory control procedures.  New regulations as well as existing ones almost certainly add more costs than benefits.  Measures that place impediments to their promulgation or facilitate their repeal should all be considered.

But if anyone thinks that it will be easy to put the brakes on regulation growth, just reflect on the NSW Government.  On the day they released their IPART report on reducing the regulatory burden, they announced a new set of proposals to up the renewable energy burden on the state from 10 per cent of the total to 15 per cent.  Gilding the lily they employed consultants to say the program would cost a trivial sum and the consultants even propose IPART as its regulator.