Friday, November 22, 2002

Natural gas in Australia after the "Hilmer revolution"

Energy Forum Papers

SUMMARY (1)

CURRENT COMPETITIVE FRAMEWORK

Prior to the Hilmer reforms, (2) long distance gas transmission pipelines were exclusive franchises and therefore (legislated) monopolies.  Policy developments stemming from the 1993 Hilmer Report eliminated monopoly provision thereby changing the framework underpinning the way Australia's gas and electricity industries operate.

Gas transmission is now regulated under the National Third Party Access Code for Natural Gas Pipeline Systems (the National Gas Code).  The National Competition Council (NCC) normally determines whether a pipeline should be covered by the National Gas Code with the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) determining the terms under which a covered pipeline operates.  Gas access may alternatively be regulated by the ACCC accepting an undertaking by the pipeline under Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act.


APPROPRIATE REGULATORY COVERAGE AND PRACTICE

National issues

Regulatory coverage seeks to prevent monopoly exploitation by an enterprise.  But, in replacing private control this will impact adversely on operational efficiency and incentives for efficient investment.  Regulation is most effective where it is designed to achieve the efficiency inherent in privately owned competitive network facilities.

To avoid discouraging new investment, the regulator should not require prices on existing pipelines to be set below, or services above, the levels consumers would be prepared to pay in a competitive market.  Successful innovative and uncertain investments commonly earn a risk premium above "normal" profits.  The regulator should include such a premium in the prices set for a firm -- even one that is well established -- that has pioneered markets that were previously unserved.  The ACCC, however, generally sets regulated prices at levels that offer inadequate recompense for costs and risk.

For new pipelines built without government protection or other favours, there is little basis for regulatory controls.  These pipelines, by definition, start with no monopoly and users are free to seek out the pipeline links that offer the best terms.  If provision is made for an asset built under such circumstances to become a regulated "essential facility", at some future time, the provision should be restricted to specific circumstances, and should be under constant review.

Furthermore, natural gas pipelines that pre-dated the Hilmer reform era are increasingly experiencing some competitive pressures since the removal of their franchise protection.  These pressures require revocation of the regulatory coverage of some pipelines.  Failure to revoke coverage where there is workable competition can seriously impede competitive development.  Where the regulation sets prices too low, this leads to inefficient imposts on pipelines and unsustainable subsidies to customers.


Victorian issues

Victoria is the major gas using state other than Western Australia.  The state's "market carriage" system for gas presents an additional regulatory matter.  Victoria's network involves the Government-owned VENCorp controlling pipelines and no user-rights to a specific capacity.  Most other pipelines are "contract" carriage under the pipeline owners' control with the capacity allocated to users.

The Victorian "market carriage" system offers too little incentive for the pipeliner to implement improvements and insufficient certainty for users.  It should be converted to a contract carriage system.

The present regulatory structure also has some anomalies with respect to gas and electricity.  For example, price caps are not presently aligned in Victoria.  To avoid distorting investment decisions between the two energy sources, the gas price cap (the Value of Lost Load) should be set at a similar level to that of electricity.

In addition, electricity transmission price regulation is based on a revenue cap, while that of gas is based on a price cap.  The latter is more efficient because it does not discourage efficient use.  Electricity price setting methodologies should be aligned with those of gas.


INTRODUCTION

REGULATION'S ROLE IN THE GAS INDUSTRY

As with electricity, gas is best analysed as comprising four elements:

  • supply of gas (which unlike electricity might include storage),
  • transmission along high pressure pipes,
  • local distribution, and
  • retailing.

Of the four elements of gas supply, distribution alone is an uncontestable natural monopoly.  For the other elements control is normally best left to commercial market forces.

Once in situ a local network is unchallengeable except from alternative fuels.  Although there are occasional examples of a rival duplicating an incumbent's distribution network, this is unusual and probably socially wasteful.  It would also be possible to avoid regulation of distribution if users signed long term contracts with the pipeline but this will be impracticable with highly dispersed household usage.  Some form of regulation of distribution is, therefore, probably inevitable.

While transmission and production might also have monopoly features, these are likely to be far less persistent than with distribution.  New sources of gas supply will usually be found if prices are attractive.  With transmission, rival networks can be built to contest an incumbent's market.  Such a possibility is, of course, reduced to the extent that regulation is in place and brings prices lower than those that would otherwise prevail.  Gas supply and transmission are also different from distribution in that their development decisions and final customers involve commercial parties capable of contracting with each other for long periods.

In general, Australian governments have not sought to be major suppliers of gas ex-mine.  Long term contracts with gas producers have been signed by government agencies.  There have been pressures to renegotiate those contracts (including by the competition authorities seeking to force consortia to have their different firms market separately).  However, governments have, quite rightly, been reluctant to break contracts, even those of long standing.

Transmission pipelines have been at the heart of recent policy concerns.  They have been a focus of changed sentiments on the nature of natural monopoly and whether any regulation is required in some cases.


THE 1994 COAG DECISIONS

In 1994, the Council of Australian Governments (CoAG) agreed to "free and fair" trade in natural gas both intra-and inter-state.  Part of this involved an agreement to create no additional exclusive franchises for retail, distribution and transmission and to make existing franchise arrangements more competitive.  Government sanctioned franchises were seen to be bringing inadequate incentives for pipelines to operate efficiently and to develop.  The monopoly status they created also gave rise to the need for considerable regulatory intrusion to prevent abuse.

However, particularly with those franchises owned by government, there was too little restraint on monopolistic abuse prior to 1994 and prices were high.  Even so, the taxpayer, as owner of those pipelines failed to benefit from this.  Instead, the excessive revenues from monopoly prices tended to be dissipated in excessive manning levels and other operational inefficiencies.  Hence, in the case of the Victorian system, privatisation brought a net increase in government revenue.  The private sector bidders were able to spot opportunities for saving costs and their bids reflected this, allowing the government to save more on debt retirement than it lost in net revenues foregone from its gas business.

The CoAG decision followed from the Hilmer Committee recommendations.  The impetus for and recommendations of the Hilmer report stemmed from a need to redress the competitive restraining effects of state government owned or controlled monopolies that were bottleneck "essential facilities" infrastructure.  The report made specific mention of gas transmission pipelines

Although Hilmer discussed wide notions of "essential facilities" where regulation could be contemplated, the authors were, "conscious of the need to carefully limit the circumstances in which one business is required by law to make its facilities available to another." (p.250).  The Hilmer Report returned many times to emphasise the need to avoid undermining property rights and, hence, investment incentives, (e.g. p.256, 258).  The Hilmer report and its consequent legislation sought to ensure the regulated aspects of these services were confined to the core "essential facilities".

With regard to the rationale for regulatory coverage, Hilmer said "While it is difficult to define precisely the nature of the facilities and industries likely to meet these requirements, a frequent feature is the traditional involvement of government in these industries, either as owner or extensive regulator".  In short, in Australia in the early 1990s the only "essential facilities" were government owned or those businesses which enjoyed government support or protection from competition

The 1994 CoAG approach reversed previous practice under which gas pipelines were either exclusively owned by governments or were only permitted to operate with government approval.  The previous approach had seen the need to vest exclusive control over a market to a single pipeline.  This was based on the notion that there might otherwise be unnecessary duplication and therefore risks that investment returns might be harmed.  Under the previous approach, the transmission pipeline and distribution businesses were affiliated and prices were controlled either directly where the government owned the businesses, or indirectly where it franchised the activity.

The new policy approach was designed to make the gas industry more responsive to demand and to introduce greater entrepreneurship, risk taking and therefore innovation on the part of pipeliners.

While clear improvements in gas supply, operational efficiencies and prices have followed, the conditions giving rise to the new policy have not stood still.  Partly due to the reforms introduced, transmission pipelines have become subject to greater competitive forces and the need for their regulation is passing -- and at least in the case of eastern NSW -- has passed.


CONTINUED IMPEDIMENTS PREVENTING
MARKETS FROM OPERATING

REGULATIONS INCONSISTENT WITH EFFICIENCY

The decision to replace the regulated approach with a more entrepreneurial solution meant that gas pipelines, like motor vehicle plants, would have no automatic rights to a particular market.  Nor would a gas source be immune from competition.

Once the integrated and protected franchise model was abandoned, the industry required a framework for its on-going development.  Where this entailed opening up previous monopolies, the new framework had a clear public benefit.

However, the present framework has been developed on an ad hoc basis with often contradictory elements.  The more important features causing this development to be flawed have been:

  • the extremely high hurdles that the regulatory authorities have established with regard to the number of competitors required before they allow unregulated markets to operate.  These hurdles would prevent almost any pipeline from being regarded as sufficiently disciplined by competition to allow for a withdrawal of regulatory control;
  • a National Gas Code that is heavily weighted towards the assumption of the need for regulation with such features as a queuing policy (a role which price performs in the economy generally) and a very prescriptive cost-based guide to pricing which takes no account of market risk;
  • a transmission system in Victoria, the largest market, under which firm carriage cannot be arranged and which therefore introduces undue risk to actual and potential gas customers and insufficient incentive for pipeline companies to expand their pipelines or implement cost savings;
  • transmission price regulation for electricity based on a revenue rather than price cap that encourages energy conservation rather than efficient use of energy and incompatibilities with price cap regulation;
  • inconsistent price ceiling levels for gas and electricity.

Price setting criteria have been perhaps the most contentious.  These criteria have largely entailed questions about whether the authorities were establishing price settings that were too low, thereby offering inadequate returns and reducing the motivation to build new and enhanced facilities.


UNNECESSARY REGULATORY COVERAGE OF PIPELINES

Coverage of existing pipelines

The new arrangements included a requirement for the National Competition Council to determine whether a pipeline should be designated as covered (i.e. regulated) by the National Gas Code.  All such covered pipelines, unless they have no capacity for sale to non-affiliates, are required to have their rates approved by the ACCC.

There are inherent difficulties in estimating a synthetic price.  These aside, having a government agency specify the terms and conditions under which the pipeline may offer their services is asymmetrical between suppliers and customers.

This is because the essence of Australian regulation is to ensure productivity gains are reaped by customers rather than suppliers.  Regulation of existing pipelines with de facto natural monopoly is designed to pass along savings in improved productivity in lower prices.  These savings would automatically flow through to customers under perfect competition.  Even under the less stylised form of competition actually prevalent in most markets, only where firms maintained genuine innovatory gaps over their competitors would they tend to retain the "surplus" profits.

The customers of transmission pipelines are wholesalers or major users, and in both cases are capable of developing contracts to protect their interests.  They face every advantage where the price they pay for pipeline services cannot be increased since the regulators aim is to hand back to customers cost savings the pipeline makes.  Those without contracts -- new customers -- can simply refuse to buy if the terms are onerous.  Commonly, new customers have locational choices.

Hence, regulatory imperfections will almost certainly mean terms and conditions disadvantageous to the pipeliner, since it is impracticable to impose disadvantageous terms and conditions on most transmission pipeline customers, whereas the pipeliner has its costs sunk.

Regulation of profits is designed for situations where the monopolist would otherwise restrict output to ensure prices in excess of long run marginal costs.  However this definition of monopoly behaviour is less useful for markets where marginal costs are low.  It might, for example, justify a forced price reduction on pay-tv services, the outcome of which would be a severe reduction in any such new investment that entailed high fixed costs.

In the case of gas pipelines, the issue is not usually one of restricting output.  Rather it is about setting the prices of output that is either fixed or where demand is not influenced by its price. (3)  Indeed, regulated pipelines are required to have a queuing policy to ration access rather than using price for this.  The risk, in such circumstances, is that the regulator may set prices too low in the knowledge that adverse implications in terms of reduced incentives to invest will be long term rather than immediate.

Since the implementation of the National Gas Code, a number of decisions made by the ACCC and other regulators have forced pipeline owners to accept prices that are lower than those that would have been voluntarily entered into by the interested parties in the market-place.  GasNet is the latest of those, with the ACCC setting a WACC return about 20 per cent below that sought by the company as well as reducing the company's allowable capital expenditure.

Setting inappropriately low prices will bring reduced incentives to maintain and upgrade existing pipelines.  Perhaps more importantly, this will discourage investment in new pipelines.  Indeed, some pipeline investors have made public statements that they will not invest further in the industry.


Coverage of new pipelines

Requiring new pipelines to be regulated is gratuitous and contrary to efficiency.  New pipelines enjoy no exclusivity and by definition have no franchise or monopoly.  For gas suppliers and customers they can only bring benefits.  Unless or until a facility can be regarded as "essential", regulating it will impede its development and any redistributive changes the regulation might bring would not compensate for the reduced level of efficiency that regulation entails.  The new pipeline competes for customers in the same way as all other goods and services and has no lien on the consumer dollar.

While there is a case for pipelines originally built under franchise protection remaining under regulatory control until new competition emerges, this is not so with the post 1994 era pipelines.  Post 1994 era pipeline developers rely on market discovery and business acumen to profitably meet consumer needs, just like entrepreneurs contemplating any other investment.  Setting more onerous terms for new pipeline developments will bring sub-optimal levels of capital expenditure on them.

That said, like other "essential facilities" through the ages, pipelines that have achieved a monopoly position, whether or not they were originally franchised, can be expected to be opened for general use, implicitly on terms that they might not have chosen for themselves.  This was the case with ports in the seventeenth century and with railways from the mid 1840s. (4)  It is also the case with patents granted to new inventors.

Accordingly, it might be argued that at some stage a pipeline which was developed entrepreneurially in a competitive environment can become an "essential facility" requiring it to offer its services to all-comers.  However at the outset this cannot be the case:  the facility cannot be "essential" when life went on satisfactorily prior to its existence.


Withdrawal of coverage

The issue of when adequate competition is in place is a vexed one.  Clearly a multitude of competitors offers the best insurance against monopolistic price gouging, and US authorities generally regard five suppliers of similar size to be adequate to ensure no such power exists.

Nonetheless, robust competition can persist and perhaps continue indefinitely with even two competitors, especially if the competitive framework is one where other products or services offer some useful substitution or could rapidly enter the market.  Such monopolies exist in the case of Coke versus Pepsi, Boeing versus Airbus or even Qantas versus Virgin.  Even a single supplier can be sufficient.  The latter case occurs with the Microsoft operating system where its monopoly position is muted by the possibility of newcomers like Linux and by the competition it faces from previous sales of earlier versions of its software.

None of this is to deny the better outcomes that normally emerge when there are competitive offerings.  Moreover, the difficulties of customer "lock-in" that are the reason behind the "essential facility" concept are greater with reticulated gas and electricity than is the case with some of the other goods and service experiencing monopoly or duopoly.

Hence, it may be that at some future time a purely entrepreneurial facility may appropriately be redesignated as "essential" should no rivals emerge.  But even if a pipeline were to become regarded as "essential" and subject to regulation, this is likely to be transitory.

In this respect it is worth bearing in mind that facilities like the seventeenth century ports and nineteenth century railways, after having been "declared" and subject to regulation, eventually experienced changed competitive circumstances.  In some cases, the on-going regulation designed to promote fairness actually caused the bankruptcy of the regulated assets' owners.  The regulations remained in place in spite of the emergence of rival means of supplying their markets and seriously impeded their managements' abilities to respond to the different competitive situations.

The experience of railway regulation illustrates the need for the authorities to stand ready to remove facilities from regulatory control where competition emerges.  Judgements are required about whether or when to regulate a pipeline, and the law has to recognise that many pipelines will not achieve the monopolistic power that would warrant their regulation.  They will face actual or potential competition from other pipelines, or may never attain a sufficient share of the energy market to require control.

Generally, regulated access to essential facilities has been in place to ensure that downstream users are not squeezed by a bottleneck service.  In the case of the Moomba to Sydney Pipeline (MSP) the NCC also considered access necessary to protect upstream suppliers.  This is unfortunate.  Such businesses are commonly considered to be capable of safeguarding themselves through appropriate contractual arrangements and extending regulatory protection to them could open up a vast expansion of government oversight of the economy.

When a regulator places obstacles in the way of a new facility being constructed, there is a loss to the economy.  The case for new pipelines to be free of price regulation is no less strong than that for new bakeries, car plants or any other facilities that have no government franchise.  Regulation that closes off market entry by insisting that incumbents underprice their services is just as harmful to a healthy economy as regulation that forbids new competition.


AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL GAS REGULATION

Provisions of the National Gas Code

The National Gas Code itself is far from the "light-handed" regulation that was proposed.  It is highly prescriptive.

For example, as has previously been noted the regulatory implications of Coverage under the National Gas Code does not allow for the operation of the price mechanism, the means by which supply is rationed in market systems.  Thus, under s.3.14, the arrangements are designed to preclude a pipeline from obtaining any greater profits than the regulator anticipated, and this is further amplified in s.3.23(d)(ii) which requires a tenderer to produce a policy regarding "additional revenue", a provision that does not seem to have a reciprocal arrangement where there is negative additional revenue.

And, in line with regulators' decision frameworks, the pricing policy sets out to cover new pipelines (s. 8.13) that have no franchise and which can only be subject to competition -- their not having been built already provides assurances of this.

Shortcomings of this nature are probably inevitable with regulatory codes and add force to the need to avoid regulation wherever possible.


Regulators' approaches to the National Gas Code

Stated approach of the regulatory authorities

As well as deficiencies in the National Gas Code, there remains a predisposition for regulatory intervention in prominent regulatory circles.  Although proclaiming regulation to be inferior to markets, resourceful regulators will often find merit in regulatory outcomes that they see as superior to those that might unfold in markets.

Thus, in addressing some of these matters, the Chairman of the NCC, Mr Graham Samuel claimed that

"..., it is important to remember that not all investment is good investment.  Critics ignore the effects of NOT granting access -- what happens to investment in other markets if access is denied?  More broadly, investment is not desirable for its own sake, but rather for the benefits it brings in increasing living standards."

Mr Samuel argued that the Council's should prevent unnecessary duplication of infrastructure and employ a wide public benefit test rather than one that examines the issue from the private perspective. (5)  This central planning approach to investment decision making is the pre-Hilmer model and should be avoided if investment in infrastructure is not to be discouraged by governments.

Mistrust of market mechanisms is also apparent in the June 2002 ACCC Draft Greenfields Guideline for gas transmission pipelines.  This envisages little scope for an unregulated pipeline to operate-such a pipeline would need to approach the ACCC with a proposed access arrangement and have this accepted.

The Greenfield Draft follows US practice, described in the next section, of requiring the pipeliner to submit its proposed charges to the regulator prior to receiving approval to levy those tariffs.  Unfortunately the ACCC proposals therefore attempt to graft approaches designed for free standing monopoly pipelines facing low risk to pipelines that face all the uncertainties of an entrepreneurial proposal.  The Productivity Commission in its Review of the National Access Regime recognised the shortcomings of the present approach in deterring investment and made some specific recommendations for improvement. (6)  Among these was a proposal for a "regulatory holiday" to prevent stifling the incentives for new Greenfield facilities.


Regulatory actions

An early test of the ability of regulators to withdraw from intervening in a market where competition offered adequate discipline concerned the Duke Energy pipeline from Longford to Sydney.

This facility established to rival the existing Moomba to Sydney Pipeline (MSP) meant massive over-capacity and an ending of the conditions that first justified the regulation.  Indeed, a price war broke out before Duke's pipeline was completed.

However, with the ACCC publicly silent on the matter, the NCC argued that they should regulate both pipelines.  This was based on the premise that they did not traverse parallel routes and that, even if they did, regulation would still be necessary to prevent collusion.  Such analytical reasoning by the NCC gives regulatory agencies the opportunity to control virtually every economic activity in the country and was heavily criticised by us. (7)

In the event, in 2001, the Australian Competition Tribunal (ACT) overturned the NCC's ambitions to regulate Duke Energy's pipeline.

The NCC accepted the Tribunal's decision and MSP therefore sought reciprocal treatment to escape its own regulatory prison.  But the NCC recommended continued coverage of the MSP, partly because it saw the original Tribunal decision on the Duke Energy pipeline as based on the on-going regulation of the MSP, which would automatically restrain the prices that Duke Energy could charge.

Among the other reasons the NCC gave in favour of continued price regulation of the MSP was an ACCC draft decision that proposed to reduce the price on the MSP further than it had fallen in the face of the competition from Duke.  The NCC saw this synthetic ACCC price as being more realistic than a market price emerging from competition.

Such mistrust of actual market outcomes is frequently seen in regulatory bodies.  It often stems from a disposition among regulators to assume prices of assets, once the assets have been sunk, should be based on a form of marginal cost, or at least not fully reflect replacement costs and the risk-adjusted return required of them prior to commitment.  As previously discussed such a regulatory price-setting framework must have a deterrent effect on other capital expenditures and bring reduced levels of economic growth.  The NCC recommendations on the MSP will be contested and it is likely that its regulatory status will come before the ACT.

The NCC adopted a more realistic approach to competitive provision in agreeing in 2002 to recommend regulatory coverage revocation of the Parmelia pipeline in Western Australia.  Consistent with its acceptance of the ACT decision on Duke Energy, it agreed that the pipeline does not have market power because it competes with the much larger Dampier to Bunbury pipeline and there is excess capacity.

The implications of the present attempt by the MSP to have its regulation removed may eventually bring into question the need for regulation on other pipelines.  Perhaps this might even extend to the VENCorp controlled GasNet system in Victoria, though the GasNet system, as a monopoly, would not expect early release from regulatory oversight.


Price decisions of regulators

Allowable investment returns

The ACCC has recognised a need to allow "generous benchmark returns that provide clear incentives for a service provider to achieve efficiencies grow demand for its services and outperform the benchmark return determined for the next regulatory period." (8)  The ACCC estimates the return to equity it allows is 12.68 per cent compared with the average stock exchange return over the ten years to September 2002 of 11.2 per cent and 4.8 per cent over the last five years.

Even so, it has already been noted that regulated businesses clearly think the ACCC stipulated return to be inadequate compensation for their risks.  This is partly because they contest the basis of the estimates, for example claiming that the allowed return does not properly account for the replacement cost of the pipeline.

The ACCC in its cost estimates also does not allow pipelines or other facilities to retain the benefits of rapid depreciation on the dubious grounds that passing on these benefits directly to consumers mirrors the outcome in competitive markets.  This is rather simplistic.  If these benefits were in fact simply passed on, they would not, of course, be benefits to the industry.  The government would be under some misunderstanding in implementing the policies, perhaps to compensate for the tax code's inappropriately slow depreciation rates, with a view to bringing increased investment.  Indeed, on the ACCC's line of reasoning, the rate of depreciation or the tax rate itself would matter little since competition would simply return both to some "normal" level.

As discussed in the previous section, these issues have become prominent as a result of the NCC coverage recommendations on the Moomba to Sydney Pipeline (MSP).  The prices on the MSP, once it faced competition from Duke, fell from 71 cents/GJ to 66 cents/GJ.  This is consistent with the price the consultant, NECG, estimates would prevail under a cost base called the hypothetical new entrant test (HNET).  The ACCC estimates the synthetic price to be 50 cents/GJ (it is apparently still developing its thinking on the matter, having recently revised this from 47 cents/GJ due to a different treatment of deferred taxes).  Its consultant, NERA, puts the HNET at 51 cents/GJ.

The ACCC offered as evidence to the NCC's review of the Moomba to Sydney pipeline, work undertaken by NERA which suggested the appropriate amount of annual depreciation on the pipeline was $5.2 million. (9)  This is on a facility with an agreed replacement cost value of one billion dollars, an 80 year engineering life and subject to considerable risk of by-pass (and the Duke Pipeline serving the Moomba to Sydney Pipeline's Sydney market is evidence of this) as well as risks of technological obsolescence. (10)

Such measures mean prices set below the rates necessary for profitable operations.  They mean that the facility is protected from competition -- at the expense of its shareholders -- and that new facility building is deterred.

The estimate by the regulator of a lower "competitive" price than the one that has emerged is a key reason why the NCC recommends continued regulatory coverage.  Other concerns of the regulator are about the pipeline's market power over upstream supply sources and alleged incentives to collude with downstream affiliates. (11)


Competitive tendering

Pipeline regulations have provision for competitive tendering.  Under this approach, the ACCC automatically accepts the price implicit in the winning tender.  Even so, the ACCC may reject a tender process if it considers there to have been too little interest shown or if the bids exhibit insufficient competitiveness.  Moreover, the process is highly formalised, costly and time-consuming with the ACCC identifying fourteen separate stages in the process, including a public inquiry.

These matters aside, competitive tendering is only an option for an opportunity with well-known and high prospectivity.  This is rarely the case.  Normally an entrepreneur spots an opportunity which has not previously been taken up because of its riskiness.  Even if such opportunities could attract rival bids requiring them to proceed by that process would cause economic harm -- it would constitute a deterrence for firms to engage in marketing research since their rivals would be able to free-ride should they spot a promising opportunity.


NEW PIPELINE DEVELOPMENTS

Following the changes stemming from the 1994 CoAG decision and the National Gas Code, new pipelines that were not protected by a franchise were constructed or have commenced.  These included:

  • Duke Energy's Eastern Gas Pipeline from Longford to Sydney
  • The AGL Central West extension to Dubbo of the Moomba to Sydney Pipeline
  • Duke Energy's Bass Strait to Tasmania link
  • The Origin, International Power, TXU Otway to Adelaide link

However two of these pipelines, Duke's Eastern Gas Pipeline and the Central West, predated the promulgation of the National Gas Code.  Both of these have experienced disappointment in the light of regulatory attitudes to the pipelines' pricing regimes.  The latest new major development, the Otways to Adelaide link, appears to have been designed to avoid being covered by regulation, and perhaps less than optimally sized as a result, by having all the capacity booked by the joint owners.

The most active recent new pipeline builder, Duke Energy, has been among those developers which have publicly announced that they are unlikely to invest in any new pipelines as a result of the "chilling" effect of regulatory oversight.

The implications for reduced efficiency from the present intrusive arrangements were recognised by the Productivity Commission in its Review of the National Access Regime.  Although the Productivity Commission found that across-the-board abandonment of access regulation at this stage would be inappropriate, it argued that changes were required to facilitate efficient investment, one of which to be considered included provision for access holidays. (12)


THE MANAGEMENT OF THE VICTORIAN GAS MARKET

THE US APPROACH TO GAS MARKET MANAGEMENT

Across the world, gas is mainly transported under contracts between transmission businesses and producers, customers, agents, retailers and others.  In the US, this approach, called the "contract carriage" model was spontaneously created following measures to require pipelines to operate on an open access basis.

Without anyone having planned it, producers, users and transporters buy and sell both gas and transport contracts to ensure they meet their long and short term balances.  The contracting points have evolved so that they centre on about 50 "hubs" -- normally points at which different pipelines interconnect.  Buyers, sellers and others seek to defray their risks by forward contracting with each other at these hubs.  This way the sellers and buyers both have certainty in the quantities produced and delivered, and in the price.

A few US pipelines are "common carriage".  These pipelines charge all customers the same rate and are obliged to expand capacity to meet reasonable demand.  Common carriage was not a model adopted in Australia and under the National Gas Code, pipeline companies cannot be obligated to expand capacity.

US gas pipeline regulation has been in place since the 1938 National Gas Act (NGA).  Its key control was, and remains, the "certificate of public convenience and necessity", which automatically gives some protection from competition, and which mandates a rate regime and obligation to serve.  Ostensibly, the approach is therefore contrary to the competition oriented regime adopted in Australia post 1994.

The NGA allowed transmission pipelines to own gas but regulated the price of that gas (but not gas from non-affiliates).  Following a series of developments under which transmission pipelines increasingly came to carry non-affiliates' gas, came Order 636 in 1992 under which pipelines were required to separate their own gas sales from their transportation service.  This has left the pipelines as pure transport businesses.

The US Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) assessment of proposed new pipelines has continued to focus on minimising their adverse effects on existing pipelines.  Although the conditions were somewhat relaxed in a policy statement of 1999, the paternalistic flavour remains:  FERC only approves a new pipeline if the potential benefits of "overbuilding" offset other costs like environmental disruption or a negative effect on an existing rival pipeline. (13)

The procedure for approval of new pipelines in the US is highly formalised.  Proponents must declare an "open season" where users are invited to seek (unpriced) capacity on a basis of need.  There is a dual set of contracts on the part of the local distribution business or other large user, comprising product and carriage.

In addition to published rates for firm carriage, rates for interruptible service are also published.  Tariff rates must be approved by FERC and are normally strictly in line with costs, (14) which are full costs in the case of firm access and operating costs for interruptible.  The US approach effectively transfers the equity in the pipeline to the firm capacity holders.  These customers have the right to trade their capacity and are usually credited with 90 per cent of the excess revenue that is earned by the pipeline from interruptible shippers.


THE COORDINATION TASK OF PIPELINES

It is not difficult to arrange for gas to pass through the different parties between the well and the burner.  In the US, merchant pipelines developed and had other parties accept them as having the necessary skills to balance the line.  An open access pipeline system with contract carriage puts the responsibility for ensuring transport capacity as well as gas procurement on the customers.  Parties negotiate contracts simultaneously with the gas supplier for product and the pipeline for capacity.  In the process they may also have contracts with other intermediaries.

Referring to the changes then underway in the US, Jeff Makholm, one of the principle advisors to the Victorian Government in its gas restructuring noted: (15)

"the landlords (that is the pipeline owners) and the tenants (mostly gas distribution companies) are fighting over who should be the beneficiary of the "found" floor space (valuable capacity that exists due to the acquired expertise in operating the various pipelines that comprise the network)."

Only if they have an incentive to do so will the "landlords" seek out the latent capacity in the existing system.  Makholm correctly maintains that for economic efficiency buyers must, "hold clear contractual rights to practically all existing ... capacity." Clear property rights that are transferable and valued offer appropriate incentives to uncover hidden value to those best able to do so.


THE VICTORIAN GAS SYSTEM

Coordination and development under market carriage

Rather than adopting the well proven contract carriage system, the Victorian Government has opted to establish a market with some novel features.  The Government structurally separated gas retailers from the pipe owning distributors, and made it mandatory for buyers and sellers to participate in a "spot" market, placing the transmission business under the operational control of a Government body, VENCorp.

In contrast to the US system of pipeline control, VENCorp, the publicly owned System Operator, determines the quantities the pipeline carries and makes its expansion decisions.  This has some features similar to the US common carriage system but leaves the pipeline owner as little more than a passive sub-contractor to VENCorp.

Under the Victorian market carriage system, as with common carriage, the retailer does not require carriage rights.  The advantage claimed of this is that retailers need not be concerned about their ability to obtain additional capacity when a customer changes supplier, since the supply rights, in so far as they exist, are automatically transferred with the contract.

The downside to this is that users cannot contract for carriage and thereby obtain priority for carriage on the pipeline.  Nor do they have a clear means of recourse in the event that they are denied delivery of the gas they have contracted.  VENCorp has no capability of signing contracts that offer such assurances and has legislative protection against any liability for its actions that might lead to delivery shortfalls or gas interruptions.

Under the Victorian model, gas shippers and suppliers make offers on a daily basis for gas they have contracted which is surplus to their requirements and for gas shortages they anticipate.  Although the market is efficient in that it clears at a price that reflects the scarcity value of the gas, it assumes that the carriage will always be available.  Events of July 22 2002 showed that the gas might not always be available and users were disconnected.

This rather devalues the VENCorp case made three days earlier that

"the market carriage regime established by the MSOR of itself reduces the need for long term certainty.  In particular, by removing the need for long term gas haulage contracts (and applying a spot market model instead), the MSOR establishes a market environment in which market participants have a reduced need for long term certainty". (16)

The implications of the lack of property rights to carriage

The inability of users to obtain firm carriage access is likely to have contributed to several deferrals of gas fired new electric power plants to serve the Victoria/South Australia region.  These proposals included plants to be located in Maryvale (Paperlinx/Duke 200 MW) and South Ballarat (AES 500 MW).  One early outcome of deferrals is the intent signalled by the electricity market manager, NEMMCO, to seek to contract increased electricity capacity under its reserve trader provisions. (17)

Market carriage also creates difficulties for firms wishing to contract gas through the Victorian system to other systems.  The shipper faces contractual uncertainty in selling gas that must be transported through a Victorian system within which he has no contractual rights.

A further risk of inefficiency is that the model used may reduce the incentives of the transmission pipeline, GasNet, to seek out economies.  GasNet simply does as it is instructed by VENCorp, which specifies how much gas is to be carried and how much is to be in the pipeline at the end of each day ("linepack").  This dampens GasNet's incentives to take actions with a view to increase capacity availability within its existing pipes.  Market carriage in general is likely to bring GasNet to adopt a more conservative business approach than might be optimal.

Of course, it is also true that under a regulated contract carriage approach, the pipeline's incentives are severely attenuated.  A pipeline that develops new capacity under such circumstances would have the price of that capacity reduced at the next "re-set" to bring the return on capital back to the regulator's target rate.  Hence a customer, unless it thought that future capacity would be in short supply, would not sign a contract at a premium price covering the period beyond that "re-set".  The customer would normally be confident that the regulator would reduce the price in view of the newly discovered capacity.

In addition, the difference between the two forms is reduced to the degree, as some maintain happens in South Australia, that the government is persuaded to intervene when shortages arise thereby nullifying the contracts users have with the pipeline.

Thus the difference may not be great between the two carriage methods from the perspective of incentives on the operator to find low cost augmentations or innovative means of better selling capacity.

Yet market carriage remains a system with additional shortcomings to those inherent in all regulated systems.  Its expansion is driven by a government agency.  Contract carriage is more directly responsive to commercial drivers.  Augmentations respond to the willingness of customers to incur costs and would also provide those customers with some form of rights (probably financial rights) over the capacity their contracts has created.  Thus a new gas fired generator would pay for an expansion and have rights to the increased capacity, thereby ensuring that the capital expenditure is highly responsive to commercial need.

If the Victorian system were to be changed to the conventional contract carriage approach, consideration of a non-disruptive way for this to occur would be required.  This would probably entail vesting users their existing implicit quantity and destination rights.  These would be tradeable, probably on electronic bulletin boards, and holders of firm capacity rights would not be able to hoard them.

Multiple entry and exit points complicate pipeline management.  In this respect, the Victorian system is somewhat more meshed than other Australian systems, though not more than many US systems that operate on contract carriage bases.  The more meshed nature of the Victorian system means the pipeline would require a body that ensures it is kept in balance.  If this were to be GasNet, that business -- in line with US practice -- would probably not be permitted to buy and sell capacity contracts since it could then favour its own resource over those of other businesses.

Regulation in general is having adverse effects in a great many ways.  What is really required is to remove the regulatory coverage at the earliest opportunity, that is as soon as competition has eroded the previous monopoly power.  Nonetheless, the move to a contract carriage is an interim step that will allow some efficiency improvements.


Operating costs of the Victorian system

A further disadvantage of vesting control of the facility by a body not motivated by profit maximisation is the excessive caution this brings.  VENCorp's incentive is to avoid the possibility of capacity shortages.  Such motivations in the past have led to goldplating.  They can also lead to perverted outcomes since in the future, a regulator is likely to take the view that capacity built in excess of needs is excessive and should not command the return envisaged of it.  But the instigator of that capacity overbuild, VENCorp, has no liability for its mistaken view.

This is likely to entail higher operating costs.  With respect to the Victorian system, VENCorp claims to operate in a highly cost-effective manner.  But it comprises an extra layer of management and board oversight compared with an integrated system.  And as a State owned body, it is unlikely to have the same cost saving imperatives as a private company that is profit-focussed and unencumbered with multiple objectives.

While we have no comparative benchmark, it does appear that the O&M costs of GasNet and VENCorp at 28 per cent of 2003 forecast revenue appears to be relatively high.


GAS AND ELECTRICITY MARKET ASYMMETRIES

DIFFERENT VOLL LEVELS

It is claimed that the market carriage system employed in Victoria brings gas and electricity into better alignment.

Establishing signals and other decision structures to promote optimal investment in electricity transmission has been highly contentious.  In Australia, unlike many other countries, vast distances tend to make transmission costs, especially transmission augmentations, far more important than in densely populated markets.  The UK approach has been to smear most electricity transmission costs across all users and suppliers and to build new lines as the regulator decides this is warranted.  This analogy with the planning and provision of roads may have merit in the UK where transmission forms only about five per cent of the total electricity bill and excessive expenditure may not result in serious distortions to the final consumer.  However, augmentation in Australia's "long stringy" system can be no less expensive than resolving a localised power shortage by building new generation.

As with gas, electricity faces considerable controversy over whether to adopt a centrally planned augmentation system or allow market provision.

These matters aside, the two markets are far from being aligned.  The gas market VoLL in Victoria is set at $800/ Gj, a level that coincidentally is similar to the $10,000/MWh electricity VoLL equivalent. (18)  However, the gas price is in fact effectively capped at below $20/Gj, the cost of the last increment of supply that is presently available.  Recent shortage events have highlighted the risk, perhaps increasing risk, of this cap being reached.

In fact gas prices in Victoria, even on a day when there were forced disconnections averaged less than $10/GJ.  Those (generator) participants that were ordered to cease using gas were understandably reluctant to do so when the price of their electricity output was many times that level.  At least one of the generators has reported that it had contracts that it was forced to break at some considerable penalty.

There are clear benefits in aligning maximum market prices of gas and electricity since gas fired electricity will usually be the marginal source of supply.  Hence consistency and the avoidance of market distortion would require VoLL being allowed to rise to similar levels for the two commodities.

It may however be that permitting such high prices would not bring forward much additional capacity.  While this is certainly true in the short run, allowing prices to rise to several fold their existing level would bring great incentives for users and retailers to contract for additional storage capacity and perhaps more robust links between the markets.


DIFFERENT DURATION OF BIDS

With the gas market based on a daily price and electricity prices set at 5/30 minute periods there are major implications for efficiency.  Not only do the two prices need to be made consistent, but gas prices cannot be left remaining on a daily basis.

More frequent bidding and re-bidding provision (probably with locational features) may entail costs including those integral to the development of intra-day gas pipe injections and depletion profiles.  For most participants these may not be great in a market that is normally characterised by static prices.  But the need for such features will increase as the main GasNet pipeline achieves greater utilisation.  Indeed, if the VoLL price is to be better aligned to that of electricity, the likely means of price changes occurring smoothly would be via demand side bids.  These require intra-day bidding to be effective.


SETTING THE PRICE LEVELS FOR REGULATED FACILITIES

A further issue with the present arrangements in energy results from revenue capping of the electricity transmission businesses earnings.  Revenue capping rather than price capping owes its popularity to environmentalists' pressures to prevent actions that might "waste" scarce resources.  It is claimed that a price cap would encourage the transmission business to sell more energy than was needed.

Such notions belong to an earlier era.  All businesses seek to persuade consumers to buy more of their product and the price system ensures the appropriate incentives are in place optimise increased sales with conservation of supplies.

Placing transmission businesses without the incentive to pursue sales growth is likely to mean opportunities foregone.  These might include reducing the prospect of a joint approach of energy supplier and transport supplier to make offers to attract particular businesses.

Although GasNet has a revenue "target" this is more akin to a price cap and the business obtains the benefit of increased gas flow.  However, as gas and electricity are increasingly in competition, electricity's regulatory arrangements should be aligned to those of gas.


CHANGING THE VICTORIAN ARRANGEMENTS

Australia is suffering from energy market reform fatigue.  But as markets once introduced throw up new areas that require consequent change this seems inevitable.  The alternative of stopping the reform is likely to bring a return of many of the earlier inefficiencies.

The reforms to update the Victorian gas arrangements would not entail draconian change.

They might be accommodated by

  • Making explicit the implicit carriage rights that existing users have and allowing the users to trade in their capacity (and possibly imposing a charge to offset the "gift" that the vesting might entail).
  • Requiring all future users and those seeking increased use to have capacity as well as gas or to risk facing penalty charges by becoming financially interruptible.
  • Have an independent body examine whether and under what conditions coverage might be revoked on the GasNet pipeline system
  • Facilitating trade in capacity through electronic bulletin boards.
  • Resetting the gas VoLL at a level that is consistent with the electricity market VoLL and introducing an intra-day gas market.


ENDNOTES

1.  Max Kimber gave helpful advice and assistance in preparing this paper.

2.  Set out in National Competition Policy, Hilmer F.G., Rayner M.R., and Taperell, G.Q., AGPS, 1993.

3.  The demand for pipeline usage is a derived demand.  It depends on the demand for gas.  Thus if the elasticity of demand for gas is 0.3 (a doubling of price brings a 30 per cent fall in demand) and the pipeline comprises only 10 per cent of total costs, passing on a doubling of pipeline costs leads to only a 3 per cent fall in gas demand.  Of course, if supply is competitive, it is of little relevance whether demand is derived or not, since suppliers will take advantage of cheaper transport if it is available.

4.  For an authority who traces this aspect through the common law see Richard A. Epstein Principles for a Free Society, Perseus Books, Reading Mass, 1998.

5.  Address to Utilicon 2000, Melbourne August 7 2000.

6.  Review of the National Access Regime, Report No. 17, Productivity Commission, September 2001.  Specific proposals include:

RECOMMENDATION 11.1
Part IIIA should make provision for the proponent of a proposed investment in an essential infrastructure facility to seek a binding ruling on whether the services provided by that facility would meet the declaration criteria.  Where the Minister, after receiving advice from the National Competition Council, determines that they would not, the services concerned would be exempt from declaration.  A binding ruling should apply in perpetuity, unless revoked by the Minister on advice from the Council on the grounds of a material change in circumstances.  Such a revocation should be appellable to the Australian Competition Tribunal.

RECOMMENDATION 11.3
The Commonwealth Government should, through the Council of Australian Governments, initiate a process to refine mechanisms (additional to those provided for in recommendations 11.1 and 11.2) to facilitate efficient investment within the Part IIIA regime in particular and access regimes generally.  The mechanisms to be considered should include:

  • fixed-term access holidays available to any proposed investment in essential infrastructure which is determined to be contestable;  and
  • provision for a ‘truncation' premium to be added to the cost of capital that has been agreed between a project proponent and the regulator prior to investment.

This process should be completed in sufficient time to enable legislative implementation within Part IIIA no later than 2003.

7Review of Competition Policy, The Productivity Commission's Inquiry into Clause 6 of the Competition Principles Agreement and Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act 1974.

8.  ACCC, Regional development of natural gas transmission pipelines, October 2002.

9.  NERA Report Commissioned by ACCC on Aspects of the Moomba-Sydney Pipeline System, http://www.ncc.gov.au/pdf/REGaMoCR-003.pdf, September 2002

10.  The pipeline has all its present sales contracted though its former affiliate, AGL.  In one sense, the ACCC price set therefore matters little but a forced price reduction on non-contracted sales puts pressure, including through "most favoured customer" clauses, on contract sales volumes and prices.

11.  Moomba to Sydney Pipeline:  Revocation Application under the , NCC November 2002

12.  Productivity Commission, Review of the National Access Code, Report No. 17, September 2001.

13.  FERC gives a certificate of public necessity and convenience if 25% of the pipeline proposed is contracted, especially if there is 10 year firm contracts for 100% of capacity.  Or if revenues under contracts exceed costs or if sponsors are fully at risk.  These policy guidelines were relaxed in 1999.  But it now also requires evidence of public benefits like bottleneck removal, competitive alternatives, lower cost to customers but a negative effect would still be seen if the new pipeline created potential excess capacity.  For expansions where it is less than 5% the cost is rolled in.  FERC would not allow incremental pricing where the cost of the roll-in is lower than the original build, since it sees this as best benefiting existing users.

14.  FERC uses the Hirfindahl-Hirschman index, (first applied by the United States Department of Justice following its 1986 report on gas pipelines).  This would normally require the equivalent of five similarly sized independent operators prior to a pipeline being allocated status to pursue "market-based" tariffs.  To date no pipeline has qualified for this.  However, the relatively mature pipeline system does mean potential rivalry, which keeps prices reflective of costs.

15.  Jeff D Makholm, Gas Pipeline Capacity:  Who Owns It?  Who Profits?  How Much?, Public Utilities Fortnightly, October 1 1994

16.  Vencorp Submission to the ACCC seeking the authorisation of the Market System Operating Rules, 18 July 2002, http://www.accc.gov.au/gas/fs-gas.htm

17.  The reserve trader provisions themselves are a market intervention that could leave the electricity market vulnerable to future inefficiencies by creating a dual market.

18.  As the $800/Gj is set as the average price for the day it is effectively much higher than the average electricity VoLL price which is based on a five minute spike.

Wednesday, November 20, 2002

Bracks' Luck Will Be a Test

Steve Bracks is a lucky politician, but has he worked hard enough to sustain his luck?

Arguable not, and he will be sorely tested if he wins another term on the 30th of November.

When Mr Bracks won the unwinnable election three years ago he inherited a booming economy, a growing population and state finances with little debt, efficient services and a massive $1.7 billion operating surplus.

According to broad indicators, he has not squandered this inheritance.  The Bracks administration has restrained the growth of the government sector measured as a share of the State's economy.  Debt levels have been cut.  Payroll tax rates have been cut.  With studious indecision, the Bracks Government has avoided many of the more wasteful infrastructure projects it promoted whilst in Opposition, and they have fulfilled the State's competition policy commitments.

While it is fair to conclude that this is a different and better government than its Labor Party predecessor, there is cause for concern.

The Bracks Government has allowed the public sector wages bill to blow-out.  Over its first three years of government, the State's wages bill grew by 27 per cent, or by 9 per cent per year.  A further 6 per cent growth is forecast for 2002-03, though judging from the election commitments to date spending will be higher.

The money has been used to fund around 10,000 new positions and large wage increases particular in health, education and police.

The concern is not so much with the additional staff or even with the wage increases.  Rather the problem for the longer term lies with the restrictive workplace arrangements.  The Government has added a raft of restrictive practices and conditions that will drive future labour costs higher without off-setting productivity gains.  For example the wages deal with the nurses sets a fixed ratio of four patients per nurse irrespective of demand.  It also restored automatic annual increments to nurses' pay, reversing the previous government's approach of paying according to efficiency.  These inflexibilities have contributed to the longer elective surgery waiting lists and the increasing number ambulance forced to by-pass hospitals record under the Bracks Government's watch despite the additional expenditure.  The Government's deal with teachers give rise to a similar a set of problems.

The Bracks Government's problem with labour extends to infrastructure.  The Government has slowly ramped up its plans for spending on infrastructure, including $3.5 billion in transport strategy, $500 in hospital developments, Commonwealth games venues and a $157 million Synchotron.  Sweetheart deals between the Bracks Government and construction unions is set to increase the cost and reduce the viability of these projects.  For example, the deal arranged recently for the MCG redevelopment added around $20 millions to the cost of the project.  It also resulted in the Commonwealth withdrawing its contribution to the project thereby adding an addition $77 million to the State's cost.  If similar deals spread to other State infrastructure projects -- as is expected -- then the cost to the State budget will be enormous.

To date, the Bracks Government has been able to fund its rising expenditure with an effortless rise in revenue.  Over the first three years of its term, State revenue grew by 30 per cent, or 10 per cent per year.

Three factors have driven revenue growth in this period:  an overheated housing market, a free-spending federal government and high returns on the stock market.  None of these trends are likely to continue into the future.  Indeed the gravy train is already stalling.

The housing boom which generated $1.2 billion in excess of forward estimates last year is beginning to slow.  The Commonwealth, which has pumped billions into the State coffers in the form of higher first homebuyers grant, national competition policy grants, tax reform compensation grants and additional road funding, is facing a tougher budget climate, no election and other priorities.

The buoyant stock market of the last few years has allowed the government to fund a large proportion of it superannuation and insurance liabilities with minimal draw on tax or grant revenue.  This avenue of earnings has already dried-up with a shortfall of $1.1 billion in the State's super scheme recorded last year.  More losses are likely to be brought to book this year.  The investment losses are likely to spread to WorkCover.

While the Bracks Government has made an artform of "behavioural taxes", with traffic fines currently running at about $35 million per month with double digit growth, there is a limit to people's masochism.

Bracks has had a dream run to date, requiring little real effort to appear to be both fiscally responsible and extremely generous.  He will have to make his own luck if he wins another term, by driving value for money in the public services and in government contracts.  To date there is no indication he has what it takes.


ADVERTISEMENT

Tuesday, November 19, 2002

Green Power Riddled by Perilous Politics and Specious Economics

The politics of energy is a heady brew.  Two weeks ago, Candy Broad, the Energy Minister, announced measures designed to suppress electricity price rises.  At the same time she called for additional use of high cost renewable energy which would boost electricity costs.

The government announced that it is to maintain price caps for household electricity.  When these were introduced last year, they were set too low and two of the five retailers responded by selling up and getting out of the market.

Prices set too low bring an inefficient and unreliable energy system.  This year, however, Victoria has new power stations and the ability to import more electricity from NSW if need be.  This will more than offset the effects of reduced Snowy hydro-electricity output resulting from the drought and increased environmental flows.  As a result, wholesale prices, which account for about 40% of households' electricity costs, have fallen by almost a fifth.  Though government price controls rarely make sense, their present extension is unlikely to bring drastic short term harm.

But Ms Broad is also seeking a 60 per cent increase in the Commonwealth's Mandated Renewable Energy Target (MRET).  This requires retailers to include a growing proportion of "green" energy in their total supply.  It operates over and above voluntary schemes where retailers offer consumers green energy at a premium price.

The cheapest form of renewable energy is wind generation.  Even this is more than twice as expensive as electricity from coal, gas and hydro.  Moreover, wind power works intermittently and requires additional costs for back-up support from other generators.

Present MRET policies will require Australian consumers to pay an additional $380-540 million per year for electricity.  Raising the requirement by 60 per cent will cost at minimum a further $228-324 million.  These costs must be passed on in electricity prices.

One goal of the government in seeking to increase the MRET target is to stimulate the local wind generator industry.

In the bad old days before Bob Hawke took the Government reins in Canberra, tariff protection on goods like clothing was used with the hope of giving a leg up to "infant" industries.  It didn't work and generations of Australians were foisted with higher clothing prices for no benefit.  The renewable energy plans look to be an equally doomed re-run of this.

As with the push for industry protection, wind power has its vested interests.  Traders seeking to create a market for greenhouse credits and windmill developers have joined forces with a claque of green activists who would prefer everyone used a lot less energy anyway.  The lobbying of these interests provides a softening up process that makes the government's proposals seem moderate.

In August the Government's Infrastructure Planning Council, oin which green energy interests are heavily represented, called for 25 per cent of Victorian energy to be supplied by renewables by 2020.  That's more than double the share under present policies.

Last week another report, commissioned by Origin Energy the largest holder of green electricity credits in Victoria, promoted increased mandatory use of renewables.  That report made the implausible claim that increasing the mandatory renewables share to 21 per cent of electricity would only cost 0.2 cents per kWh.  Standard generation costs are 4 cents per kWh.

The policy of foisting increased costs on the electricity consumer has recently assumed a politically unexpected dimension.  The wind lobby imagined it had the environmentalists on-side.  However, many object to the noise and visibly intrusive nature of windmills and are campaigning against them.  Their objections are centred on windmills placed in the most scenically splendid areas.  These are often the very places where the wind blows hardest and where windmills must be placed.

The silent majority of passive consumers seeking lower costs of living therefore has an improbable ally, which vastly complicates the policy approach.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, November 17, 2002

Bracks Fails the IR Test

The Bracks Government is facing an economic and electoral disaster in Melton.

It walked the Japanese firm -- Saizeriya -- into inter-union battle and failed to fix the mess.  As a result the State could lose a multi-billion dollar food processing complex.

Victoria's reputation as a reliable food manufacturer has already been damaged.  If the project fails, our reputation and the millions spent to enhance it will be destroyed;  thousand of jobs will be lost along with new markets for agricultural products.

The fault goes right to the top -- to Mr Bracks.  Shortly after winning government Mr Bracks went to Japan to assure Saizeriya that his Government would meet the commitments made by the previous government and insure a productive IR climate.

The Premier understood the significance of the project.  Saizeriya is a massive Japanese Italian-style food chain with over 570 stores.  It is profitable, innovative and path breaking and where it goes others follow.  After much effort and assistance from the State Government and the City of Melton, the firm decided to build a $40 million pilot plant at a site in Melton.  If all went well, this was to be the first of eight plants with a total construction value of in excess $400 million.  According to the City of Melton, the Saizeriya investment would spawn an addition investment of $1.4 billion.  The whole package constitutes the largest investment in the food industry in modern times.

Instead of helping, the Bracks government lead the Japanese into a nightmare.  The IR Minister Monica Gould succumbed to pressure and agreed to give the NUW coverage of the site.  Given that the militant AMWU has general coverage of the food manufacturing sector, she would have known that her decision would precipitate disputation.

Industrial disputation ensued from the turning of the first sod in April 2001.  The CFMEU, which had coverage over the construction phase, went on a perpetual go-slow in support of the AMWU and the AMWU blocked the supply of steel to the site.  The Government stood by helpless until December 2001 when Saizeriya purchased a factory site in New Zealand and threatened to pull the plug.  The Government then responded with an offer to compensate the firm for time lost, provide the services of an specialist to fix the problem and set new deadlines.  The IR specialist turned out to be a union stooge and was thrown off the site by management, the new deadlines were not met and more money was squandered.

The pilot plant is yet to be completed and is well over 12 months behind schedule.  The project is once again in front of the AIRC.  The latest deadline of December 2002 is looking in doubt and Saizeriya's management is no doubt once again demanding action or else.

The bottom-line is that the Bracks Government has proven to be grossly incompetent and has put in jeopardy jobs, the bush and our reputation.

While we know a lot about the Saizeriya project as a result of the Cole Royal Commission, there every reason to surmise that similar ineptitude has lead to long and costly delays in other projects including the Geelong highway, Holden engine plant and Age printing plant and Federation Square.


ADVERTISEMENT

Thursday, November 07, 2002

Paper 13 Challenges Labour Law

Ask almost anyone involved in the Australian construction industry what outcome they expect from the Cole Royal Commission and they will reply negatively.  The consensus is that the Commission will hand down its report and within a short period the industry will return to normal patterns of industrial relations thuggery and intimidation.

But something has happened suggesting a different outcome could be possible.  About a fortnight ago the Commission stopped taking evidence apparently to begin writing its report.  However, last week the Commission unexpectedly released yet another discussion paper with invitations for more submissions.  What's going on?

The paper, the 13th, creates an entire new focus away from industrial relations perspectives to look at competition issues and asks fundamental questions about regulation in society.  One interpretation is that it builds on a scenario put to the commission that the industrial relations war in the industry is in fact a charade for a complex process of market and competition destruction that is actually made legal by employment law.

Suddenly the focus has shifted from considering unions as the bad guys to looking at the behaviour of businesses who don't want competition.

On the surface, this new scenario could appear fanciful.  But it transpires that the great institutional defender of competition and consumer rights, the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission has limited capacity or willingness to interfere in competition destruction where it involves industrial relations, because the Trade Practices Act prevents it from interfering in "employment".  Further, even the National Competition Council supports a public policy position of excising labour issues from competition law.

Suddenly the problems in the construction industry look to have deeper causes than the simplistic "good/ evil employer" verses "evil/ good unions" stance that typifies the public debate.

To give a practical example;  in the current 2002 round of construction industry enterprise bargaining negotiations, businesses who would normally be competitors for plumbing, formwork, concreting and other construction tasks, meet regularly with their respective unions to discuss prices, rates and work practices.  The meetings are legal, because the discussions and price agreements pertain to "employment".  But take those same meetings, remove the unions and start talking and fixing prices for tenders, concrete, wiring and other inputs, and the participants risk facing heavy fines for collusion under the Trade Practices Act.

The reality is that the legislative and policy framework of competition law has long drawn a distinction between declaring illegal market collusion on commercial matters, but making legal the same behaviours when done under employment frameworks.  However, in the construction industry, labour issues constitute a large percentage of costs and dictate commercial dynamics.  Here the distinction between price fixing on labour, and price fixing and competition destruction on tenders is razor fine.

Taking this perspective, unions look like partners with businesses in an exercise of market manipulation, with government the creators of opportunity.  Battles between unions and employers take the appearance of elaborate smokescreens designed to fool the public and the "non-insiders" in the industry that are the victims of the manipulation.

The Commission discussion paper seems to suggest that in the construction industry the distinction between legal and illegal market manipulation has become highly blurred and perhaps is a core cause of industry problems.  Even further, the paper asks if it remains appropriate to isolate "employment" from competition law, thus raising questions about the ethical positioning of the entire industrial relations system.  Let the real debate begin!

The Commission is seeking submissions.  The responses alone will be illuminating.  Unions and academic labour lawyers can be expected to submit the usual posturings about ILO conventions and the immorality of regulating labour like any other commodity.  But greater interest will be in business and their employer associations' responses because they have a dilemma.

If the construction industry is silent, recommendations could emerge to extend competition law into labour areas in unpredictable ways thus potentially threatening some underlying business structures.  If businesses and their associations criticise the discussion paper but fail to substantiate their criticism adequately, evidence already accumulated by the Commission could expose possible complicity in market manipulation.  If business agrees with the discussion paper, they could ferment change and open a new and, to some, a frightening era of competition in commercial construction.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, November 03, 2002

Bracks' Wage Battle

While budgetary issues are unlikely to dominate the coming State election as they have in the past, they will be a key issue.

One of the main questions will be:  whether the Bracks Government in "old-tax-and spend" Labor or "new-fiscally-responsible" Labor?

The Financial Report of The State of Victoria 2001-2002 released this week provides the first real overview of the Government's record.  And while there are questions in some areas, in general the Government record is New not Old Labor.

The Bracks administration has restrained government growth to below the level of general growth in the state economy.  It has shifted spending priorities towards health, education, public safety and infrastructure.  They have avoided many of the more wasteful infrastructure projects advance whilst in Opposition.  They are involving the private sector in infrastructure development and service delivery.  They have increased charges for various government services, thereby using price signals to limit the growth in demand.  They have maintained debt reduction and fulfilled the State's competition policy commitments.

In short the Bracks Government is of a distinctly different character than its Labor Party predecessors when it comes to fiscal management and ideology.  And the state is better for it.

Will they be able to continue with new Labor polices if re-elected?  In short, probably not.

During its first term, the Bracks Government has experienced a dream run.  It inherited a $1.7 billion budget surplus and a buoyant economy -- thanks in large part to its predecessor.  The economy along with an overheated housing market, a free-spending federal government and high returns on the stock market generated phenomenal State revenue growth.  Over first three years of its term, State revenue grew by 22 per cent or just over 7 per cent per year.

The inherited surplus has now been cut to below $300 million and the revenue flow will surely slow.  The Howard Government will shift its spending priorities away from State grants to things such as defense and homeland security.  The housing bubble will burst.  Consumer spending is already beginning to slow -- as is spending on gaming which has been the largest source of State revenue growth.  And the recent stock market decline has already had a major impact on the State's revenue with earnings down in last year by $1.1 billion and more losses likely to be brought to book this year.

Because of the easy money, the Bracks Government has not been required to focus on value-for-money where it counts the most -- the public sector workforce -- over the first three years of its term, the State's wages bill grew by 27 per cent or by 9 per cent per year.  A further increase of 6 per cent is budgeted for 2002-03, which gauging from the blow-out that is already evident;  this must be treated as an ambitious estimate.

The next Government irrespective of its composition will need to rein in the growth and probably the size of the States's wages bill.  This will be a tough test for a Bracks Government as it will not only require it to dismantle much of its own handy work but require it to take on its largest political constituency -- the public sector unions.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, November 02, 2002

Free Trade or Fair Trade?

Reduced trade barriers have been key elements in the increased prosperity the world has seen in the post-1945 era.  These lower barriers have allowed greater specialisation of production with consequent gains in cheaper goods enjoyed by all parties.

At the present time the average tariff on imports into Australia is 3.8 per cent.  In 1984/84 the tariff equivalent averaged 21 per cent for agricultural products and 13 per cent for manufactures.

The rapid reduction in Australian tariffs did not cause high levels of unemployment.  Present levels of unemployment are lower now than they were during the mid 1980s.


DRIVERS FOR LIBERALISATION

Multilateral agreements under the GATT and WTO have been the leading arrangements bringing greater liberalisation, but narrower agreements like the European Union and Canada-US bilateral free trade have also been significant.  For Australia, the bilateral NAFTA and CER agreements with New Zealand have made important contributions in allowing Australia and New Zealand to become, in substance, a single economy.

Unilateral, non-reciprocated trade reform also offers benefits -- indeed, Australia's liberalisation has in the main been of this nature with tariff and other barriers being reduced following reports of the Productivity Commission or its predecessors.  These unilateral reductions have then been used as bargaining coin to seek concessions from other countries in trade negotiations.

Although trade liberalisation works best if all parties participate, gains are also made with unilateral liberalisations where others do not reciprocate.  Unilateral liberalisations result in a relative contraction or improved efficiency of the tariff reducing country's less competitive businesses.  These outcomes allow more to be produced with the same labour, capital and other resources.


BENEFITS OF LIBERALISATION

Traditionally, trade benefits have been seen most clearly where countries have vastly different economic structures.  Comparative advantage in different areas of production has allowed both countries to gain as a result of specialisation.  (The so-called Heckscher-Ohlin model).

This view of trade gains has been at the heart of the process over a long period -- England sent manufactures to Australia and received primary products in return.

More recently, the increased income levels stemming from the European Union (EU) have highlighted different forms of gains or, perhaps more accurately, a different view of the same gains.  The EU gains were realised by countries with structurally similar economies.

The gains came from intra-industry trade -- the trading partners appeared to be buying and selling goods that they already made in their home countries.  The gains from this intra-industry trade following liberalisations between countries that have similar economic profiles have come from two directions:

  • increased competitive pressures on suppliers that previously went less heavily challenged in their home markets;
  • businesses facing increased competition usually lift their performance to the benefit of consumers in all participating countries a variation of the traditional comparative advantage gains but one that takes advantage of the increased specialisation of modern production and the increased number of stages through which materials are put prior to reaching the final consumer.

FAIR TRADE

Over the years there have always been calls for trade liberalisation conditional on some measure of "fairness".  After all, it could be said that those countries that pay very low wages are at a trade advantage with high wage countries like Australia.

But a moment's thought shows the deficiencies of this approach.  For a start it would deny market opportunities to countries with low income levels, opportunities that have been crucial to the subsequent growth, and high income levels of countries ranging from Japan southern Europe.  And as we have seen, trade liberalisation has been accompanied by increased not decreased employment all round.

Moreover, once embarked upon, this road leads to a reversal of the trade liberalisation that has served us so well.  Thus it might be said that Australian farmers with our vast agricultural land resources have unfair advantages over European farmers in broad area crops like wheat.  Similarly, Australia with its abundance of easily won mineral wealth is not on a level playing field with mining operations in other countries.  In both cases, many in importing countries would seek to equalise the competition by placing a penalty on Australian exports.

More recently, some have sought to use environmental or worker safety standards as conditions for permitting other countries to export to us.  Although many championing such causes do so out of strong convictions, it means paternalistically imposing our own standards on other countries.  And often supporting measures to restrict trade on safety or environmental grounds are those with a vested interest in maintaining a cushion against more competitive suppliers.  But the protected suppliers' gain is the consumer's loss.

Even seeking to use the fair trade weapon as a pressure on manufacturers to lift employment conditions in poor countries where they operate is likely to backfire on the workers in those countries.  Forcing higher wages is likely to mean industries migrate to other countries which are less susceptible to such pressures.  The outcome is lost jobs in the targeted country, with the displaced workers having to accept far inferior conditions that those they previously experienced.


CONCLUDING COMMENTS

There is in fact no yardstick by which one country can be judged to be playing fair in its trade relations with others.

Setting a criterion of "fairness" means the trade has to be managed.  Some bureaucracy would need to sift through literally thousands of trade items across two hundred countries to give each product the elephant stamp of approval.  This would grind commerce down and with it living standards would fall in affluent and poor countries alike.

This bureaucratic intervention, the openings "fair" trade intervention offers vested interests to protect themselves, and the denial of opportunities for poor countries to lift their living standards all testify against employing the notion of "fair" competition in trade relations.


ADVERTISEMENT