Sunday, August 27, 2006

Not easy being green but we'll prosper

If you have been a frequent reader of this column, you would know that I have a problem with the green lobby.

Like the majority of people, I am a passionate environmentalist.  That is I want to preserve, enhance, enjoy and understand the natural environment in its many dimensions.

I am also strongly in favour of prosperity and believe that with human ingenuity and the right institutions, we can have prosperity and improve the environment.

The green lobby, or rather its dominant voices, do not share my outlook.  They see growth, markets, technology, and people as at odds with the natural environment.

Accordingly they seek to restrict markets, undermine property rights, ban technology, and eliminate the hand of man from the land.

Their motto is lock it away from man and give them -- the greens -- the key.

Many of the established groups emerged from the protest movement of the 1960s and '70s.  Back then they had a worthwhile message as environmental values were undervalued.

World moving, however, has moved on.  Environmental values have being incorporated into the mainstream and large gains have been made.  However too many of these groups remain mired in a negative past and in denial of gains.

If they are just groups of ageing hippies living in Nimbin, there would be no worries, but they are not.

The green lobby has demanded and been given the mantle of environmental guardians and as a result have become rich and influential beyond their due.

My beef is not with the money or power, but what they do with it and the narrowness of their views.

While the green lobby frequently demands openness and democracy of others, it is very much a closed shop dominated by a few pessimistic professionals.

There is a degree of uniformity in views and approach that is unwarranted and downright destructive of the very thing that the sector alleges to do:  protect the environment.

There is now an alternative.  Two years ago a group of frustrated environmentalists got together in Ballarat and gave birth to the Australian Environmental Foundation.

Having fended the threat of legal action from a wealthy green group, the AEF is now active and making a difference.  It is pro-biotechnology, pro-nuclear power, pro-modern farming, pro-economic growth, pro-business and pro-environment.

It is open to all and driven by its membership rather than its staff.

Importantly it recognises that we live in a complex world where results count.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, August 26, 2006

Takeover talk is nonsense

When you go to buy a loaf of bread, is the nationality of the owner of the shop relevant?  Should government be in the business of deciding who you can and can't buy your bread from?  Is it the role of government to permit an Australian to sell you a loaf of bread, but to prohibit an American from selling you exactly the same loaf of bread?

The answer to all of these questions is yes, according to people like Greens leader Bob Brown, and Dick Smith.

The debate as to whether Coles Myer should be allowed to be taken over by an overseas bidder is, at its core, about these issues.

Discrimination against people because of their background is viewed as abhorrent in practically every social context -- except where that context involves foreign investment.  And then in that case it seems quite acceptable to voice opinions that in any other environment would rightly be regarded as obnoxious.

A few days ago Smith provided his justification as to why the federal government should stop non-Australians buying Coles Myer.  "These foreign owners will immediately start reducing staff numbers -- they'll do everything they can to get wages down so our food will be cheaper and that's what our consumers like.  But, of course, long-term thinking it's bad because we're going to sell off all our wealth and all our profits will head off overseas".

Such thinking is so misconceived it's difficult to know where to begin.  It is exactly the attitude that prevailed in Australia until tariffs were cut in the 1980s.  Sadly, it is this sort of continuing hostility to free trade and the free flow of investment that consigns to poverty hundreds of million of people around the globe.

The cheapest loaf of bread available from Coles costs about $1.60.  Many people shopping at Coles wouldn't particularly notice if the price of bread went up or down by a few cents.  Politicians and successful entrepreneurs probably wouldn't.  But many people would notice the difference.  A person living on an aged pension of $208 a week would notice.  So too would an 18-year-old in casual employment earning $10.70 an hour.  A reduction of a few dollars a week in a family's grocery bill is a few dollars that can either be spent on something else or can be added to household savings.

It is hardly surprising that consumers like cheaper food.  Cheaper food is one way they can improve living standards for themselves and their families.  Households spend on average 20 per cent of their disposable income on food.  As families move up the income scale their spending on food declines as a proportion of their total expenditure.  Put simply, the cost of food is more important to poor people than to rich people.  It is an obvious point, but it is one often forgotten.  If a takeover of Coles Myer results in cheaper food, then all Australians should welcome it.

Businesses should be free to employ as many or as few employees as they think they require.  And if a business is overstaffed, the business should be free to attempt to pass on to customers any higher costs in the form of higher prices.  Customers should be free to pay higher prices to inefficient businesses if they so decide.

However, it is completely wrong for government to attempt to impose such a policy preference on the community.  Yet this is what is suggested by those urging the federal government stop any takeover in the name of protecting jobs.  A system based on jobs created by penalising consumers is a system that in the long run is unsustainable.

The claim that a publicly listed company such as Coles Myer contributes to "our" wealth, and that the company's profits are "our" profits is wrong.  The company is not the government.  We as Australians have no greater claim to Coles Myer than we do to the corner milk bar.  The wealth of the company is not our wealth, and its profits are not our profits -- they are the property of the individual shareholders.

Beyond an emotional attachment to a brand name and a logo there is no national interest at stake in any takeover of Coles Myer by overseas interests.  The best way to protect the national interest is by ensuring competition in the existing Australian supermarket duopoly.  Foreign management might succeed in providing what so far Australian management has not.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, August 25, 2006

Govt to blame for high home prices

Federal Treasurer Peter Costello recently drew attention to high house prices preventing young people getting a foot on the home ownership ladder.  He suggested this might have adverse effects on family formation.  Although there was some initial reaction to the suggestion that land prices were being pushed up by government rationing its availability, other material has been since issued by the Urban Development Institute that corroborates the facts.

Bricks and mortar elements of house prices have barely moved in real terms over a 33-year period.  By contrast, prices of the land component have increased by between a factor of two (Melbourne) to eight in Sydney and as much as 10 in Adelaide.  A block of land on the periphery of Sydney sells for $460,000 with Melbourne being the cheapest of the major capitals at $112,000.  Such price levels are only possible because government regulates land availability by preventing land owners from building houses on their land or selling to others to undertake the building.

This throttling of the availability of land for housing has grown at an accelerating rate over a 50-year period.  It owes nothing to the availability of land -- in Australia urban areas account for only 0.3 per cent of the area.  Nor is it anything to do with infrastructure costs.  The excessive costs are purely due to government rationing of land.  Australian state governments have been progressively increasing the up-front development charges imposed on new housing developments.  HIA put this at over $60,000 for Sydney and the UDIA, using a different accounting methodology put it at twice this level.  The upshot is that government regulations and taxes are forcing up the cost of new houses which are now, in real terms more than twice what they were 30 years ago.

In doing so, the prices of existing houses are boosted making those of us who already own our homes richer compared to those not yet on the ladder:  many of whom, unless policy is changed, will never get a toehold into property ownership.  Present policy is highly discriminatory, and exploitative, towards younger people, few of whom own houses.

The policy changes required include a considerable increase in the land cleared for housing development.  Longer term, all planning restraints, except those preventing land owners from being adversely affected by developments on adjacent properties, should be removed.  In the interests of smaller government, restoring landowner property rights and restoring affordability for those without their own homes governments must accelerate land releases and must cease the discriminatory taxation of new homes.

Thursday, August 24, 2006

No opportunities on the property ladder

In launching a program that featured my book The Tragedy of Planning, the Treasurer Peter Costello drew attention to high house prices preventing young people getting a foot on the home ownership ladder.  He suggested that this might have adverse effects on family formation.

Although there was some initial reaction to the suggestion that land prices were being pushed up by government rationing its availability, other material has been since issued by the Urban Development Institute that corroborates the facts.  The following chart illustrates price developments over the past 30 years.

1973 base2006 real per cent change
over and above CPI
Sydney land100687%
Sydney house100-8%
Melbourne land100130%
Melbourne house10011%
Brisbane land100190%
Brisbane house100-5%
Perth land100543%
Perth house1003%
Adelaide land100995%
Adelaide house10023%

The figures examine price developments in land and the house structure itself over a 33-year period.  This clearly illustrates that the bricks and mortar elements of house prices have barely moved in real terms over the period.  By contrast, prices of the land component have increased by between a factor of two (Melbourne) to eight in Sydney and as much ten in Adelaide.

A block of land on the periphery of Sydney sells for $460,000 with Melbourne being the cheapest of the major capitals at $112,000.  The increase in prices of housing land has taken place in a context where the price of its alternative use, farming land, sells for something like $3,000 per hectare, or $300 per block.  Yet housing land acquisition costs, according to information collected by UrbisJHD is up to $120,000 in Sydney down to a low of $12,000 in Adelaide.

Such price levels are only possible because government regulates land availability by preventing land owners from building houses on their land or selling to others to undertake the building.  This throttling of the availability of land for housing has grown at an accelerating rate over a 50-year period.  It owes nothing to the availability of land -- in Australia urban areas account for only 0.3 per cent of the area.  Nor is it anything to do with infrastructure costs.  It is barely conceivable that in any area within commuting distance from existing urban areas such infrastructure could cost more than $50,000.  In most cases it would be under $30,000 once roads, water, sewerage, planning costs and other land preparation measures have been taken.

The excessive costs are purely due to government rationing of land.  Many areas around the world, including some of the fastest growing municipalities like Houston, Atlanta and many other US cities as well as some slow growing areas (most German cities) have no such rationing.  The outcome is flat real land prices in these places.  Median house prices in Dallas, Houston and Atlanta are under $A180,000 including the land).  And this is in spite of the fact that house construction costs in Australia are lower (indeed among the lowest in the world).

In addition to the scarcity-driven prices of land, Australian state governments have been progressively increasing the up-front development charges imposed on new housing developments.  HIA put this at over $60,000 for Sydney and the UDIA, using a different accounting methodology put it at twice this level.  In many US cities, the developer contribution required is one tenth of this.

The upshot is that government regulations and taxes are forcing up the cost of new houses which are now, in real terms more than twice what they were 30 years ago.  In doing so, the prices of existing houses are boosted making those of us who already own our homes richer compared to those not yet on the ladder:  many of whom, unless policy is changed, will never get a toehold into property ownership.  Present policy is highly discriminatory, and exploitative, towards younger people, few of whom own houses.  It is a sad indictment on governments who claim to represent all their citizens' interests.

In addition, at a more mundane level the regulatory induced price increases are devouring savings (with household savings levels at record lows and even now at negative levels).  This is likely to bring about lower than optimal levels of investment and productivity as years go by.

The policy changes required include a considerable increase in the land cleared for housing development.  Longer term all planning restraints, except those preventing land owners from being adversely affected by developments on adjacent properties, should be removed.  One of the secrets of low German house prices is a constitutional right German landowners have that means they can do with their land as they wish.  The onus is reversed in modern Australia -- the landowner may do nothing with his or her land unless the government gives regulatory approval.  And the extent of the restrictions on use have grown to their present highly intrusive levels.

In the interests of smaller government, restoring landowner property rights and, above all, restoring affordability for those without their own homes governments must accelerate land releases and must cease the discriminatory taxation of new homes.


ADVERTISEMENT

Wednesday, August 23, 2006

Does Western Civilisation Have a Future?

C.D. Kemp Lecture, August 17 2006


I'm honored to be asked to give the C.D. Kemp Lecture before members of the Institute he founded and which lives on after him.  I've been going around Australia for a couple of weeks on what I like to think of as my "Head for the hills!  It's the end of the world!" tour.  But don't worry, it's like Barbra Streisand's farewell tour, I'll be back to do another end-of-the-world tour in a year or two.

Whether or not the western world is ending, it's certainly changed.  It's a very strange feeling from the perspective of four decades on to return to a famous book C D Kemp wrote in 1964, Big Businessmen, a portrait of a now all but extinct generation of Australian industrialists.  They were men whose sense of themselves in relation to the society they lived in was immensely secure.  They had an instinctive belief in the culture that raised them and enriched them.  To have pointed out such a fact at the time would have seemed superfluous:  it was still shared by many forces in society -- bank managers, kindergarten teachers, even Anglican clerics.

None of these pillars of what we used to regard as conventional society is quite as sturdy as it was, and most of them have collapsed.  Many mainstream Protestant churches are, to one degree or another, post-Christian.  If they no longer seem disposed to converting the unbelieving to Christ, they can at least convert them to the boggiest of soft-left political cliches.  In this world, if Jesus were alive today he'd most likely be a gay Anglican vicar in a committed relationship driving around in an environmentally-friendly car with an "Arms Are For Hugging" sticker on the way to an interfaith dialogue with a Wiccan and a couple of Wahhabi imams.

Yet, if the purpose of the modern church is to be a cutting-edge political pacesetter, it's Islam that's doing the better job.  It's easy to look at gold-toothed Punjabi yobs in northern England or Algerian pseudo-rappers in French suburbs and think, oh well, their Muslim identity is clearly pretty residual.  But that's to apply westernised notions of piety.  Today the mosque is a meetinghouse, and throughout the west what it meets to discuss is, even when not explicitly jihadist, always political.  The mosque or madrassah is not the place to go for spiritual contemplation so much as political motivation.  The Muslim identity of those French rioters or English jailbirds may seem spiritually vestigial but it's politically potent.  So, even as a political project, the mainstream Protestant churches are a bust.  Pre-modern Islam beats post-modern Christianity.

As for many teachers, they regard the accumulated inheritance of western civilisation as an unending parade of racism, sexism, imperialism and other malign -isms, leavened only by routine genocides.  Even if this were true -- which it's not -- it's not a good sustaining narrative for any nation unless it's planning on going out of business.

And, speaking of business, even the heirs of those Big Businessmen C D Kemp wrote about feel obliged to join the ranks of the civilisational self-loathers.  I notice that in its commercials the oil company BP -- that's to say, British Petroleum -- now says that BP stands for "Beyond Petroleum":  the ads are all about how it's developing environmentally-friendly ways to conserve energy;  in other words, it's ashamed of the business it's in.

The question posed here tonight is very direct:  "Does Western Civilisation Have A Future?"  One answer's easy:  if western civilisation doesn't have a past, it certainly won't have a future.  No society can survive when it consciously unmoors itself from its own inheritance.  But let me answer it in a less philosophical way:

Much of western civilisation does not have any future.  That's to say, we're not just speaking philosophically, but literally.  In a very short time, France, Belgium, the Netherlands and other countries we regard as part of the western tradition will cease to exist in any meaningful sense.  They don't have a future because they've given up breeding.  Spain's population is halving with every generation:  Two grown-ups have a total of one baby.  So there are half as many children as parents.  And a quarter as many grandchildren as grandparents.  And an eighth as many great-grandchildren as great-grandparents.  And, after that there's no point extrapolating, because you're over the falls and it's too late to start paddling back.  I received a flurry of letters from furious Spaniards when the government decided to replace the words "father" and "mother" on its birth certificates with the less orientationally offensive terms "Progenitor A" and "Progenitor B".  This was part of the bureaucratic spring-cleaning of traditional language that always accompanies the arrival in law of "gay marriage".  But, with historically low numbers of progeny, the designations of the respective progenitors seem of marginal concern.  They'd be better off trying to encourage the average young Spaniard to wander into a Barcelona singles bar and see if anyone wants to come back to his pad to play Progenitor A and Progenitor B.  ("Well, okay, but only if I can be Progenitor A ...")

Seventeen European nations are now at what demographers call "lowest-low" fertility -- 1.3 births per woman, the point at which you're so far down the death spiral you can't pull out.  In theory, those countries will find their population halving every 35 years or so.  In practice, it will be quicker than that, as the savvier youngsters figure there's no point sticking around a country that's turned into an undertaker's waiting room.  So large parts of the western world are literally dying -- and, in Europe, the successor population to those aging French and Dutch and Belgians is already in place.  Perhaps the differences will be minimal.  In France, the Catholic churches will become mosques;  in England, the village pubs will cease serving alcohol;  in the Netherlands, the gay nightclubs will close up shop and relocate to San Francisco.  But otherwise life will go on much as before.  The new Europeans will be observant Muslims instead of post-Christian secularists but they will still be recognisably European:  It will be like Cats after a cast change:  same long-running show, new actors, but the plot, the music, the sets are all the same.  The animating principles of advanced societies are so strong that they will thrive whoever's at the switch.

But what if they don't?  In the 2005 rankings of Freedom House's survey of personal liberty and democracy around the world, five of the eight countries with the lowest "freedom" score were Muslim.  Of the 46 Muslim majority nations in the world, only three were free.  Of the 16 nations in which Muslims form between 20 and 50 per cent of the population, only another three were ranked as free:  Benin, Serbia and Montenegro, and Suriname.  It will be interesting to follow France's fortunes as a fourth member of that group.

If you think a nation is no more than a "great hotel" (as the Canadian novelist Yann Martel described his own country, approvingly), you can always slash rates and fill the empty rooms -- for as long as there are any would-be lodgers left out there to move in.  But there aren't going to be many would-be immigrants out there in the years ahead -- not for aging western societies in which an ever smaller pool of young people pay ever higher taxes to support ever swelling geriatric native populations.  And, if you believe a nation is the collective, accumulated wisdom of a shared past, then a dependence on immigration alone for population replenishment will leave you lost and diminished.  That's why Peter Costello's stirring call -- a boy for you, a girl for me, and one for Australia -- is, ultimately, a national security issue -- and a more basic one than how much you spend on defence.

Americans take for granted all the "it's about the future of all our children" hooey that would ring so hollow in a European election.  In the 2005 German campaign, voters were offered what would be regarded in the US as a statistically improbable choice:  a childless man (Herr Schroeder) vs a childless woman (Frau Merkel).  Statist Europe signed on to Hillary Rodham Clinton's alleged African proverb -- "It takes a village to raise a child" -- only to discover they got it backwards:  on the Continent, the lack of children will raze the village.  And most of the villagers still refuse to recognise the contradictions:  You can't breed at the lethargic rate of most Europeans and then bitch and whine about letting the Turks into the European Union.  Demographically, they're the kids you couldn't be bothered having.

One would assume a demographic disaster is the sort of thing that sneaks up on you because you're having a grand old time:  You stayed in university till you were 38, you took early retirement at 45, you had two months a year on the Cote d'Azur, you drank wine, you ate foie gras and truffles, you marched in the street for a 28-hour work week ... It was all such great fun there was no time to have children.  You thought the couple in the next street would, or the next town, or in all those bucolic villages you pass through on the way to your weekend home.

But the strange thing is that Europeans aren't happy.  The Germans are so slumped in despond that in 2005 the government began running a Teutonic feelgood marketing campaign in which old people are posed against pastoral vistas, fetching young gays mooch around the Holocaust memorial, Katarina Witt stands in front of some photogenic moppets, etc., and then they all point their fingers at the camera and shout "Du bist Deutschland!" -- "You are Germany!" -- which is meant somehow to pep up glum Hun couch potatoes.  Can't see it working myself.  The European Union got rid of all the supposed obstacles to happiness -- war, politics, the burden of work, insufficient leisure time, tiresome dependents -- and yet their people are strikingly unhappy.  Consider this poll taken in 2002 for the first anniversary of 9/11:  61 per cent of Americans said they were optimistic about the future, as opposed to 43 per cent of Canadians, 42 per cent of Britons, 29 per cent of the French, 23 per cent of Russians and 15 per cent of Germans.  I wouldn't reckon those numbers will get any cheerier over the years.

What's the most laughable article published in a major American newspaper in the last decade?  A good contender is a New York Times column by the august Princeton economist Paul Krugman.  The headline was "French Family Values", and the thesis is that, while parochial American conservatives drone on about "family values", the Europeans live it, enacting policies that are more "family friendly".  On the Continent, claims Professor Krugman, "government regulations actually allow people to make a desirable tradeoff -- to modestly lower income in return for more time with friends and family".

How can an economist make that claim without noticing that the upshot of all these "family friendly" policies is that nobody has any families?  Isn't the first test of a profamily regime its impact on families?

As for all that extra time, what happened?  Europeans work fewer hours than Americans, they don't have to pay for their own health care, they don't go to church and they don't contribute to other civic groups, they don't marry and they don't have kids to take to school and basketball and the county fair.

So what do they do with all the time?

Forget for the moment Europe's lack of world-beating companies:  They regard capitalism red in tooth and claw as an Anglo-American fetish, and they mostly despise it.  And in fairness some of their quasi-state corporations are very pleasant:  I'd much rather fly Air France than United or Continental.  But what about the things Europeans supposedly value?  With so much free time, where is the great European art?  Assuredly Gershwin and Bernstein aren't Bach and Mozart, but what have the Continentals got?  Their pop culture is more American than it's ever been.  Fifty years ago, before European welfarism had them in its vise-like death grip, the French had better pop songs and the Italians made better movies.  Where are Europe's men of science?  At American universities.

Meanwhile, Continental governments pour fortunes into prestigious white elephants of Euro-identity, like the Airbus 380, the QE2 of the skies, capable of carrying 500, 800, a thousand passengers at a time, if only somebody somewhere would order the damn thing, which they might consider doing once all the airports have built new runways to handle it.  Don't get me wrong, I'm sure it's a swell idea.  It'll come in very useful for large-scale evacuation operations circa 2015.

"When life becomes an extended picnic, with nothing of importance to do", writes Charles Murray in In Our Hands, "ideas of greatness become an irritant.  Such is the nature of the Europe syndrome." The Continent has embraced a spiritual death long before the demographic one.  In those 17 Europeans countries which have fallen into "lowest-low fertility", where are the children?  In a way, you're looking at them:  the guy sipping espresso at a sidewalk café listening to his iPod.  Free citizens of advanced western democracies are increasingly the world's wrinkliest teenagers:  the state makes the grown-up decisions and we spend our pocket money on our record collection.  Hilaire Belloc, incidentally, foresaw this very clearly in his book The Servile State in 1912 -- before teenagers or record collections had been invented.  He understood that the long-term cost of a softened state is the infantilisation of the population.  The populations of wealthy democratic societies expect to be able to choose from dozens of breakfast cereals at the supermarket, thousands of movies at the video store, and millions of porn sites on the Internet, yet think it perfectly normal to demand that the state take care of their elderly parents and their young children while they're working -- to, in effect, surrender what most previous societies would have regarded as all the responsibilities of adulthood.  It's a curious inversion of citizenship to demand control over peripheral leisure activities but to contract out the big life-changing stuff to the government.  And it's hard to come up with a wake-up call for a society as dedicated as latter-day Europe to the belief that life is about sleeping in.

Australia has more economic freedom than the EU and fewer distorting demographic problems, so, along with America, it's one of the two countries with a sporting chance of avoiding the perfect storm about to engulf the rest of the west.  But at some point it too will have to confront these issues -- not just the falling birth rate and aging population, but the underlying civilisational ennui of which the big lack of babies is merely the most obvious symptom.  I feel bad running around like a headless chicken shrieking about this stuff.  But let's face it, scaremongering is the default mode of the age.  We worry incessantly, because worrying is the way the responsible citizen of an advanced society demonstrates his virtue:  He feels good about feeling bad.  So he worries mostly about what offers the best opportunities for self-loathing -- climate change, or the need to increase mostly harmful foreign aid to African dictatorships.  This is a kind of decadence.  September 11th 2001 was not "the day everything changed", but the day that revealed how much had already changed.  On September 10th, how many journalists had the Council of American-Islamic Relations or the Canadian Islamic Congress or the Muslim Council of Britain in their rolodexes?  If you'd said that whether something does or does not cause offence to Muslims would be the early 21st century's principal political dynamic in Denmark, Sweden, the Netherlands, Belgium, France and the United Kingdom, most folks would have thought you were crazy.  Yet on that Tuesday morning the top of the iceberg bobbed up and toppled the Twin Towers.

But it's important to remember:  radical Islam is only the top-eighth of that iceberg -- it's an opportunist enemy taking advantage of a demographically declining and spiritually decayed west.  The real issue is the seven-eighths below the surface -- the larger forces at play in the developed world that have left Europe too enfeebled to resist its remorseless transformation into Eurabia and call into question the future of much of the rest of the world.  The key factors are:

  1. Demographic decline;
  2. The unsustainability of the social democratic state;
  3. Civilisational exhaustion.

None of these is Islam's fault.  They're self-inflicted.  If you doubt that, forget about fast Islamifying Europe and look at the most geriatric jurisdiction on the planet.  In Japan, the rising sun has already passed into the next phase of its long sunset:  net population loss.  2005 was the first year since records began in which the country had more deaths than births.  Japan offers the chance to observe the demographic death spiral in its purest form.  It's a country with no immigration, no significant minorities and no desire for any:  just the Japanese, aging and dwindling.

At first it doesn't sound too bad:  compared with the United States, most advanced societies are very crowded.  If you're in a cramped apartment in a noisy congested city, losing a couple of hundred thousand people seems a fine trade-off.  The difficulty, in a modern social democratic state, is managing which people to lose:  already, according to The Japan Times, depopulation is "presenting the government with pressing challenges on the social and economic front, including ensuring provision of social security services and securing the labor force".  For one thing, the shortage of children has led to a shortage of obstetricians.  Why would any talented ambitious med. school student want to go into a field in such precipitous decline?  Birthing is a dying business.

At the beginning of the century, the country's toymakers noticed they had a problem:  toys are for children and Japan doesn't have many.  What to do?  In 2005, Tomy began marketing a new doll called Yumel -- a baby boy with a range of 1,200 phrases designed to serve as companions for the elderly.  He says not just the usual things -- "I wuv you" -- but also asks the questions your grandchildren would ask if you had any:  "Why do elephants have long noses?" Yumel joins his friend, the Snuggling Ifbot, a toy designed to have the conversation of a five-year old child which its makers, with the usual Japanese efficiency, have determined is just enough chit-chat to prevent the old folks going senile.  It seems an appropriate final comment on the social democratic state:  in a childish infantilised self-absorbed society where adults have been stripped of core responsibilities, you need never stop playing with toys.  We are the children we never had.

And why leave it at that?  Is it likely an ever smaller number of young people will want to spend their active years looking after an ever greater number of old people?  Or will it be simpler to put all that cutting-edge Japanese technology to good use and take a flier on Mister Roboto and the post-human future?  After all, what's easier for the governing class?  Weaning a pampered population off the good life and re-teaching them the lost biological impulse or giving the Sony Corporation a license to become the Cloney Corporation?  If you need to justify it to yourself, you'd grab the graphs and say, well, demographic decline is universal.  It's like industrialisation a couple of centuries back;  everyone will get to it eventually, but the first to do so will have huge advantages:  the relevant comparison is not with England's early 19th century population surge but with England's industrial revolution.  In the industrial age, manpower was critical.  In the new technological age, manpower will be optional -- and indeed, if most of the available manpower's alienated young Muslim men, it may well be a disadvantage.  As the most advanced society with the most advanced demographic crisis, Japan seems likely to be the first jurisdiction to embrace robots and cloning and embark on the slippery slope to transhumanism.

The advantage Australians and Americans have is that most of the rest of the west is ahead of us:  their canoes are already on the brink of the falls.  But Australians who want their families to enjoy the blessings of life in a free society should understand that the life we've led since 1945 in the western world is very rare in human history.  Our children are unlikely to enjoy anything so placid, and may well spend their adult years in an ugly and savage world in which ever more parts of the map fall prey to the reprimitivisation that's afflicted Liberia, Somalia and Bosnia.

If it's difficult to focus on long-term trends because human life is itself short-term, think short-term:  Huge changes are happening now.  For states in demographic decline with ever more lavish social programs and ever less civilisational confidence, the question is a simple one:  Can they get real?  Can they grow up before they grow old?  If not, then western civilisation will go the way of all others that failed to meet a simple test:  as Ralph Waldo Emerson wrote in 1870, "Nature has made up her mind that what cannot defend itself shall not be defended".

End of the great first-home dream

When Miguel de Cervantes, the most famous figure in Spanish literature and creator of Don Quixote wrote, "There are only two families in the world.  The Haves and the Have-nots", he might well have been talking about the state of the Australian housing market.

History abounds with examples where the Haves of the world have used their influence to dictate how and where the Have-nots should live.

In Australia, the exercise of that influence is being profoundly felt in connection with the development of our cities and suburbs.

Over the past few decades we have seen "nimbyism" (not-in-my-backyard) emerge as a powerful force where those who live in pleasant places exercise their collective voice to exclude both the people and projects they consider unfit to join them.

Next came the "banana" brigade (build-absolutely-nothing-anywhere-near-anything), an anti-development movement focused not so much on the identity of potential neighbours but more on what their neighbours could or should build in order to maintain the "amenity" of the area.

While this resistance and the regulation spawned by these movements unquestionably added cost and complication to the lives of young Australian families simply wanting a home of their own, much worse was to come with the arrival of the urban-consolidation culturists -- the "consolidati".

Unlike the nimby and banana brigades before them, the consolidati took it one step further by stopping development miles from where they either live or visit.  In particular, they sought to limit expansion of the outer suburban fringe where for generations young Australian families have purchased cheap land and established their first homes.

Armed with an ideology based on a romantic but flawed notion of life in European cities, the influence of this urban consolidation has been vast.  It was their contention that in addition to the cultural and social benefits of higher-density living it would reduce infrastructure costs, be good for the environment and ultimately force people out of their cars and on to public transport.

Initially, the social and economic impacts of urban consolidation were gentle, but as the rationing effect kicked in and the stock of land available for housing dwindled, land prices began to rise at an alarming rate.  This increase led to a surge in the price of housing which brought joy to the privileged Haves who lived within the city bounds but despair for the Have-nots who were still to realise their great Australian dream.

Since 2000, the median price of housing in Australian cities has more than doubled, putting home ownership far beyond the reach of low and middle-income Australians.  Where, in most Australian cities, the historic median house price was three times the annual median household income, this leapt to more than six times median household income in most cities and to nearly nine times in Sydney.  This is a disaster for families trying to build their first home.

As the price of housing has soared in recent years, some have argued that it is not land-supply problems that have caused the price rise but demand factors such as low interest rates, capital-gains tax exemptions, negative gearing and first-home buyer grants that have been responsible.  This claim, however, is at complete odds with international evidence and basic supply/ demand economics.  Housing affordability -- or first-home ownership, is about "entry level", and entry-level housing happens on the urban fringe.  If you restrict supply at the entry point, up goes price and down goes affordability.

It is important to remember that the scarcity that propelled land prices is artificial.  It is the product of ideology-driven planning regulation aimed at curbing the size of our cities and ramping up urban densities.  Any talk of "land shortages" is absurd -- as we all know, there is abundant land in Australia suitable for housing.

The impact of this perverse policy has been that the Haves are now much richer and the Have-nots are further from reaching their home-ownership dream than ever before.  For those on middle and low incomes the prospect of ever becoming homeowners has all but evaporated, and they face the prospect of being lifetime renters.  The intergenerational inequity created by this imbalance may not be evident at the moment, but in time it sure will be.

One need only consider the long-term social and economic costs of many in the next generation reaching retirement without the security or economic capacity home-ownership affords to realise that we have a very serious problem on our hands.  The Have-nots are not only priced out of the housing market, they are also denied access to the means through which most Australians acquire personal wealth -- a home of their own.

While the promises of urban consolidation were grand, the results have proven to be disastrous.  Australian National University professor Patrick Troy predicted that this policy would not lead to green streets but instead to "mean" streets.  He was right.  Urban consolidation has not led to a more sustainable environment, it has led to an increasingly barren one.

The impact on families has also been terrible, as small backyards leave no room for trees to grow or for children to run and play.

Promises about infrastructure savings have also failed to materialise with the cost of renewing or upgrading services in the inner-city to cope with increased population densities proving to be more expensive than establishing brand-new services on the fringe.  And the claim that urban consolidation would move people out of their cars and on to public transport has also proven false.

While higher-density living near to the heart of the city is a perfectly legitimate option for those who seek a particular social or cultural lifestyle, it is also true that "four white pegs in the middle of nowhere" has been the starting point for countless Australians pursuing their dream of owning a simple decent home.

The capacities of people to become homeowners vary and it is simply not right for the home-ownership aspirations of those with the least means to be dashed by the influence of those with the greatest means who seek to determine how and where others should live.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, August 19, 2006

Green group wants practical policies

I've heard environmentalism described as a quasi-religious blend of new-age nature worship, junk science, left-wing political activism and anti-profit economics.

But while this description may apply to some deep green activists, it's also true to say that we are all environmentalists nowadays.

We all want to do our bit for biodiversity, to conserve water and energy.

But unfortunately most Australians have little say in the environmental policies being put to Government.

These policies are almost exclusively the domain of a tight network of conservation groups with a particular world view.

For example, the Wilderness Society's current campaign against broad scale tree clearing ignores the long history of land management in Australia.

Aborigines used fire to favour grassland over forest across vast areas of western NSW.

Remove fire from this landscape, introduce sheep and cattle, and it is not surprising that invasive woody weeds are a problem.

But The Wilderness Society doesn't even acknowledge the woody weed management problem, let alone propose a long term solution.

Not surprisingly the group finds itself at odds with pastoralists and croppers who want to keep their land manageable and productive.

Many environmental groups have an in principle problem with active land management and resource use.

They agitate to get foresters out of forests and to close down productive fisheries.

Some irrigators have come to understand that it doesn't matter how much water they give back for environmental flow, environmental groups will always want more.

Many of theses established environmental groups emerged from the protest movement of the 1960s and 70s.

At that time there was over-exploitation, but the pendulum has now swung in the other direction and Government policies tend to favour conservation over sustainable resource use.

The Dean of Science at the University of NSW, Mike Archer, is among those with a different slant on environmental thinking.  He is pleading for what he describes as "the revolution we must have -- between the ears and on the land".

A couple of years ago some farmers, foresters, fishers, university professors and others, got together in Ballarat to start a new environment group, the Australian Environment Foundation (AEF) -- an environment group that believes in taking an evidence-based approach to issues.

I belong to the AEF, which holds its first conference in Brisbane next month, where Dr Archer will be a keynote speaker.

We are hoping practical environmentalists will come from all over Australia.

For more information visit the AEF website.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, August 18, 2006

Education fails history lesson

The Australian History Summit, which will take place today in Canberra, is an initiative designed to strengthen the place and maintain the integrity of Australian history in the school curriculum.  It is long overdue.

Its genesis lies in the Prime Minister's Australia Day address earlier this year, at which he warned that young people would be at risk of "being disinherited from their community if that community lacks the courage and confidence to teach its history".

The Prime Minister's speech was almost instantly attacked by critics claiming that the type of history he would like to impose was triumphalist, old-fashioned and boring.  His proposed focus on names and dates would come at the expense of students learning to "understand".

Furthermore, it was suggested that the old critics of modern history teaching were behind the times and needed to embrace the new approaches being taught in schools.

Well, far from being an old critic, I graduated from high school a little over 16 years ago, when many of these new approaches were just starting to come into vogue.

The history education I received at school during this time as a result can only be described as a patchy, incoherent, terrible mess.

The role of women in our colonial past was explored in some detail, but how Australia became a nation during federation was barely touched on.

Not only was there no studying of the ancient Greeks, there was not even any acknowledgment of World War II.

The end result of my formal school education was to indeed feel "disinherited" from my community, not to mention angry and betrayed by the education system that allowed this to happen.

However, in spite of this, I can probably count myself lucky that I was educated when I was.  The tales regularly coming from schools now point to the teaching of history going even further downhill since this time, ruining the education of countless children.  Thus, it is important that the teaching of history in schools be remedied as soon as possible.

Contrary to the claims made by advocates of the new approach to history teaching, a structured narrative with the learning of names and dates is not boring, irrelevant, or a substitute for understanding.

Rather, it is necessary to put what is being learned into a broader context and hence allow the actual goal of understanding to take place.

It is also critically important to ensure that students gain an appreciation of where as a society we have come from.  Every school student should gain an appreciation of the growth and development of Western civilisation, from the Greeks and Romans, the rise of Christendom, the enlightenment, the gradual growth of freedom and democracy, and a comprehensive history of Australia both pre- and post-settlement.

Many history teachers will undoubtedly disagree that the teaching of Western civilisation should have a privileged position in the curriculum.

However, the reality is that Australia is a Western nation in the Judeo-Christian tradition, and we should not be ashamed of this fact as many left-wing teachers and commentators seem to believe.

One of the major problems with history teaching today is that too few students actually have a proper appreciation of what an extraordinary and unique achievement the modern West, and Australia as a part of it, actually is.  Instead, they are all too frequently uncritically taught that their cultural inheritance is a story of shame, murder, and colonial oppression.

The reality, however, is that Australia and the broader West have a proud, although not unblemished history, that has nonetheless culminated in societies with levels of freedom, prosperity, and human rights not even remotely parallelled elsewhere in human history.  Very few of those who attack the alleged superiority of Western culture, never mind a privileged position for it in the curriculum, would themselves ever want to live in anything other than a modern liberal democratic nation like Australia.

In short, such people are hypocrites.

This is not to suggest that we should uncritically teach a merely triumphalist form of history.  The story of Australia and the West is far from perfect -- in common with the rest of the world it is a story of mistakes, of terrible periods of bloodshed, mayhem, murder and oppression -- all of this should also be taught, warts and all.  However, it is also important to keep a sense of perspective.

In spite of the blacker parts of our history, we are incredibly fortunate to be living in a society where we actually have the freedom to acknowledge those mistakes and to try to correct them -- something most people living in our world still do not have at present.

This is also not to suggest that other areas of history, such as that relating to other nations and cultures, or even particular themes within our own culture, should not be taught.

But the teaching of these other areas of history should not come at the cost of neglecting the core narrative of Western society and Australia's part in it, which is what's happening at the moment.  Given current world events, it is more important than ever that all Australians get at least a basic grounding in their own civilisational heritage and what a unique and valuable achievement it has been, even if it's not a perfect one.

If our future generations do not see it as something valuable and even, if necessary, worth fighting for, we may in the end run the risk of losing it.


ADVERTISEMENT

Bumpy road that's paved with failure

The financial collapse of any car parts maker received front page headlines not so long ago.  But they have become so regular that such news is almost expected.  The latest business to go under is Melbourne's Ajax Engineered Fasteners.  It supplies parts to Ford and Holden.  Two hundred jobs are on the line.

But there's a bigger story.  What we are witnessing is the steady elimination of the car parts sector in Australia.  It is doubtful much will remain in five years.  What's likely to follow in a decade is the closure of one, and possibly two, of the big four car makers.  On current trends, it appears inevitable.

What has caused the collapses is not fully explained by the reduction in car tariffs.  An equal contributor is the inability of companies to manage their operations to peak efficiency.

Ajax's owners indicated that the pricing arrangements demanded by their customers made it uneconomic for them to operate.  This is common in the sector.  But the story behind this reveals what has created the industry sickness.  It is largely because of failed management and industrial relations cultures.

When the car industry was confronted with tariff reductions in the 1980s, it responded well, committing to improvements in design, quality and standards.  The industry has become world-competitive in many areas.

But the biggest failure has been in the management of workforce issues.  Initially, the big four makers were able to convince unions and workers to adopt considerable change, to allow new production technologies to operate efficiently.

They also outsourced most parts.  The industry is supposed to operate like a river.  Specialised parts makers feed the car assembly plants.  But the entire process stops if one parts maker stops.  The industry's smart new approach to manufacturing is also its greatest weakness.

This is where industrial relations has come into play.  The parts makers generally have terrible industrial relations cultures and agreements.  They have experienced strikes whenever they have tried to fix their problems.  The big four car makers have always applied pressure to end strikes.

Consequently, work practices that prevent maximum efficiency have become entrenched.  Parts makers have become wary of spending money on technology when they can't operate properly.

The big four have also demanded yearly price decreases.  Unable to extract the high levels of productivity increases needed to sustain the reductions, the local parts industry has hit the wall.  Many makers saw it coming.

About two years ago, most Australian parts makers began setting up factories overseas, designed to compete with local factories.  Parts makers who have not followed the strategy are not surviving.  The result is the elimination of the Australian car parts sector.

But the big four car makers don't have a rosy situation either.  Some have failed to create work cultures needed to respond to fast-moving market demands.  With the death of the domestic car parts sector, the big four makers will buy parts from overseas.  They will continue to demand lower prices.  This may enable them to kick along for a while, but at some stage entrenched, unresponsive work practices will eat into operations.

Unfortunately, the Government's workplace changes have come too late.  Some of the big four have internal management cultures that will prevent them from using the reforms to fix their problems.  They are at risk.

Others will use the opportunities to improve work practices.  This will not guarantee them success, but it should give them a chance.


ADVERTISEMENT

Wednesday, August 16, 2006

Compo drives NSW exodus

If you were thinking of visiting a country and saw on television a huge refugee exodus from that country, you'd be cautious about visiting.  Surely if the locals are running away there must be something dangerous about the place?

The New South Wales Government is doing a business promotion exercise in Queensland.  "Come to NSW!" they say.  But the problem is there's a business exodus from NSW to Queensland.

What do the NSW residents know that is causing them to leave?

Some simple stories tell the truth.

June Gibson is a suburban mum.  Her husband, David, is a bricklayer or at least he was until NSW workers compensation laws put him out of business.

June and David live in Gosford.  Like most self-employed people in the building industry if David had a job, he'd call on other self-employed bricklayer mates to help him.  They paid workers compensation premiums on the labourers they employed.  But they weren't required to pay premiums on the self-employed bricklayers.  They'd had several audits by the workcover authority over the years and everything was OK.

In early 2004 they had another audit.  They received a bill for $52,000 demanding premium payment on the self-employed bricklayers they'd used over the past seven years.  They were shocked.  They would have to re-mortgage their house.

They said this was unfair and refused to pay.  They were refused workers compensation cover until they paid.  This meant David could not work.  He had to close his business.  Their retirement plans have been destroyed.

The local newspaper ran a story.  June was swamped by people in the same situation.  She formed a committee and lobbied politicians.  June and David have had their bill reduced to $10,000.

The same thing has happened to others who have run public campaigns.  But June won't pay.  She says the NSW workers compensation laws are a mess.  She is correct.

If you are self-employed in NSW you are not allowed to register for workers compensation.  If you use a self-employed person you are not supposed to pay premiums on them.  But the definition of who is self-employed is confusing.  Even the auditors don't agree.

The outcome is that hundreds of thousands of small businesses in NSW live in a legal grey-zone always fearful of facing June and David's situation.  With fear like this it's hard doing business.

But it's only one reason why NSW business people shift to Queensland.

NSW has "unfair" contract laws that have turned the NSW Industrial Relations Commission into a super policeman of business.

The laws don't apply to employees but to commercial contracts.  Commercial disputes are handled as if they are industrial relations disputes.  It's created massive confusion on tenancy leases, franchising and many commercial contract situations.  Normal commercial law has been dumped and no one can be sure where they stand.

There's still more.  NSW work safety laws are dangerous.  If an accident occurs the employer is automatically guilty.  Un-proving guilt is almost impossible.  Appeals are prohibited.

Employees have little responsibility even if they cause an accident.  Unions can and do prosecute and keep half the fines.  Banks have suffered work safety prosecutions after bank robberies.  The robbers have presumption of innocence.  The businesses have presumption of guilt.  Normal justice has been eliminated in NSW.

The Government has proposed changing some of the laws but is still prosecuting people under the existing unjust laws.  These are just a few examples of a deep cancer that is repeated in almost every area of NSW business regulation.

Laws in NSW don't give business clarity.  Justice is too often dependent on striking the right deal with the right union or political faction.

If you're high profile you might receive a better deal than someone else.  "Mates" are favoured over truth, and clear and consistent policy.

The outcome is that the cost of doing business in NSW is always unknown.  June, her husband, David, and all their friends are now fearful of doing business in NSW.

Big business is in the same situation.

This is why NSW has become the business refugee source of Australia.

The best advice for Queensland business people is to stay put and enjoy the more certain business climate.


ADVERTISEMENT

The whole world must be the story

Even the most hardened summit-sceptic would have to acknowledge that the calling of this week's history summit has already produced a number of positive outcomes.

First, it has exposed for all to see how the intellectual Left in Australia have no capacity at all to make a judgment about where the political "centre" might be.  This failing was best demonstrated by Guy Rundle, who allocated political labels to the summit participants, in an item for the Crikey web site.

Rundle's category of "Right-activist" even managed to include former NSW Labor premier, Bob Carr.  Carr may overall be on the Right of the Labor Party, but he does have Gough Whitlam as his great political hero and has conventional Left positions on issues such as climate change.

However, in Rundle's world, if you are to Rundle's right you become a Right activist.  Perhaps Rundle should pause to consider how few Australians would actually be to the Left of the political centre under his definitions.

By its stated aim to return to the "essential facts, dates and events that every student should know", the summit has also brought in to the open those historians who actually wear their lack of knowledge of any historical facts as a badge of honour.  Thus, La Trobe University history research fellow, Clare Wright, appeared in The Age patronising the "ordinary folks (who) take their knowledge claims extremely seriously".  It may not have occurred to Wright, but the "ordinary folks" have actually worked out that acquiring "knowledge claims" (presumably this is academic jargon for facts) can actually be fun.

Wright claims virtue for being the product of "a thoroughly post-modern education, schooled to seek and interpret a multiplicity of voices, competing narratives and diverse texts".  Yet, in reality, a historian who interprets history without a grasp of the facts is akin to an architect trying to design a building without any understanding of what facts actually make the building stand up.

Among all the positives the summit will produce, however, there is still some cause for concern.  Speaking on ABC radio recently, Education Minister Julie Bishop said:  "Australian history should be a critical part of the school curriculum, it should at least be a stand-alone subject, and compulsory to say Year 10.  I think we should have a great deal of pride in our nation's history, and to ensure we have more informed citizens, they need to have a greater understanding of our nation's past".

The Minister is correct that history should be a critical part of the school curriculum, but should this be solely Australian history?  There is no doubt a need to address, as Gregory Melleuish has done in the paper he has prepared for the summit, the perennial complaint about Australian history that it is not interesting because it lacks the wars, violence and revolutions of other countries.

Like Melleuish, my own historical interest has largely been focused on Australian history.  But trying to prevent the Left having a walkover victory in the Australian "history wars" in the nation's classrooms, does not mean that the history of the rest of the world should be forgotten as Australian children of the 21st century take their places in an increasingly globalised environment.  If a student's knowledge of World War I is confined to Gallipoli, or of World War II to Kokoda, the balance is definitely wrong.

If a student leaves an Australian secondary school with quite a detailed understanding of how the Chinese were treated on an Australian goldfield, but no appreciation of the significance of China as a country throughout history, then there is a problem.  Space must be left in the history curriculum for Alexander the Great, Joan of Arc and Mao Zedong.  It is surely more important to know about Napoleon Bonaparte than Edmund Barton.

He would be too modest to suggest this, but the answer may lie with one of the summit participants.  If all students had, by the end of Year 10, read and learned the facts in Geoffrey Blainey's A Short History of the World, as well as his Shorter History of Australia they would at least have a reasonable starting point.  For Rundle this would be outrageously "Right activist" and for Wright it would lack "multiplicity of voices", but it would leave many students much better equipped than they are today.


ADVERTISEMENT

Sunday, August 13, 2006

Fair-trade coffee only brews more poverty

More and more consumer goods are proudly displaying the "fair trade" moniker.  Shops are now proudly presenting the fair-trade brand in catalogues, shopfronts and websites.

It's branded on clothes, chocolate, soccer balls and its most prominent vanguard, coffee.  In the United States, Wal-Mart -- regularly attacked by self-anointed "progressives" for its sale of cheap free-trade imports -- has started stocking fair-trade coffee.  Starbucks has been doing so for years.  McDonald's recently announced it is now following suit.  Fair trade has become the new chic brand to appease Western consumer guilt.

Critics claim unregulated free trade undermines labour standards, ensures cheap wages and delivers little to anyone but big multinational corporations.  They argue that laissez-faire trade is essentially tipped in favour of the rich, against the poor.

In opposition, the fair-trade campaign aims to create a level playing field that tips the rules of the game in favour of the poor, through stabilised wages, prices and profits to producers and workers.  Marketed as a means for consumers to "satisfy their palate and their conscience at the same time", it is a wildly distorted campaign of misdiagnosis and misrepresentation.

Certainly consumers are welcome to purchase "social justice" with their morning latte.  But rather than aiding development, the fair-trade coffee campaign implicitly promotes a return to the managed trade system in coffee that has hindered coffee-producing developing nations since the 1960s.

The fair-trade campaign aims to manage the international coffee trade by fixing prices at $US1.26 ($1.64) per pound and eventually fixing supply.  In doing so, it is similar to the former International Coffee Agreement established in 1963.  The ICA was developed by a UN agency, the International Coffee Organisation, to manage trade for developing countries and provide an industry to grow a product that could be exported to rich countries.  The ICA stabilised prices through quotas and controlled supply.  When there was an excess of supply, surplus coffee was destroyed or withheld to ensure the price never fell.  The result was endemic corruption as dictators in developing countries doled out coffee-growing licences to mates or the highest bidder.

In 1989 the ICA collapsed with the end of the Cold War and so did its controls.  Coffee production exploded as opportunities for individuals and countries previously locked out established production.  Brazil alone doubled its output.  New countries entered the market, including Vietnam, which increased its production tenfold.  Textbook economics applied then as now -- when supply outstripped demand, prices plummeted.  By 1992 coffee futures had bottomed and supply had massively outgrown demand.

Concurrent to the bottoming of the market, consumer consumption of coffee went through a renaissance, particularly in the United States.  The exemplar of the trend is the now common international trademark, Starbucks.  Starbucks changed coffee consumption in the world's largest economy from a standard "cup of joe" to a personalised coffee experience;  and they paid a premium for it.  While consumer prices rose for soy-macchiatos, little of the benefit flowed to producers in developing countries.

Critics cited the high consumer prices coupled with the bottoming of the market wholesale price as evidence of the failure of the free market.  To lift prices for developing countries NGOs proposed a repackaged form of the old managed-trade system -- fair trade.

In an influential 2002 report, Mugged:  Poverty in your coffee cup, Oxfam International dubbed the lowered prices as a "coffee crisis".  Yet, comparing current low prices against old ICA prices is simply naive.  The ICA artificially inflated prices and locked producers out, keeping prices high to the benefit of a select few -- certainly not the poor.  It did not tie price with demand or quality, just the relationships of producers to those doling out the licences.

Rather than blaming the tired, corrupt ICA system for inflating prices, Oxfam has ferociously attacked corporations who buy coffee from the producers and retailers, blaming them for the low prices.  By blaming excess profit, the campaign makes for good populist politics but ignores reality.  The actual coffee component in your latte amounts only to between 5 and 7 per cent of the total cost, outstripped by double-digit labour and rental costs.

Fair-trade rules can actually work against poor producers.  Enterprising individuals are excluded -- perhaps reflecting the dominant ideology of the movement, fair-trade coffee is only purchased from collectives.

Collectives are supposed to be established along democratic lines where individual producers trade their product as part of a collective agreement, but with a fixed price there is no opportunity to leverage higher prices.  Nor is there any incentive for each producer to deliver a better-quality product when theirs is not differentiated from other collective members.  Returns are distributed according to collective decision, presenting opportunities for cronyism and preferential deals based on personal and political relationships.

Despite its shortcomings, the fair-trade campaign has caught on with left-wing activists and it has become central to social-justice campaigns such as Make Poverty History.

But years after it was introduced it has failed to attract consumer support.  In 2004 Starbucks' total sales of fair-trade coffee amounted to 1.6 per cent of its total coffee sales.  It sells it only in 17 countries, despite operating stores in twice that number of countries.  Unsurprisingly those countries are almost entirely in the developed world.  An internal Oxfam Australia report shows it is worth only $2 million.  Internationally it is only worth $US87 million of the total $US10 billion trade.

Using emotive language, Oxfam claims coffee companies are "exploiting Third World farmers".  This is a deliberate tactic to play on the middle-class guilt of consumers in developed countries who have escaped poverty.  What Oxfam ignores is that developed countries have escaped poverty because they chose the decentralised, wealth-creating free-market system.  Oxfam's repackaged managed-trade system, now branded as fair trade, is the same system that has locked out the wealth-creating potential of developing countries.

Economic development for poor countries is essential.  The best means to achieve it is to ensure that market-flexible, competitive industries are established to provide sustainable avenues for employment and wealth creation.  When this is done countries will be able to use the wealth-creating opportunities of trade to export into rich countries.

Fair trade, or any other attempt to engineer global commerce, will not achieve this.  Oxfam and other fair-trade advocates want us to focus our consumer dollar on buying from their select few collectives.  They want our consumer dollar to go a shorter distance, not a longer one.  The benefits will flow to these select few who get it, but it will be devastating for the people it misses.  They will be the people who never got employed in a job consumers never created for failing to spread our limited resources wider.

The fair-trade campaign misses the point of why products are cheap and its "remedy" will do nothing to help the material lot of the world's poorest.  The best solution to fix the state of coffee prices is to allow market forces to decide the price, not reinstitute managed trade.

Blind devotion to "fair" trade will only lock up coffee production again for the select few.  As an alternative to the trade liberalisation model of development, it is sorely wanting.


ADVERTISEMENT

Batchelor plan is driving against the traffic

Throughout the world buses, trains and trams are seeing declines in usage.  In the United States they now account for only 1 per cent of the transport market.  Public transport is fast approaching similar unimportance in Australia.

In Melbourne over the past half century, public transport as a share of passenger trips has fallen from 57 per cent to 7 per cent.

Like King Canute, Transport Minister Peter Batchelor wants to roll back the trend.  His goals for 2030 are ambitious.  He wants to reduce car use from 74 to 60 per cent of all trips and to raise public transport's share to 15 per cent.

Such a trend reversal has been seen nowhere in the world.  To attempt to make it happen, the Government is allocating the lion's share of transport and road funding to public transport.

Over the coming decade, the Batchelor plan allocates more than $6 billion to public transport and little more than $2 billion to roads.  The plan allocates three times as much funding to the 7 per cent of trips that are by public transport as the 74 per cent that are by car is to receive.

Many of us have a nostalgia for public transport.  But the fact that its decline is consistent across the world in a sure-fire indicator that it does not cut the mustard of consumer needs.

The modern city just doesn't have the geography that allowed an effective public transport system in days gone by.  To be efficient, public transport needs high population densities with people moving along radial routes.

But city trips are becoming more dispersed and population densities are falling.  Half a century ago 55 per cent of Melbourne's jobs were in the CBD.  Today it is only 10 per cent.  Back then public transport paid its own way.  Today the taxpayer covers 80 per cent of the fares.

The growth of car ownership is what is killing public transport.  People prefer the convenience and comfort of their cars.  A car is now available to virtually all adults who want it.

Hence public transport is becoming redundant except for serving the city centres and some specialised needs.

Unfortunately, the Government, prodded by anti-car "elites", cannot come to terms with consumers' preferences for using their cars.  It is throwing money at public transport, preventing new shopping centre developments, and trying to ensure a more compact city.

In trying to ensure a more compact city it is restricting land for development on the periphery and encouraging apartment building in inner areas.  The effects include spiralling land prices and disappearing affordability for those who don't have a foot on the home ownership ladder.

The Government is clearly not responding to consumers' wishes.  Its policy is starving roads of funding.  Car users pay twice as much in petrol taxes and rego charges as is spent on roads.

Inadequate road spending means mounting congestion.  Aside from commuter inconvenience, this reduces the city's commercial efficiency.  Excessive costs for car commuters and other vehicle transport and is reducing the fabled "liveability" of Melbourne.


ADVERTISEMENT

Saturday, August 12, 2006

Home truths and politics

Prime Minister John Howard and Treasurer Peter Costello get blamed for a lot of things these days -- the price of petrol being too high, families carrying too much debt on their credit cards, and children growing up too fat.  The fact that these problems don't have much to do with the government is a point that is usually ignored.

The price of petrol is determined by events far beyond the powers of control of any Canberra politician.  A cut in the fuel excise tax of a few cents won't make much of a difference when petrol is close to $1.50 a litre.

While some people would no doubt like to return to the semi-socialised financial system of the 1970s, one of the benefits of financial deregulation is that it gives people the liberty to borrow as much as they think they can afford.  With that freedom comes the burden of bearing the consequences if they're wrong.  Governments should no more tell families how much money they are allowed to borrow than tell them what they must feed their children.

However, there is one present-day problem that clearly is the fault of government -- unaffordable housing.  And the responsibility for the problem rests, not with the federal government, but with the state governments.

Two decades of policies from state governments that have increasingly limited the release of land for development, which have imposed arbitrary zoning laws and which have discriminated against new home building in favour of forced urban consolidation have produced a tragic situation.

Thirty years ago the average house price in Australia was about three times the level of the median family income.  Today, the average house price is between six and nine times that level.  Thirty years ago the cost of land represented one-third of the overall price of a house.

Now, in Australian cities, land represents over half the price of a house.  In NSW the situation is even worse.  In Sydney the cost of land comprises 80 per cent of the price of a house.  This is ironic.  Although in some circles it is heresy to say so, it is not as though Australia suffers from a lack of land.

High house prices in the country's capital cities are not an accident.  They are the product of deliberate state government decisions.  This is a stark reminder for those who believe that what happens in the parliaments on Macquarie Street and Spring Street is irrelevant.  Factors affecting house prices that are under direct federal government control, such as negative gearing and tax-free capital gains on residential housing, have little impact on housing affordability.

For the overwhelming majority of Australians, home ownership is their most important economic aspiration and their house is their most significant financial asset.  The great Australian dream is to own a home, and state governments are putting that dream out of reach.

Urban planners and environmental activists have succeeded in making "sprawl" a dirty word.  The concept of sprawl conjures up images of endless Los Angeles-style highways connecting housing estates that have few amenities and no sense of community.

To avoid sprawl, and its supposed environmental costs, we're being priced into inner-city apartments from where we can enjoy the ambience of European-style covered walkways while sipping chai.  This metropolitan idyll might suit some, but for many, especially families, it is not their choice.

The impact of anti-sprawl on house prices can be measured by comparing local housing costs against costs in those cities in the United States that have similar characteristics to Australian cities, but which have more liberal planning regimes.

The average house price in the most affordable American cities, such as Houston or Atlanta, is about 2.7 times the average household income for the region.  Applying this ratio to Australian cities would have the median house price in Sydney, for example, fall from $520,000 to $162,000.  In Melbourne it would go from $360,000 to $149,000, and in Perth it would be lowered from $308,000 to $134,000.  Reducing the price of housing in Australia's capital cities to something affordable, by tackling land availability, state taxes and developer charges has a far greater potential to improve national living standards than does a fall in the cost of either petrol or bananas.

Overwhelmingly Australians prefer to live in houses in suburbs with a front garden and a backyard.  Attempted social engineering hasn't changed this basic reality.  Indeed, the leafy, happy suburbs of 2006 were the urban sprawl of 1956.


ADVERTISEMENT

Friday, August 11, 2006

The Tragedy of Planning:  Losing the Great Australian Dream

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I was inspired to write this book by observing the regulatory morass that has grown up around the provision of housing.  A house is at one and the same time most people's major investment and the source of shelter which, with food and clothing, forms one of the trio of life's essentials.  Housing is however much more than this since it also provides our main area of relaxation and the place where we raise our families.

Many people contributed much appreciated information for this work itself including from within academia, industry associations and consultancy services around Australia and overseas.  Responsibility for errors and omissions of course remains with me.

Richard J. Wood
June 2006



FOREWORD

Our homes define how we think of ourselves and the way others see us.  They represent places in which we interact with our families away from the sight of others;  they are our areas of retreat and relaxation from the world.  At the same time our homes bind us to our communities.  They become a source of security for retirement, indeed, home ownership is an increasingly important investment as we advance in years.

Unfortunately, housing has become much less affordable in recent times.  Taking the initial step towards home ownership now requires a much higher share of income than it did even 10 years ago.

Why has this occurred?  Richard Wood's analysis dismisses interest rates as a significant factor -- if that were so, poor affordability would be a global phenomenon.  But houses in many areas around the world remain highly affordable.  Nor is it the cost of building which, notwithstanding the imposts governments have introduced, has remained remarkably stable over time in real terms.  There are other reasons.

The increased costs largely relate to the rising price of land on our city fringes.  Government-imposed restrictions on land supplies, "development levies" to fund infrastructure and increasing layers of regulation all contribute.  Planning restrictions in particular, are choking our cities and increasingly pushing up the prices in what were once the most affordable places to purchase a home.

For the housing sector and related industries, higher costs mean less activity than would be the case if the laws of supply and demand were free to operate.  But there is a much larger tragedy for society as a whole.  The regulatory-induced price burden dashes the hopes of a great many aspiring home owners and has the potential to undermine the social cohesion and property ownership that does much to define us as a community.  Reducing the regulatory imposts that are creating these conditions has to be a major priority.

Ron Silberberg



SUMMARY

I think there's an enormous amount of time wasted by people trying to plan for long periods ahead, when history has shown that you just can't do this.  You can't place restrictions on people because of things you think should happen in 20 years, when we have absolutely no idea of what is likely to be the situation at that time.

-- Clem Jones (ALP), Lord Mayor of Brisbane, 1961-1975. (1)

The nineteenth-century social commentator William Cobbett echoed earlier writers in calling London, the first city of the modern era, "the Great Wen" (wen being Anglo-Saxon for wart).  This derogatory description of the crowded city is very much reversed under the present dominant approach to urban planning.

Modern planning typically seeks to ensure greater density and to prevent the geographic spread of urbanisation.  Its aims are, in part, to create a Parisian café society and, in part, to obtain cost economies in terms of transport and infrastructure spending.  Neither of these goals are realistic:  in fact, less than one-tenth of Parisians live within the romantic city that planners aspire to create;  and the economies in infrastructure and transport costs from forced densification are similarly illusory.

This modern planning ideology confronts two opposing sets of interests.  The first, which opposes plans that seek greater density, comprises incumbent homeowners, who wish to preserve their living environment in the way it has currently evolved and to prevent its densification.  The second set of interests comprises those who do not currently own a home, the interests of which coincide with those of the economy in general.  Where planning restricts land access it creates scarcity, thereby artificially bringing higher cost homes, more expensive services and more apartment buildings instead of the houses that people overwhelmingly seek.  Regrettably, people adversely affected by these policies -- those who presently do not own a home -- tend to be unaware of the reasons why prices have moved home ownership beyond their means.

Cities are places where it became convenient to organise trade, and later to facilitate manufacturing.  The advent of railroads and cars, and the end of the protective benefit of huddling for protection behind city walls, has meant that the density of cities has dropped dramatically, particularly in the developed world.  With modern transport, where almost everyone has access to their own car in the developed world, and with the communications revolution, the city is undergoing further changes, the outcomes of which are yet to be seen.  Yet crowding remains the nature of cities.

Urban planning is, at least notionally, about managing that crowding.  It has become a network of social protections, sometimes masquerading as a propellant of economic efficiency.  One of the common conceits of our times is that social protections have no costs or, that if they do, their costs are somehow automatically born by the wealthiest members of society.  In reality, social protections do have costs and their burdens can often fall, in whole or in part, on the weakest and poorest members of society.

Two vital tenets of modern economies involve first, the respect for individual property rights, and second, that governments should not restrict people's choices.  Proposals to restrict choice normally have a considerable burden of proof to overcome.  Yet contemporary urban planning is very much about both restricting choice and socialising individual property rights.  These come about, most obviously, by rationing access to land.

Planning systems are in place across all major Australian urban areas.  Invariably, they reduce the quantity of land that is available for conversion into housing.  These restraints are accompanied by others which restrict the development of shopping centres, prevent subdivisions of rural land and often require developers to expend resources on features that their customers might not value as highly as they cost.  For housing, the upshot is that agricultural land on the periphery of urban areas, which has a value of some $1,000 per hectare, is worth 100-fold this amount and more when designated for housing development.  An increase in value generated entirely from the lifting of prior official restrictions on the use of such property.

If Australia were applying the liberal systems to development that prevail in Texas for example, a house/land package price would at least halve.  Australia's ration-induced high prices for new developments on the periphery lift prices throughout the city.

Rather like the government-created shortage of taxi plates, the existence of the housing land shortage creates an unfortunate vested interest among existing house owners to maintain it.  Disconcertingly, State governments may have an interest in ensuring high land prices since this inflates their property-specific taxes.  It would be deplorable if the government-induced land shortage were to endure as it has with taxi plates around the world.  But it is unedifying to observe people living in garden suburbs reclaimed from former agricultural land decrying the wishes of others -- typically considerably less wealthy and less well politically connected than themselves -- to have their own houses-with-gardens in new suburbs reclaimed from agricultural land.

This benefits those who have over those who have not.  It directs resources and efforts to political rent-seeking, with all the conflict, arbitrary outcomes and tendencies to corruption that creates -- it is no accident that land scandals, particularly at local government level, are a notable feature of Australian politics and political history. (2)  And it paves the way for the creation of a less egalitarian society, where today's have-nots face a form of punitive regulatory tax on joining the home-owning haves, perhaps creating a permanent underclass in the process.

The way forward involves ensuring far greater rights for landowners to use their property in ways they prefer it to be used.  This means far fewer zoning restraints, a reduction in mandatory charges for land development and reduced rights of those in neighbouring properties to prevent property-owners from selling, subdividing, or redeveloping their land so that they obtain the most value from it.



1 URBAN DEVELOPMENT AND ITS CONTROL

THE CITY HISTORICALLY

Until the past couple of centuries, ancient Rome with one million people (2 per cent of the Roman Empire's population) was uniquely large. (3)  Before modern times, the difficulties associated with providing food, water and sewage systems placed severe limitations on the size of a city.  Even with the full resources of an empire at its disposal, Rome was only able to do so by having an incredible population concentration.  At something like 57,000 people per square kilometre, ancient Rome was far more tightly packed than modern Rome (3,000 per square kilometre) or Sydney at 2,200 per square kilometre or even the densest metropolis in the world today, Dhaka in Bangladesh, at 32,500 per square kilometre. (4)

Typically, the vast majority of people in any but the least developed countries now live in cities.  They do so out of preference based on the different features that urban housing provides:  features such as comfort, access to services, proximity to work, friends and so on.  Currently, East Asia is in the middle of the largest movement of people in human history, as farmers and young people move to the cities.


REGULATORY RESTRAINTS TO DEVELOPMENT

Planning for amenities

From the Mesopotamian city of Ur of the Chaldees to today, housing and house costs have depended on the same variables.  The costs of housing are a function of three factors:  the costs of building;  the costs of the building materials and other inputs;  and the costs of acquiring and preparing suitable land.

It is this last factor that has become less certain and more subject to regulatory discretion over the years, because in so many jurisdictions it has come to be dominated by approval mechanisms.  These have morphed into planning arrangements that have, in turn, been channelled into "smart" growth schemes.  Planning, originally a means of facilitating growth by allowing for the building of common-use amenities and services, has become synonymous with the prevention of activity.  Its original rationale has been subsumed into a mechanism for moulding urban and rural living environments.

Opposition to urban sprawl can be dated back at least to Elizabeth I, but it is only in recent times that opposition to it has assumed mystical respectability on a par with saving whales, stopping global warming and preventing GM foods.  As with those other goals, opposition to urban sprawl is cloaked in a mantle of moral superiority that pretends to self-denial but is invariably laced with selfinterest.

The first recorded attempts to stop populations spreading out from the immediate confines of an established city occurred as soon as a relatively settled system of law and order facilitated protections outside a city wall.  The early opposition to it stemmed from costs that might be avoided in taxes to government bodies.

Early planning arrangements were geared to relieving overcrowding.  However, a romantic attachment to nostalgia began to find favour from the late nineteenth century, which gradually came to dominate the planning profession and has taken a strong hold on the community generally.

Unlike the previous centuries, where the concerned elites had thought of cities as replete with Satanic Mills, new generations came to venerate the crowded urban landscapes.  More importantly, they resented the growth of suburbia and its more recent incarnation, "exurbia", said to be eating up rural land.  Much of the genesis of this view came from England, and the rural landscapes that were cherished were the villages, especially those in the south-east.  From the 1940s, Green Belts surrounded London.

From the earliest times there have been reactions to urban population growth.  In the case of both the two greatest sixteenth-century European cities, London and Paris, sovereigns attempted to maintain the compact nature of their capitals by preventing development outside the city or on its edges.  In 1580, Elizabeth I of England proclaimed that:

... all manner of persons, of whatever quality soever they be, to desist and forebear from [building any new] house or tenement within three miles of any of the gates of the said city of London ...

This early "green belt" was a conspicuous failure -- the boundaries of Greater London now lie 20 miles beyond the city gates of 1580. (5)

In recent years, these reactions to urban population growth have had an oscillatory character.  Concerns were first focused on the need to reduce density in the largest and fastest-growing cities.  Paris under Napoleon III did so by pulling down many of the teeming central areas and housing their inhabitants in outer suburbs.  The outcome, however, whatever measure was used, was the well-documented reduction in density levels, a reduction that is overwhelmingly driven by the personal preferences of individuals themselves.

Bruegmann (6) identifies three stages of anti-sprawl arguments over the past century.  The first began in the 1920s and was spearheaded by the architect Cough Williams-Ellis who wrote that suburban growth "crawls like a gigantic slug over the country, leaving a foul trail behind it".  The Society for the Preservation of Rural England was formed in 1926 by like-minded people to stop the middle-class encroachments.  Soon after, the term sprawl was first used in the context of suburban expansion.  As a recent article in The Spectator by Roger Scruton illustrates, this view about the merits of protecting the rural landscape from the hoi polloi still holds strongly among conservative circles in Britain. (7)

The second phase is associated with William Whyte of Fortune magazine who wrote The Exploding Metropolis, which Bruegmann calls "A hymn of praise to the dense traditional city and a bitter attack on postwar suburban development".  This attacked US cities, especially Los Angeles, and spawned a literature that focused on the costs -- roads, services, and later isolation and environmental -- said to be associated with suburban growth.

This led to a third phase which argued against car dependency and congestion that allegedly accompanied "uncontrolled" growth as opposed to the "controlled" growth that was based on planning using computer modelling.  The popular support for this is fuelled by those, often recent arrivals, seeking protection from adjacent development, especially by people that they deem to have inferior taste to themselves.  Self-interest that adds to the value of the incumbent's own property values (both through scarcity value and by reducing any impingements from more recent development) is particularly powerful.  In this respect, the Prime Minister is reported to have said that no home-owner has ever complained to him that their house prices have risen!


Planning in its modern guise

There was an overlap in the application of two rival notions of planning -- promoting urban population dispersion and preventing it.  During the 1950s, responding to critics whose focus was on overcrowding, London was still building garden cities 50 miles away from the East End from which the teeming multitudes were to be poured.  A final British legacy of government population disbursement was the Location of Offices Bureau, which survived until the Thatcher clean-out of otiose and detrimental government agencies.

Other UK cities followed London and inexorably the new ideology came to infect the Oceanic outposts of Australia and New Zealand.  Like many such infections it took a highly virulent form here, despite the lack of any population pressure -- Australia's urban sprawl covers less than 0.3 per cent of the country (even in England and Wales, urban developments covers only 8 per cent).  Moreover, Australia's more recent settlement surely diminishes the pressures for changed urban structures.  The policy actually persisted for longer in Australia.  Salisbury and Albury-Wodonga were among the dispersed cities that received favourable tax treatment well into the 1980s.

Neither of these policy trends had much effect in restraining the size of the city.  Those cities that declined did so for other reasons.  Some were redefined (with their peripheries taking in most of the growth);  others saw a movement from a blighted inner urban area, often resulting from restrictions on redevelopment;  some, such as Pittsburgh, were dependent on industries that themselves were in decline.

Above all, the decline in density resulted from technological developments, income growth and consumer preferences.  People prefer to live in greater personal space, both internal and external, and detached somewhat from their neighbours.  Urban sprawl is not the "inevitable unhappy result of laissez-faire capitalism" but embodies individual preferences, preferences which are expressed, when they have the chance, by people from all walks of life and creeds.  Once technology allowed rapid journeys -- first via rail and later by road -- the cities expanded.  Added to this, we have seen a great dispersal of work locations, partly due to the decline of large integrated factories, partly due to the changed nature of work -- especially the growth of service industries which tend to be geographically dispersed.

Robert Bruegmann traces the ebbs and flows of geographic dispersions and the policies attached to them.  He finds a remarkable similarity across the world (Soviet-era Moscow being a rare exception made possible by total government control).  European and Australian cities have tended to invest more than American cities in public transport and have, in many cases, put in place much stricter planning ordinances and subsidised housing to prevent geographic spread.  Nonetheless, the density levels are comparable.

He also points out that there is some reversal of trends, as people see more merit in inner-city living.  In this respect he says:

One of the ironies is that much of what is most attractive .... about cities' "traditional" character, is that many of the things that once defined them has disappeared.  The decanting outward of all kinds of manufacturing and warehousing functions led to a dramatic reduction in street congestion, truck traffic and pollution.

In the process, factories were converted to lofts and the city centre itself became focused on entertainment and other leisure activities.  This has also led to a reversal in cities such as San Francisco (and Melbourne and Adelaide) of the affluent/slum centre/suburb polarity.

Anti-sprawl campaigns now dominate urban planning.  Fuelling them and mightily facilitating their media profile are the arrivistes and others seeking to preserve a suburb or a favoured rural hideaway by keeping out the hoi polloi.  Contradictions abound in this series of alliances.  Thus, while the incumbents (Bruegmann calls them the "sensitive minority") want to preserve a suburb, the planners want to re-create the denser populations that they hope will feed the café latte society they favour.  As a result, the trend back to the centre by "empty nesters" and others is not leading to the higher concentrations favoured by anti-sprawl activists.  Ordinances and other measures are used to stop densities from rising -- a phenomenon best observed in Melbourne in the suburb of Camberwell, where opposition to development has led to a very significant reduction in population density.

In fact, urban change is endemic.  The row houses on the periphery of major cities that were the sprawl of the 1930s and 1950s are now highly valued by the avant-garde.  Daly City in San Francisco, about which folk singer Pete Singer despisingly sang in "Little Boxes" ("all made out of ticky-tacky and all look just the same"), is now respected and preserved.  There is, of course, little difference in this from even earlier eras -- much of the most prized real estate in Australian cities was last century's urban sprawl -- the Prahrans, and Balmains.

While urban change is endemic and its direction is by no means following a universal stereotype, a sea change appears unlikely.  According to UK studies reported by Nathan and Urwin: (8)

  • City centre populations grew by nearly 100 per cent in Dundee, around 40 per cent in Liverpool and by nearly 300 per cent in Manchester between 1991 and 2001.  By 2001, there were 2,900 people living in the centre of Dundee, 13,500 in Liverpool and 10,000 in Manchester.  These numbers have risen since 2001 -- for example, in 2004, the city centre population in Manchester was probably about 15,000 people.
  • City centre living has grown massively and seems to have reduced, but not reversed, longer run trends toward suburban living.
  • It is dominated by students who mainly live there only for a few years before setting out on the property ladder -- there are very few families with children and hardly anyone over 40.  So far, the expected "empty-nester" demand has not eventuated.
  • It's heavily consumerist -- there's lots of shopping and clubbing.  There's no conflict with the evening economy -- people move in for the nightlife, not despite it.
  • City centres aren't seen as family-friendly.  Noise, pollution, lack of space and lack of public services all become big problems when children arrive on the scene.  These attitudes are firmly entrenched and have a long history.
  • There's little point trying to put families into city centres -- it would be expensive and might not work, and city cores basically work well for their existing residents.

Even though planning restraints have impeded new development, the consumer continues to voice her/his own preferences.  Hence, house-building leap-frogged and indented the no-go areas.  But regulatory restraints meant it did so at a higher land cost.  Such outcomes are the ultimate corollary of scarcity -- especially scarcity that is maintained by government frontier guards patrolling the availability of alternative supplies, as they do in Australia where State-wide planning is effectively in place.  Inevitably, the higher costs on the periphery are transmitted to adjacent properties and throughout the urban area, creating the house price escalation Australia faces today.



2 URBAN SPRAWL:  ITS SUPPORTERS AND DETRACTORS

CONSUMER PREFERENCES

The abusive terminology captured in the term "sprawl" is about objecting to other people living as they wish.  The growth of prosperity means that, unless they are prevented by official restrictions on land use which raises prices beyond their reach, most families can aspire to owning their own home-with-a-garden.  Even with reasonable provision for parklands and nature reserves, of all the world's developed countries, Australia should have the least difficulty in permitting land use to reflect the preferences of its citizens.  Especially given that Central Business Districts generally provide only about 15 per cent of total employment.

Given relatively high immigration, and the general preference for the amenities of urban living, Australian cities only have the choices of growing out or growing up.  People's preferences should be the crucial determinant here.  Clearly, people's preferences are for their own homes on their own land. (9)  They are impeded from fulfilling those preferences by zoning restraints that raise the cost of bringing new land into use for urban purposes.

Moreover, growing out generally makes far more sense as it imposes considerably less crowding, pollution and congestion and allows households significantly more living space.  Policy makers may, however, prefer placing a more intensive load on existing infrastructure to providing new infrastructure on the urban fringe.  Often such preferences are motivated by claimed cost savings;  yet many such savings, for example on water and sewerage costs, are spurious once the age of existing facilities and their inaccessibility are taken into account.

Simultaneously opposing "sprawl" (on the grounds that the greenery someone else owns should not be converted into the homes-with-gardens other folk want to live in) and opposing building-up (on the grounds of loss of amenity) is not a sustainable policy duet.  The pressure on existing facilities from such policies clearly imposes considerable costs on those who are not already home-owners, thereby increasing the divide between the "haves" and the "have-nots".


PLANNING AND PUBLIC TRANSPORT

Much of the basis of planning is posited on outdated notions of the city.  These notions see the city as a radial development centred on the CBD.  Yet, facilitated by the car and communications advances, different work patterns and an increased need for space-extensive shopping centres have been among the factors that have refashioned modern cities.  These trends and developments have changed the nature and importance of the CBD.

These trends are exemplified by a declining share of employment in CBDs.  Melbourne is typical:  jobs in the central city fell from 55 per cent to 28 per cent of the total between 1961 and 2001.  In that latter year, the core CBD itself accounted for only 10 per cent of jobs.  This has immense ramifications for planning, especially road development and public transport.

Many planners (and governments generally) are predisposed against the car, presumably for similar reasons they are antagonistic to urban growth -- the car epitomises the ability to free oneself from the constraints of a centralised transport system.  It also allows the vast reductions in population density that is much opposed by the café latte set.

Typical of planning schemes that discriminate against the car is the Transport Green Paper put out by the Queensland Government. (10)  This places the emphasis for government spending on public transport.  In its comments on the paper in February 2006, the Royal Automobile Club of Queensland estimated that the State government's documented spending on transport over the next 20 years was weighted 80 per cent towards public transport.  The imbalance of such an allocation is clear when data show that car travel comprises 56 per cent of all trips and public transport only 8 per cent.

Plans are designed to ensure job and commercial growth is largely confined to transport hubs, many of which are ill-suited to the types of growth required to meet consumer needs most efficiently.

The Queensland Government's plans are not untypical of those of other State governments.  Indeed, before the 1990s, the Labor Government in Victoria was required (under pressure from public transport unions and others favouring public transport) to construct "arterial" roads with traffic lights and intersections rather than freeways with overpasses, since the latter, it was feared, would take too much clientele from trains, trams and buses.

Transport economist John Cox finds antecedents for this modern authoritarianism when he suggests that:

Quixotic endeavours by ... governments to delay the building of freeways and limit the mobility of motorists in order to push them onto public transport reminds me of the opposition of the Duke of Wellington to the introduction of railways.  He was opposed to railways, he said, because they would "only encourage the common people to move around needlessly". (11)

To encourage greater use of public transport, many advocate an increased use of toll roads.  There are also frequent calls to make public transport free, sometimes in conjunction with the introduction of road pricing. (12)

While user-pays principles are generally a sound basis for policy, advocates often overlook the fact that the car user, in aggregate, pays twice as much in transport-specific taxes as governments spend on roads.

Moreover, "user pays" also involves some greater sophistication in charging (for example, differential charges by time of day).  Along these lines, "user-pays" would also entail charges on alternative modes -- including public transport -- which presently rarely recovers more than 20 per cent of its total costs, and a proper allocation would likely result in a five-fold fare increase, especially for peak-hour travellers. (13)  Public transport is even "peakier" than road usage.  If there were to be a time-of-day charge on car usage, would it not also make equal sense to charge public transport users similarly?  This would be even-handed and would surely be preferable to having governments making people's choices for them.

Increased subsidies to public transport for journey-to/from-work peak-time users would increase system "peakiness" and also, in many cases, degrade comfort -- during the peak, many public transport facilities, especially those on fixed tracks, generally operate quite close to capacity limitations.

In addition, further subsidisation of public transport also gives rise to an equity issue.  The areas that are almost universally best served by public transport subsidies are those located relatively close to city centres;  routes converge on these areas, which not only means improved frequency but also closer proximity to transit stops.  Hence, subsidies from general taxation would amount to a redistribution, most often from poor to rich.

A further problem is one of monopoly.  As government has the exclusive power to allow or prevent the building of new roads, might they not see road pricing as a taxation bonanza?  The prospect of obtaining increased tax revenue would prove irresistibly attractive to some governments, and would encourage them to allow a scarcity of road space to develop.  Governments' enthusiasm for this would be constrained only by fears that they might deprive the city of the transportation services it needs in order to flourish.

These matters aside, although free public transport would certainly attract more patronage, it would not attract as much as its advocates think.  This can be tested by observing the transport choices of workers in the public transport industry who already travel free.  The number of workers' cars parked at tram, train and bus terminals is testimony to the attractions of car travel -- even to people who are far from affluent and work within the industry itself.

Sadly for those favouring public transport, the tide of demographic history is running strongly against them.  Public transport needs high concentrations of people.  A rule of thumb is that rail-based systems require 40,000 people per square kilometre to be viable.  Such a system therefore works, after a fashion, in Hong Kong, which has that population density.  Express bus systems need 26,000 per square kilometre.

Australian cities have densities of about 1,500 per square kilometre and reach only 5,500 even in the densest suburbs.  On top of this, concentration levels have been falling for decades in spite of land rationing by the government designed to promote denser urban living.  Even an intensification of this government-created shortage of land will not reverse the trend.

The estimates of what is required for a viable public transport system with growing patronage levels are also being made worse by the changing nature of workplaces.  More and more trips are cross-town.  These trends are exemplified by a declining share of employment in central areas where radially-based public transport systems work best.  As previously noted, in Melbourne, jobs in the central area fell from 55 per cent to 28 per cent of the total between 1961 and 2001.  In that latter year, the CBD accounted for only 10 per cent of jobs.

This has immense ramifications for planning, especially road development and public transport.  Not only is Melbourne, like virtually all other cities, getting less dense, but the trip profile is becoming far more dispersed and difficult to jam into a public transport service.

The car is most people's preferred means of transport, unless parking is expensive and/or public transport frequency is high.  Trying to discriminate against it not only offends against personal choice but will reduce the value of the city and jeopardise its future attractiveness as a living, working and leisure centre.

Hence, attempts to use transport subsidies or taxes to counteract congestion are difficult to find, apart perhaps from in a handful of the largest and most densely settled cities such as Hong Kong, New York and London.  The modern city and modern life generally revolve too heavily around the motor car for people to prefer the inferior service that is concomitant with public transport.  The car is the mode of choice for 90 per cent of motorised trips and, in turn, 90 per cent of the population own or have ready access to a car.  Attempts to combat its use will not only constitute attempts to frustrate consumer choices but will rebound on the urban areas that attempt to do so by making them less attractive and less vibrant, causing them to lose activities and people to other areas.

Trying to force the city's development around a mass transit system is a variant of preventing car use and offers few advantages over it.  Both such approaches, except in a few mega-core urban concentrations, will constrain the city's adaptability to the needs of the people using and living within it and result in it losing relevance and attractiveness.  It was Charles de Gaulle who proclaimed, to the wrath of youthful demonstrators, that Paris must adapt to the car.  This allowed the centre of Paris to be compromised, but at the same time retain its commercial viability, thereby preventing its relegation to that of an ancient curiosity shop.


BEHIND THE SHIFTS IN URBAN GEOGRAPHY

Ancient cities, often walled and desperately overcrowded, sprawled almost as soon as relatively settled law and order allowed for something other than an overwhelming priority on personal security and defence.  In all these metamorphoses, we have seen a reduction of the density of the city and its central areas until today, notwithstanding the ease of multi-storey apartments, no major developed-world city has a population density greater than one-tenth that of ancient Rome.

The sprawl represented several factors:

  • The need for some activities that were particularly noxious (such as leather tanning) to move away from residential areas.
  • Increased affluence among the richest inhabitants and with it the resources to move away from the bustle into more sanitary, cooler and quieter areas where more land-extensive homes could be built;  in Paris the faubourgs (i.e. suburbs) such as St Honoré were the outer areas in the eighteenth century and anticipated moves to equivalently far-flung suburbs that developed in Melbourne (Toorak) and Sydney (Vaucluse).
  • Improved transport.  Train lines in London allowed the ribbon development (called strip development in the US) which spread out in fingers during the nineteenth century.  The development of the car and bus brought the in-fill between the corridors.
  • The changing functions of the city centre from a centre of manufacturing to a commercial centre and increasingly to a leisure centre within which only 15-20 per cent of jobs are located.  As a leisure centre, there are some trends to increased population within the centre of the city, particularly by those with high incomes:  in many cases using their city-living accommodation as a second home -- reversing the previous and still dominant trend of second homes outside of the city.

The target almost universally sought within the modern planning fraternity is to achieve a greater density.  This accords with goals that favour greater use of public transport and a general anti-car philosophy.  But it tends to run up against a NIMBY (Not In My BackYard) opposition to high-rise in the targeted neighbourhoods themselves.  By raising barriers to building out, such policies have, as a natural consequence, increased conflict over land use in existing suburbs and inner-city areas.  According to some, increased density cannot do more than reduce the amenity of such areas, to which local residents react adversely. (14)  Such adverse reactions stem from perceived changes (illusory or otherwise) in the area from how it was when the existing residents originally chose to live there.

Planning controls, when captured by the incumbent property-owners, often take on a highly conservative anti-development character.  As a result of an ageing of the population, many of the suburbs controlled in this way now have very much lower population concentrations than in the halcyon days that the anti-development pressure groups seek to re-create.

The alternative planning restraint approach seeks densification, claiming that this is the only way to achieve the "café latte" society that so many of the cultural elites favour, and to economise on infrastructure costs.  Provision of infrastructure is, however, made cheaper by high-rise only to a limited extent.

Various studies showed that it might be marginally cheaper to build up to a certain point, but beyond that the cost increased considerably.  Usually floor six, and certainly floor ten, was when the "threshold" was reached and costs climbed rapidly. (15)

In other respects, economies in infrastructure disappear once the shift in urban geographic needs evident in the modern city comes into play.  Those needs -- highly dispersed origin and destination work travel pairs, the need for personal transport for carriage of goods and the shifting nature of the city as a leisure resource -- render the previous paradigms obsolete.



3 ANTECEDENTS FOR CONTROLS IN AUSTRALIA

THE BRITISH ORIGINS OF AUSTRALIAN PLANNING

Australia has followed variants of the British approach to urban planning.

In the UK, modern metropolitan planning began in the nineteenth century.  The extent of urban planning has steadily increased.  Compared with contemporary levels of urban planning:

Nineteenth century town planning was more down-to-earth in its concerns with public health, sanitation and with meeting the functional requirements of industry and transport. (16)

The Artisans' and Labourers' Dwelling Improvement Act 1875 gave local authorities compulsory acquisition powers.  The Public Health Act 1875 set minimum design standards. (17)  The Housing of the Working Class Act 1890 legislated for early council housing.  (In 1909, only 10 per cent of people in the UK owned their own house.)

To summarise, in these Acts the three functions of local authorities were to clear existing areas, to build themselves, and to control the development of others. (18)

The roles of public health, housing management, building control and town planning became separate functions and professions. (19)

The Housing and Town Planning Act 1909 enabled the creation of much more extensive council housing and also gave local councils the power to devise development "schemes" (as town plans were then called).  The provision of council housing was expanded under the 1919 Housing and Town Planning Act to provide for Great War veterans.  This was expanded further under the 1924 Housing Act.  The 1919 Act also required councils to produce "schemes" (town plans) for settlements over 20,000 in population, showing land-use zoning, particularly the location of new housing estates.  Implementation and enforcement were, however, constrained by the lack of trained, skilled personnel. (20)

In what has become a persistent pattern around the world, the public housing that was the original focus of much of the development of urban planning has tended to be poorly designed and maintained.  The adoption of mechanical lifts, allowing residential buildings to rise above their previous practical limit of about six storeys, was not consistent in its effects.

The social results when applied to cheap council housing where the lifts do not work and people have to walk up the stairs is another matter altogether from the situation in a carefully maintained block of expensive private flats (apartments). (21)

A difference that has persisted.

Ironically, many blocks of council flats built as an alternative to nineteenth-century slums have now become slums themselves.  Paradoxically those that have been taken over by private developers and upgraded have been greatly improved, but then, of course, are no longer part of the social housing sector. (22)

While the information and incentive failures of public ownership have become increasingly obvious, that similar problems might afflict regulation is less widely acknowledged.  (But, then, for the planning profession to accept the latter point would undermine much of its status and career prospects.)

The inter-war period saw a great expansion of private housing construction, leading to much denunciation of "urban blight" (the spread of suburbs over formerly agricultural land -- what later became known as "sprawl").  The Town and Country Planning Act 1932:

... in an attempt to control the flood [of private house building], required local authorities to produce zoning maps designating restricted areas for housing development, and requiring developers to get a rudimentary form of planning permission.

But deference to the rights of private property lingered:

... many developers virtually ignored the legislation, as the penalties were minimal and difficult to enforce.  Also the local authorities were required to pay compensation if permission was refused, which naturally discouraged them from doing so.  If there was no plan available when developers wanted to build they were granted what was known as "interim development control" permission.  In practical terms all this meant that the planners often drew up the local land use zoning plan after the developers had built -- hardly positive town planning! (23)

Developers tended to build along major roads in "ribbon" development, which made provision of schools and other services more difficult.  The response was the Restriction of Ribbon Development Act 1935, which attempted to encourage "clumping" by requiring developers to build in more compact developments. (24)  The Special Areas Act 1934 introduced a minimal level of State intervention and regional planning which attempted to move work to areas (South Wales, Cumberland, Glasgow) where there were many unemployed.  The policy was not conspicuously successful.

It was considered bad economics, as some areas in the north were taking on the form of ghost towns as everyone moved out, leaving empty houses, disused factories and neglected roads and public facilities, i.e. wasting existing facilities.  These problems have continued to haunt the government to the present day.  In spite of decades of intervention ... the situation has not balanced out. (25)

While the inter-war and earlier Acts established the precedents, it was only after the Second World War that urban planning seriously took off.  Given the effects of bombing, the Second World War's legitimisation of massive central planning and the desire to create "homes fit for heroes", planning came to be seen as the solution to a range of problems as part of a greatly expanded welfare state -- as a natural evolution in a mixed economy.

In 1944, the Greater London Development Plan was produced, London having already acquired a designated green belt under the Green Belt (London and Home Counties) Act 1938. (26)  The legislative centrepiece of post-war urban planning was the Town and Country Planning Act 1947.  It required all development to receive planning approval and all local authorities to produce land-use planning maps backed up by strong planning controls and a betterment tax (originally set at 100 per cent, later diluted to near non-existence).  The New Towns Act 1946, which sought to channel development to designated growth centres (an approach later abandoned), and the National Parks and Access to the Countryside Act 1949 were further elements in the post-war planning system. (27)  The shortage of qualified planners was ameliorated by using experts from a range of disciplines and backgrounds (typically surveying, civil engineering, architecture and public health).

The 1947 system represented a half-way house between nationalisation and a free market.  It effectively nationalised the development value rather than nationalising the land itself. (28)

The question of betterment taxes (attempts to socialise the windfall gains from regulation-created land scarcity) and compensation waved back and forth under Labour and Conservative Governments.  Requiring developers to pay infrastructure costs is part of this same debate.

Planners failed to predict various changes (notably the rise of the motor car and of the owner-occupier).  The visions of the planners also proved to be persistently narrower than the range of purposes urban dwellers actually had.  Public housing, a focus of the planning system, was an area of limited achievement:

... several commentators argue that Britain ended up with more homeless, not fewer, as the result of the net effect of clearance policies ... In some areas, there was so much slum clearance, and inadequate new housing development (because the local authorities ran out of money), that the end result was a net loss of housing stock! (29) ... often the sense of community in working-class areas was demolished along with the housing. (30)

Dissatisfaction was generated in other ways, particularly in the aftermath of wartime bombing:

... planners were given extensive powers of compulsory purchase, land assembly and decision-making -- often against the wishes of the remaining residents, who sometimes considered they suffered more at the hands of the planners than that of the Germans. (31)

Basing planning on land-use zoning was deemed inadequate to deal with rapid change.  The Town and Country Planning Acts (1968 and 1971) replaced zoning with Structure Plans designed to set goals and turned planning into an interactive process.  Alas:

Ironically, the new system proved even more long-winded and inflexible than the previous one and many local authorities had great difficulty producing the Local and Structure Plans, let alone carrying out continuous monitoring. (32)

Public dissatisfaction with the planners' efforts led to the Civic Amenities Act 1967, which placed an emphasis on conservation and heritage.  Attempts to move industry to where people were unemployed continued with the Distribution of Industry Act 1958 and the Local Employment Acts (1960, 1963 and 1970) and culminated in the last grand regional employment Act, the Industry Act 1972.  Attempts to control further the development of London led to the Control of Offices and Industrial Development Act 1965 and the Industrial Development Act 1966.  The Special Development Act 1967 created another layer of designated development areas.  The Community Land Act 1975 was another attempt to tax the profits of developers for public purposes.  Problems of the inner cities also reached public consciousness and led to further legislative activity -- the Housing Acts (1969 and 1974), the Areas Act 1978, and the Local Government and Housing Act 1989. (33)

Though there was some wind-back under the Thatcher Government, the basic structures of the system remained in place. (34)  But even text books questioned whether the upward trend of planning control and purposes had been socially positive:

The planners had done a great deal but had solved very few problems.  In fact they had created many new ones. (35)

The question of what could be expected from planning remained a very open one:

... after the Brixton riots of the early 1980s Lord Scarman implied in his report (1982) that the planners were to blame.  If this was so, then the planner has a major role in social problem-solving, offering "salvation by bricks".  Indeed, many of the nineteenth-century visionaries believed that transplanting people into model communities with plenty of grass, trees and sunshine would change them as people. (36)

The Thatcher period also saw the creation of a major asset bubble in house values whose outcome left many home-owners (having over-borrowed) with negative equity in their homes.  Asset bubbles typically occur when investors believe they have a one-way bet on asset values.  Land rationing creates precisely such an effect.  (Recent house price exuberance in the US -- restricted to particular housing markets (37) -- and in Sydney also seems to provide examples of the potential for asset bubbles under land rationing.)


AUSTRALIAN ADOPTION OF BRITISH PLANNING APPROACHES

Metropolitan planning in Australia also grew slowly.  Early on, however, land rationing became a prime element in such planning.  The Western Australian Town Planning and Development Act 1928 was the first such legislation in Australia to give local government the power to control the use of private land.

... by 1945 all states except South Australia had legislation which gave local government the authority to prepare and administer statutory land use plans, subject only to the overriding powers of the responsible state minister. (38)

As in Britain, authorities did not begin systematically to interfere with what property owners could do with their property until after the Second World War.  Only in Brisbane, with the amalgamation of 22 municipalities into the greater Brisbane Council in 1925, was metropolitan planning delegated to a territorially expansive local council covering an area of 375 square miles. (39)


Sydney

The first legislation allowing for a major metropolitan plan in Australia was the NSW Local Government (Town and Country Planning) Amendment Act 1945.  It extended beyond similar legislation in WA (1928), Tasmania (1944) and Victoria (1944) by incorporating provision for a broad plan for the County of Cumberland, the Sydney metropolitan region, with a County Council elected and financed by the constituent local councils.  A plan was submitted in 1948 and promulgated in 1951.

The plan was limited to "regulating and controlling the use of land" and envisaged a population growth from 1.7 to 2.4 million over 25 years.  It incorporated a green belt -- that is, a limit on the spread of urban growth -- which reserved land for open space and future highways.  It also zoned areas for industrial expansion and "living areas" from which substantive industrial and commercial activity was largely excluded.

Landowners, local councils, State authorities (the Housing Commission, Main Roads, Railways) either resented, defied or resisted the plan.  Furthermore, the actual rate of population growth was almost double that which the plan envisaged. (40)  The more encompassing a plan is, the more factors it has to cover, the more things that can be miscalculated.

The State Minister abolished much of the green belt (without prior consultation with the County Council) in December 1959, the strongest argument for which was rising house prices.  The Council did secure agreement that rural land would only become available for urban use after detailed planning incorporating provision for schools, parks, through routes, etc., and that landowners would accept the costs of water and sewerage reticulation.  This went with an increasing trend for local councils to require landowners to complete roads and stormwater drainage works in new subdivisions.  What had been unprecedented arrangements have since become standard throughout metropolitan Australia and indicated how extensive the power of "regulating and controlling the use of land" could be.

The County Council itself was abolished in 1963 and planning responsibility taken over by the new State Planning Authority.  In 1968, it released the Sydney Region Outline Plan which did not gain statutory status.

A clear pressure in the development of planning was that provision of services would precede, rather than lag behind, home building.  The desire for "orderliness" clashed somewhat with the notion of local democracy, since local councils proved less than consistent in the use of their land control powers.  Sydney was a forerunner in Australian metropolitan planning, the other cities tending to be more cautious in the use of land control measures. (41)  That Sydney house prices became notoriously high was hardly a coincidence.

The Land and Environment Court Act 1979 created the Land and Environment Court as the body for judicial appeal over planning and development matters. (42)  The Environmental Planning and Assessment Act 1979 represented a shift towards more policy-based urban governance, providing a legal and appeal structure for local planning.  Sydney continued to expand through land releases in areas not serviced by rail or other public transport.  Sydney surged ahead of Melbourne as a financial and international centre (by 1983, 73 per cent of merchant bank head offices were located in Sydney). (43)

The 1988 Metropolitan Strategy was, like the 1968 Plan, not gazetted.  It endorsed urban consolidation -- a concentrated, not a dispersed, city -- aiming to increase the use of multi-unit dwellings and increase the number of lots in new suburban subdivisions from 8 to 10 per hectare.  This trend was reinforced by the 1995 Cities for the 21st Century, which wanted further increases in residential density -- what one commentator called "fairly heroic" increases -- encouragement of sub-regional centres such as Parramatta and Chatswood, and increased residential, tourism and other use of the Harbour foreshores. (44)

The 2000 Olympics occasioned significant specific construction and refurbishment.  A Framework for Managing Growth (1997) supported the compact city approach, while establishing four subregions (Sydney, Newcastle, Wollongong, Central Coast), thereby incorporating the corridor/node approach of earlier plans.  Shaping Our Cities (1998) endorsed the concept of environmental sustainability while also wishing to encourage economic growth. (45)

In December 2005, the NSW Government released City of Cities:  A Plan for Sydney's Future.  It envisaged Sydney as a collection of cities:  two harbour cities (centred on the Sydney CBD and North Sydney) and three river cities (centred on Parramatta, Penrith and Liverpool).  The metropolitan strategy projected a population increase to 2031 of 1.1 million, involving 640,000 new homes of which the bulk (420,000) would be built in existing suburbs, the rest on the urban fringe.  The strategy projected regular review processes.  It specified general aims with set benchmarks.

The projected planning process would be based on ten sub-regional groupings of local governments.  They would test numbers for additional dwellings and jobs in their area, and engage in stakeholder and community consultation.  The resulting numbers would be subject to review by the State Government and, having been determined, would feed into the State budgetary process and activity plans.  The plan asserts that "sufficient" zoned land would be made available for housing and commercial activity.


Melbourne

The Town and Country Planning Act 1944 created a Town and Country Planning Board to advise the Minister for Local Government and empowered municipal councils to prepare planning schemes.  The Board and the local councils asked for a metropolitan plan, which was initiated in 1949.  The Victorian Government delegated preparation of the plan to the existing Melbourne and Metropolitan Board of Works (53 members elected by local councils) and made it the responsible body in 1955.  The plan was notably less prescriptive than Sydney's Cumberland plan, with no intention of restricting the outward growth of suburbs.  It envisaged population growth from 1.4 to 2.5 million and the possibility of further controlled expansion.  From 1956 to 1975 (when the Country Roads Board became the sole highway authority) it was also responsible for "inner highways".  The Victorian State government was also rather less committed to the planning process than NSW.

The Town and Country Planning (Amendment) Act 1968 enlarged the Board of Works' planning responsibilities to 5,000 square kilometres (but not the Mornington Peninsula), created a State Planning Council of heads of major public works authorities, and set up the structures for pre-determined State planning policy and regional plans.  The Minister for Planning Act 1973 separated ministerial responsibilities for planning and local government.  In the early 1970s, the concept of preferred development corridors was also developed -- that is, that urban spread be restricted and channelled.  The use of land rationing as a basis of policy has steadily increased since.  (See Appendix 1) (46)

The late 1970s were notable for the Housing Commission land deals scandal, where an inquiry (the Gowens Inquiry) found that land was purchased at inflated prices (possibly due to collusion between a Commission purchasing officer and local real estate agents) leaving insufficient funds to develop the sites which remained undeveloped for years.  Some of the land had not been properly surveyed and was subject to flooding or zone restrictions. (47)  The 1980 Metropolitan Strategy Plan sought to consolidate growth in inner Melbourne -- "the hole in the middle of a swelling doughnut" in the words of the Chairman of the Melbourne and Metropolitan Board of Works -- and aimed to reduce investment in infrastructure on the urban fringe. (48)

The Kennett Government dramatically restructured local government, reducing the number of Metropolitan councils from 56 to 31.  Planning for the inner city was set out in the 1994 Creating Prosperity:  Victoria's Capital City Policy and for the wider metropolitan area by the 1995 Living Suburbs:  A Policy for Metropolitan Melbourne and the Twenty-First Century which claimed that 20 years of urban land supply was available at the fringe. (49)

The Bracks Government engaged in a major consultation exercise which produced Melbourne 2030:  Planning for Sustainable Growth (2002) which was very similar to the previous Living Suburbs, apart from being keener on "green wedges". (50)  These are to be protected "through tougher planning controls over use and development, the introduction of the urban growth boundary, changes to planning provisions and changes to legislation". (51)


Perth

An advisory plan for the metropolitan region was released in 1955 by the office of the Commissioner for Town Planning.  The Metropolitan Region Town Planning Scheme Act 1959 set up a Metropolitan Region Planning Authority under the Metropolitan Region Town Planning Scheme Act 1959.  A statutory plan was adopted in 1963 with coverage over 5,400 square kilometres for a staged expansion of the city from a population of 0.5 to 1.4 million.

The authority was deliberately designed to avoid problems encountered by the Cumberland County Council in Sydney and the Board of Works in Melbourne, particularly through direct representation of major public agencies and local government.  While better co-ordination of public authorities was achieved, interaction with the private sector was less harmonious, with significant land speculation.  Interim development controls were first imposed in 1956, including the stopping of "premature" subdivision of land.  The creation of one-way bets in land ownership led to considerable inflation of land and house prices.  Agreements with developers came to incorporate controlled prices.

Large tracts of land were privately purchased in anticipation of population being in excess of projections, with anticipated zoning changes.  In 1971, the planning authority released the Corridor Plan for Perth, prescribing four corridors of urban growth from a central urban core. (52)  The creation of a Department of Conservation and Environment led to the division of the State into river system areas.  Perth was part of System 6 covering the South-West of the State and the number of areas reserved for conservation reasons increased.  The 1987 Planning for the Future of the Perth Metropolitan Region sought increased urban consolidation, but the 1990 Metroplan reverted to the previous corridor concept.  Railway lines were re-opened (Perth-Fremantle), three existing suburban lines electrified, and the new Northern Suburbs Transit System was developed along with an expansion of freeways. (53)

The 1990s saw the completion of many road projects originally envisaged by the 1963 Metropolitan Region Scheme.  More recent planning has again focused on increased public transport.  Unlike the trend elsewhere, Perth has also seen an increase in the number of local governments. (54)


Brisbane

The Greater Brisbane Council began to exercise some control over land use in 1935, but a statutory planning authority was not established until 1965.  The City of Brisbane (Town Plan) Act 1959 resulted in the gazetting of a statutory plan (without road proposals) in 1965.  Legislation was passed enabling the Council to negotiate contributions to the costs of water supply and sewerage services, plus contributions in cash or kind for open space, roads and other public improvements.

A later plan was gazetted in 1971.  It did not set out long-term intentions for urban expansion, and land use changes, including from rural to urban, were negotiated rather than prescribed.  In that year, an amendment to the City of Brisbane (Town Plan) Act (opposed by Lord Mayor Clem Jones whose highly service-oriented notion of planning is quoted at the beginning of this monograph) required the preparation of a revised plan by February 1975, including a statement of goals and intentions.  A plan was issued but not endorsed by the Council.

The State and Regional Planning, Public Works and Environmental Control Act 1971 gave the State Co-ordinator General very wide powers over the plans and development of all public authorities, including local governments.  The use of City Council planning powers to collect contributions to public works was the salient feature of Brisbane planning up to the mid-1970s. (55)

Brisbane and surrounding areas -- the South-East Queensland Region -- grew rapidly, but metropolitan planning remained largely of a zoning form until the election of a Labor government in 1989.  The initial The Brisbane Plan:  A City Strategy (1990) was only released as a discussion document, but a South-Eastern Region Planning Project was undertaken. (56)

The 1998 Regional Framework for Growth proposes to manage growth while preserving the separate identity of Brisbane, the Gold Coast, the Sunshine Coast and Toowoomba in a planning timeframe extending to 2011, by which time 3 million people are expected to be living in the region.  Brisbane City Council's 1998 Brisbane 2011:  The Livable City for the Future calls for transit-oriented development within a framework concerned for environmental sustainability. (57)


Adelaide

Adelaide was the last of the mainland capitals to adopt a metropolitan plan.  Since 1955, however, subdivisions in the metropolitan area have only been permitted if they could be economically provided with sewerage by the relevant State authority (in this period, the Department of Engineering and Water Supply).  Adelaide was the only metropolitan capital not to experience a significant backlog of sewerage connection.

Until the early 1970s, it was the only metropolitan capital to avoid significant inflation in land prices.  When signs of a land price boom appeared in 1972, the State government responded with the Land Prices Control Act 1973.

The South Australian State government was also by far the most active State government in housing and other forms of urban development.  The provision of cheap and fully-serviced land, plus some rental premises for industrial plants, was part of a concerted effort to attract manufacturing to the State.  The South Australian Housing Trust provided housing, not merely for the needy, but for middle-income families as well, building about one-third of new houses in South Australia in the post-war period.  In the early postwar period, this involved sacrifices in more normal areas of public development, such as schools and hospitals.

A State Planning Authority was created and a Metropolitan Development Plan adopted in 1967 under the Planning And Development Act 1966-67, following a select committee originally appointed in 1955 and which reported in 1962.  A metropolitan planning area of 1,840 square kilometres was established, with urban expansion concentrated in six districts providing for growth to 1991 and an urban population of almost 1.4 million. (58)

The focus of planning remained on housing, though broadened to a "systems planning" approach that incorporated infrastructure development.  The comparatively slow growth of Adelaide after the 1960s meant that there was less pressure to revise planning.  The 2020 Vision document, released after a 1990-92 review, emphasised urban consolidation and directed peripheral growth to the north of the city, away from the McLaren Vale wine region.  Planning has focused on urban consolidation and protecting water catchment areas.  A steady process of amalgamating local councils has also occurred, from 30 to 19 in the metropolitan area.  Adelaide was also the putative location (on environmentally-degraded land) of the MultiFunctionPolis concept (a Japanese-based futuristic city), the plans for which finally collapsed in 2000. (59)


Hobart

From 1944, local councils were empowered to prepare and implement land use plans under the general supervision of a Commissioner for Town and Country Planning.  A Southern Metropolitan Region Planning Authority with representatives from the City of Hobart and the four other metropolitan municipalities was set up in 1958.  A State Planning Co-ordinator's office was set up in 1974.  At that stage, about 20 per cent of the State's new dwellings were built by the Department of Housing for rental or sale. (60)



4 AUSTRALIAN LAND POLICY OVERVIEW

By the late 1960s and early 1970s, the price of land for housing was rising markedly more rapidly than other prices.  Planning authorities blamed developers for "holding land vacant" until the price rose, developers blamed the shortage of land with planning permission. (61)  Since the former behaviour was rational commercial behaviour under conditions of land rationing, in a sense they were both correct.

Provision of services by local councils and public authorities had generally lagged behind suburban expansion in the 1950s and 1960s.  This led to increasing provision of the requirement that developers pay for such services, especially as lack of sewerage, in particular, became less publicly acceptable.

This, in turn, pushed the cost of infrastructure increasingly "up front" to housing market entrants (62) and foreclosed the previously existing option of accepting a lag in service provision in order to enter the housing market.  Such policies reduce the level of housing development to that compatible with the concurrent provision of infrastructure.

Prior expenditure on servicing land also increased the cost of holding developed sites vacant, as these changed from merely being -- as they had from the 1920s to the early post-war period -- a survey lot with water and electricity, sometimes accessed by unsealed (or even unmade) road, to being highly capital intensive.

A further area of claimed cost increase to government was the provision of services requiring acquisition of land (such as schools, parks and other public facilities). (63)  In many respects these higher costs may be due to the planners themselves having a preference for services of a standard that those being required to pay for them might regard as excessive.  Doubtless they also reflect the experience of governments facing political pressure to expand transport and recreational facilities once development has been established.

As a result, many small land developers left the industry and the larger firms that remained adopted various strategies to minimise their holdings of developed sites. (64)  It also increased the range of public authorities involved in planning permission. (65)  The more complex the process, the greater the approval risk, which will either be reflected in the prices or in the level of investment.

There is a clear long-term pattern of increasing the requirements on what developers could offer.  This must affect housing market entrants disproportionately -- either the cost is passed on entirely or the rate of return is reduced.  Reducing the rate of return will reduce investment.  Hence, costs imposed on housing developers are, one way or another, always borne by those first entering the housing market.

Land price booms occurred in Perth in the mid-1960s and Adelaide in the early 1970s.  On both occasions, the recommended responses revolved around improved land rationing, as the principle of land use control itself was not criticised. (66)

Inherent in the principle of land rationing was a marked divergence between the price of urban land and adjacent rural land.  As one commentator noted:

The whole system of land use control distributes wealth to sitting private owners in an apparently arbitrary manner.

Betterment taxes, land tax surcharges and (in the case of Canberra) use of Crown leasehold have all been recommended or applied as attempts to deal with the problem. (67)  After all, if one argued that separation of control of the use of land (planning) from the financial results of such decisions (ownership) generated inherent contradictions, one solution was to make the public planner the owner. (68)  (Alternatively, one could make the private owner the land-use controller.)

Planning has gradually been intensified as each new measure brings distortions of values that land owners and those seeking new houses will seek to circumvent.  The outcome throughout Australia -- and not just in the major cities -- has been a steady restriction through planning controls on the property owner's freedom to enjoy and profit from his or her land.

Each major urban area is now buffered by a green curtain, circumventing which is a designated urban growth boundary.  Within that boundary, development -- house building, construction of shops, construction of leisure centres -- is forbidden without permission.

Outside of the boundary, a blanket denial of development is in place.  In Victoria, for example, no dwelling may be built unless it is on at least 40 hectares of land or 8 hectares if it is located in a "rural living zone".

Farmer representatives are reportedly against urban expansion.  They maintain that it pushes up land values (and therefore rates) and brings about restrictions on farming activity.  There is merit in having regard to these matters -- it should, for example, be incumbent on anyone electing to build near farms that have objectionable features to accept those features and relinquish any grounds for seeking to have them curtailed.  Similarly, it appears unfair to charge farmers increased rates unless they obtain correspondingly increased value.

We should, however, be wary of accepting farmer views that amount to vetoes on the uses of land other than their own.  It is easily possible to create a surfeit of democracy whereby the individual is oppressed by a majority.  Land is individually owned and not the responsibility of something called "the community".  It is not appropriate that organisations should be able to lobby successfully for others not to use their property as they see fit -- farmers in general cannot be given a mandate to determine what other farmers do with their land (they do, of course, have the right to insist on non-interference with the peaceful use of their own property).

Metropolitan development in Victoria is controlled under Melbourne 2030.  Not only is housing development constrained, but retail activity is being increasingly concentrated in a limited number of existing large centres.  This is reinforced by existing planning laws which require new retail developments to prove that they will not have a deleterious impact on existing retail centres in their region -- in other words, that they will not compete with existing centres.  The planning laws also require that new centres provide the same level and character of public amenity and access as existing facilities, irrespective of their clients' desires and nature.

As such, planning laws have greatly reduced the scope for expansion of retail infrastructure and vested monopoly rights to incumbent shopping centre owners.  The laws have also reduced the scope for new forms of shopping, such as factory outlets and bulky goods centres.  These types of retail outlet place a higher premium on car transport than existing centres and planners.  It is, after all, hard to bring a dishwasher, a lathe or 20 boxes of shoes home on the tram.  They also aim to provide a low-cost, single-purpose experience rather than the high-cost, all-things-to-everyone environment forced on shopping centres.

These new facilities have appeared in Australian cities largely because of loopholes in the planning system's universality.  This is exemplified in Melbourne by the example of the recent redevelopment of Essendon airport.  In the late 1990s, the Federal Government decided to sell Essendon, along with most other airports around the country.  While Essendon was to remain a functioning airport, it provided scope to divert a substantial amount of land in a rapidly growing area to other purposes.  Being a Commonwealth entity, the airport was exempt from State and local government planning laws, and specifically from the tentacles of Melbourne 2030.  In pursuit of a higher price and good policy, the Government sold the property with the exemption largely intact.

Not surprisingly, the purchaser of Essendon airport paid a premium for the property and announced its intention to redevelop the site as a large retail centre, starting with a 120-store, Direct Factory Outlet centre.  Again, not surprisingly, the owners and financiers of existing shopping centres were furious and pursued legal actions to stop the development.  The development undermined the monopoly powers they had obtained and the profit that flowed from them.  The State Government and its planners also resisted the decision, as it undermined their ability to extract their own share of the excess prices stemming from the protection of existing centres, as well as their control over people's actions and lifestyle.

Similar developments in other States have arisen where Commonwealth land at airports has been excised from State-based planning controls.  As in Melbourne, State planning restraints have been circumvented around Sydney and Brisbane airports where non-State-approved shopping centres have been built.

Michael Baker from the UrbisJHD consultancy has assembled data on shops per head of population.  His findings reveal Australia to be under-provided with shops compared with the most liberal jurisdiction, the US.  It is, however, rather better provided for than in some other countries where planning restraints are even greater, for example, in Hong Kong, where space itself is the constraint. (69)

One outcome of the restraint on shopping space in Australia is higher prices -- Baker finds occupancy costs in US regional shopping malls average 13 per cent of sales, as opposed to 16-17 per cent in Australia.  Another outcome of the planning restrictions is a higher turnover in Australian supermarkets, a performance that brings with it a corollary of diminished consumer choice and convenience.

Restraint of competition in shopping services is a clear case of government's seeking to impose its own views and preferences on those of the consumer.  Ostensibly, aside from wanting to protect existing facilities from competition, the planners were seeking to ensure relatively favourable treatment for those using public transport.  Their concerns were that those without a car would be discriminated against.  Regulations, with associated costs, were promulgated to require better access for public transport than shopping centre owners would otherwise see as profitable to arrange.  In effect, all users are required to contribute a fee (by means of higher charges for the goods and services supplied in the centre) to ensure greater provision of public transport for the benefit of those without cars.  Alternatively put, because not everyone has access to a car, the regulations seek to ensure that nobody may use a center which does not give non-car owners the same advantages as car owners.

Table 1:  Shopping Centre and Total Retail Space Per Capita, Selected Countries

United States (2003}20.239.2
New Zealand (2000)4.325.8
Australia (2003)6.420.4
United Kingdom (2000)3.214.0
Hong Kong (2003)N/A12.9
South Korea (2002)N/A12.9
Singapore (2003)4.310.8
Canada (2003)12.8N/A
Japan (2002)3.210.8

Source:  UrbisJHD, FPD Savills, ICSC, FW Dodge, Michael Baker


Such measures are never likely to be efficient and fail a major test of public policy by being totally non-transparent.  It is impossible to gauge the costs and the degree to which different consumers are paying them.  This is, in all likelihood, intentional.  Government agencies and the pressure groups to which they are responding would prefer the costs to be hidden rather than have them opened to public scrutiny.  Few seem fazed that this is alien to the principles of democratic responsible government.  Taxation, not hidden regulatory costs, is the appropriate vehicle to pay for distributing resources from those who are deemed able to support others to those deemed worthy of such support.

The hidden form of taxation caused by regulatory measures like those identified and proudly paraded in Planning Schemes makes it difficult for the community to evaluate, or even to recognise, it as a charge on their purchases.  Contravening competition in this way means higher prices, with the planning authorities redirecting some of these excessive prices back to services favouring groups that the planners deem worthy of such subsidies.  Because some developers have paid their political dues and gained a priority planning permission as a result of offering outlays that government bodies want, this means that they are keen to capitalise on the restraint from competition they have bought.  At the very least they are keen to impose similar costs on their competitors.

None of these regulatory favours come free of costs and, as recent high-profile corruption charges in northern Melbourne, Geelong, and the Gold Coast have demonstrated, the current planning approach creates pools of resources that corrupt democratic processes.

Not only do government institutions ration land on the basis of their perception of need, but they (and the electorate) acquiesce in that need being under-fulfilled, and accept the price consequences of shortage.  Moreover, with respect to shopping centers or theatre complexes, the government criteria for agreeing to new providers include prerequisites that the existing providers will not be adversely impacted by the competition.

In the wider areas of government, not only would such strictures be rare, they would be recognised as harmful to the interests of consumers and would, indeed, be illegal under Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act.  Governments, at least ostensibly, have accepted the benefits of competition and have outlawed measures that allow monopolies in supply and other restraints of trade.  In the case of commercial infrastructure within cities, governments not only tolerate monopolies but also aid and abet them (70) yet they insouciantly test their planning restraints against the same anti-competition laws and somehow find them to be conforming.

Shops and other commercial infrastructure exist to supply services to willing consumers.  They do not have a reason for existence per se and to offer them protection undermines the efficiency of the retailers who supply services to consumers.



5 THE EVOLUTION OF PLANNING: 
SERVICING NEEDS TO CREATING VISIONS

A feature of the history of planning in Britain, apart from its spiralling up from relatively small beginnings, was a succession of fashionable visions that promoted new and progressively more intense measures of control.  Each increase in dissatisfaction with the results of past plans was generally met by the substitution of new plans and expanded planning.  But if planners were not subject to notable public satisfaction with what had happened, some could take satisfaction in what hadn't.

One elderly planner remarked that his greatest lifetime achievement could be judged by what had not been built as a result of his efforts.  In particular he had prevented two conurbations joining up in a continuous sprawl. (71)

In the words of Robert Bruegmann:

Yes, and every time people get these things that were once the privilege only of the rich there's a vast resentment factor.  So if you look at the people who are really angry about sprawl, a lot of these are people in the central city, they're used to being the ones to tell everybody else how to live.  It's also people at the very edge and what they don't want is someone in the field next to them building exactly the same kind of houses that they have.  So it's very understandable why a lot of the people who are angry about sprawl are angry about sprawl. (72)

Planning at its most utilitarian simply makes sure that services such as electricity, roads, water, sewerage and so forth go to where people are choosing to be.  But that is a very user friendly, service-oriented, conception of planning.  Grand visions are much more inspiring.  But such visions are based on deeply dubious presumptions:

  • that ordinary people, left to their own devices, will systematically make wrong decisions;
  • that the purposes of urban life are fully known to planners;
  • that the future is clear to planners;
  • that both will be faithfully reflected in planning decisions;  and
  • that centralised coercion processes information, and expresses social knowledge, better than dispersed consent.

Built into such a grand conception of the role of the urban planner is a curious combination of disrespect for other people's choices, and the processes which express them, with hubristic confidence in their own.  The experience of urban planning does not give much support for this stark dichotomy.


LOBBYING AS THE GENERATOR OF INCREASED HOUSING COSTS

Post-war Australia saw a boom in home ownership, which rose rapidly from just over 50 per cent of households being owner-occupiers to 70 per cent in the mid-1960s.  Home-building was increasingly efficient, employment high and capital available at cheap rates. (73)  And planning (particularly in the form of land rationing) was relatively underdeveloped.

Public housing was not well targeted -- the 1973 Henderson Enquiry found that most of those in public housing were not poor and most of the poor were not in public housing.  Land clearances were unpopular and the high-rise flats that were constructed on them not liked by families who lived in them. (74)  Of course, as urban land becomes more expensive, if public housing investment is held constant, the capacity to build new housing will fall.

However, home ownership rates and the production of new rental housing began to decline in the late 1960s, with housing prices and rents outstripping inflation, (75) and the size of new houses increasing markedly, (76) as land-rationing-based planning gathered pace.  By 1975, the cost of servicing a new suburban block in Melbourne was about $9,000 -- 40 per cent or more of the building costs of an average house and about a year's income to the average occupier. (77)

Thus a cruel paradox developed.  Since the effective housing performance of the 1950s, national productivity per head had increased by as much as a third.  To a lesser degree building productivity had also improved;  real building costs were low by international standards and still trended downward.  But a richer and more productive population found that it could now supply home ownership to a falling proportion of young households with children -- although in real terms the houses were cheaper to build, and more households were willing and able to pay for them, both annually and overall, than ever before.  And as more people became captive tenants, public and private investment in new rental housing declined. (78)

THE SAVE OUR SUBURBS PHENOMENON

Mobility is both a blessing and a curse of modern urban living.  First railways, and then cars, greatly expanded the area a metropolis could cover, enormously widening the proportion of society who could afford to own a home-with-a-garden.  The huge long-term drop in the population density of cities, at least in the developed world, is a direct result of that increased mobility.

But if people became more mobile, so did commerce and industry.  Indeed, it has been argued that the rise of zoning laws is a direct result of that mobility, as people sought to preserve the amenity of their local areas. (79)  People do not merely "buy a house".  They buy a house in a particular area with a particular character.  They are naturally likely to resent, and resist, changes that reduce that amenity without any compensation (indeed, in extreme cases, may directly reduce their property values).

The land rationing which is justified by the demonisation of "sprawl" has the inevitable consequence, given rising population and falling household sizes, of requiring increased population density in cities where such land rationing occurs.  Existing home-owning residents benefit from the rising property values that come from such land rationing, but often resent the loss of amenity from the increased crowding.  They are likely to resent especially the high-rise accommodation and development which results from increasingly expensive metropolitan land being channelled into as high-value uses as possible, particularly in the inner city.  Yet it is precisely the existence of such alternative uses that helps sustain the upward pressure on the value of their own properties.

The desire to continue to accrue the benefits to existing owners of metropolitan land rationing, without suffering the natural consequences of loss of amenity from increased crowding, naturally leads to increased pressure being placed on planning systems, which are expected to resolve the inevitable consequences of these incompatible pressures.

Hence the self-contradictions which show up in "resident politics", as exemplified by organisations such as Save Our Suburbs (Victoria). (80)  Save Our Suburbs (SOS Vic) states as a basic policy principle the protection of the property rights of residents.

E1 The property rights of existing residents must be respected (81)

But it is quite clear, that it means existing and continuing residents.  It is not in favour of the property rights of those who decide to sell-and-leave (which invites unwanted uses) or would like to enter the home-owning market as cheaply as possible.  In particular, it wants strong restrictions on the property rights of "developers".  The emphasis on a strong, pervasive and extensive planning system is clearly based on the notion that other people's choices are the problem, while reflecting the priority of their own choices.  SOS endorses land rationing:

A6 SOS believes that the urban expansion of Melbourne should be contained by means of direct government intervention to prevent the development of peripheral agricultural and other land

CI SOS recognises and supports the need to limit the geographical spread of Melbourne

D3 The urban expansion of Melbourne should be contained, so far as necessary, by direct restrictions or controls upon the development of peripheral land

(In other words, we have our old suburbs, but you are not allowed your new ones.) SOS accepts that some increased density is therefore inevitable:

A3 SOS believes there is a case for an increase in residential density in some areas

But wants it to be as "nice" (read controlled) as possible:

A4 SOS believes that medium and high density development should take place in properly chosen locations and in a coordinated fashion, rather than upon an unplanned and sporadic basis.
A5 SOS believes that greater densities can and should be achieved without adversely affecting existing residents, with better quality results than at present.

The negative consequences of land rationing are blamed on "the market":

... the market should not be allowed to follow its own direction based as it is purely on short-term financial gain, which is potentially diametrically opposite to the needs of orderly forward planning The lack of controlled planning -- read market driven development -- has got Melbourne into the position it is in today. (82)

SOS endorses (B1) the Charter for Planning:

4.5 Containment of urban spread

Planning must seek to control the spread of urban development onto rural land, and more especially to land of high economic, natural or cultural value (p.4)

Because of its endorsement of land rationing and its multiplication of the criteria to be met (efficiency, social equity, economical sustainability, quality of life, amenity, conservation of nature, conservation of cultural significance, quality of design, common interest, property equity, consistency, public input and accountability, transparency, freedom from political interference, compensation for demonstrable loss, amenity ...), (83) this is clearly a charter for very highly intrusive planning.

SOS wants quick, orderly, certain planning with local democratic control.  (Clearly there is some tension between the latter and the consequent likelihood of the former.)

The fundamental cornerstone of any planning regime in a democracy is transparency, public control and oversight. (84)

In a footnote to the SOS policy summary, there is a nice statement of precisely how layered and complex the planning system is:

(Note 1) This includes legislation, state policies, published guidelines, municipal strategic statements, planning scheme ordinances, overlays, neighbourhood character studies, the advertising of applications, the control of demolition, processing of applications at municipal level, hearings of the Victorian Civil and Administrative Tribunal, and interventions by the Minister.

SOS complains about problems in the planning process:

long timeframes, inconsistent decisions and difficulty in amending planning schemes ... (85)

and notes that the folk actually charged with doing and implementing the planning often don't do such a good job:

... in our experience, it is often local objectors rather than council planners who reveal inconsistencies, errors and omissions in DA proposals and plans ... (86)

neither of which is surprising given the weight of demands with which the planning system is expected to deal.  SOS clearly feels that local, majoritarian planning is the solution:

E2 Where a majority of owners in a specified precinct desire height limits or other planning controls, these controls should be established and enforced by the planning system.

With strong controls over demolition (Section H) and design (Section M).  Developers are to pay all infrastructure costs:

A7 SOS believes that all forms of development should bear the direct and indirect costs involved, so far as these can be calculated, unless a sub sidy is required in the public interest and for explicit reasons.

Which gets to the heart of the problem.  SOS wants to stop (negative) third-party effects on how property owners use their property.  But its endorsement of land rationing immediately imposes a huge third-party effect on renters and those seeking to enter the home-with-garden market (and a pervasive tax on development) which dwarfs the amenity losses it worries about and which themselves are overwhelmingly predictable consequences of that very land rationing.

Rather gloomily in this respect, in the course of a very influential piece in the New York Times, Edward Glaeser (87) speculates that, above a certain price level, housing price escalation takes on a life of its own as residents seek to boost prices by calling for building restrictions.  This is not inconsistent with the different attitudes to housing in Germany and England, whereby in the former's relatively unrestricted environments, the issue of house prices rarely appears in the newspapers and never on the front pages.

Glaeser also examines whether judges have become much more sympathetic to blocking development for environmental reasons.  However, having faced some adverse judgements, SOS wants the role of the Victorian Civil and Administrative Tribunal (VCAT) severely restricted. (88)  Yet the more a regulatory regime is expected to do, the more judicial oversight will be dragged in, as the more grounds there will be to appeal because of clashes between different criteria.  SOS constantly sees as "solvable", with the "right" approach, problems which are largely inherent in a system based on land rationing, given rising population, falling household sizes and residents' natural wish to resist the loss of amenity from the increased crowding that the same land rationing makes inevitable.  Regulation is not costless.  Multiplying desirable criteria is not costless.  Multiplying information processing demands is not costless.  The more that centralised planning is expected to do, the less well it will inevitably function.

The politics of protecting the amenity and rising property values of existing residents simply expresses the inevitability of increasing conflict over property use which land rationing imposes.  Once State Governments endorse land rationing, intensified residential protest and activism is what they must expect.

Jim Fedako puts this issue in trenchant terms.  He says that, regrettably, with planning, "property owners -- community members -- can use government to roll over the rights of developers and fellow property owners".  He points out that

The free market has a tool that allows a property owner to align the future use of his property with his vision, the restrictive covenant.  A property owner could, for example, create a legacy by selling his land contingent on the development carrying his family name.  Should the property owner be too restrictive, the value of his property will fall.  He will be exchanging a psychic good, a family legacy, for cash.

Anything beyond this he regards as communal theft. (89)  Certainly, such residential activities are seeking to trade down property rights in order to trade up increased scarcity value and amenity.



6 PLANNING AND LAND PRICES

THE LAND RATIONING OUTCOME OF PLANNING

Each Australian policy approach -- leasehold in Canberra, extensive Land Commission activity in Adelaide, a territorially expansive local government authority in Brisbane -- has proved, sooner or later, to fall prey to exactly the same pressures, as these pressures are inherent in planning based on land rationing.  No planning approach which threatens the property values of home-owners is likely to gain, or retain, political approval.  Local governments are particularly vulnerable to rate-payer revolts (90) and provincial and national governments are also highly likely to be solicitous of home-owners' concerns about what is, for so many voters, their prime asset.  Land rationing protects the property values of existing home-owners;  it thus provides a powerful political protection to planning.

But land rationing -- combined with increasing population (91) -- means increased density and land prices, generating conflict over existing amenity, increasing rents, and pricing new entrants out of the housing market.  Planning based on land rationing thus generates and exacerbates the increased conflict for which it purports to be the solution.  As long as planning is seen as beneficial, each problem generated then justifies more planning.

Land rationing also undermines the effect of competitive jurisdictions.  Land rationing raises local government rate revenue across all resident landowners (which is particularly attractive, as it raises revenues from people to whom a basic network of services had already been provided by discriminating against folk for whom further services would have to be provided).  Land rationing thus systematically undermines fiscal incentives for local governments to provide for those seeking to enter the home-owning market -- particularly if State Governments effectively act as "land cartel enforcers".

Land rationing is certainly not beneficial for low-income groups or for spreading wealth in society more broadly.  It is most unlikely that restrictions on people's use of their property, and costs loaded on to the provision of housing, can be arranged to offer greater opportunities and provision for the most marginal members of society and create a more equal society.  This is particularly so because more expensive housing means, over the longer term, more expensive rents. (92)

Planning itself is a device whereby the costs of the preferences of the planners can be imposed on other people.  Naturally, this has proved congenial to those who think themselves likely to be able to get the planning process to reflect their preferences.  Hence the persistent notion that the solution to the problems created by land rationing is to have even more land rationing.  The development of science (including social science) has encouraged the notion that people are manipulable social units and continually added to the analytical tools allegedly able to improve planning.  More importantly -- since such tools have regularly failed to live up to the claims about their utility -- it has multiplied the concerns that planning is deemed needed for.  But technological and social change has not become any more predictable.  So the more planning seeks to do, the more at the mercy of technological and social change it becomes.  And the wider the inherent clash with what people want, the greater the likely unintended consequences.

Each intervention provides benefits and costs.  Removing the intervention threatens any beneficiaries, so the normal pattern has been to add further interventions to try to deal with the costs of previous ones, with the adjustment of previous interventions being far more likely than their removal. (93)  The pooling of action involved in centralised decision-making obscures costs, trade-offs and consequences.  The result has been a burgeoning pattern of interventions, each laid upon the previous.

There is quite a pattern of commentators surveying with dissatisfaction the results of previous planning efforts, which are deemed unsatisfactory in terms of their effects because they are insufficiently comprehensive.  They therefore conclude that planners need more power and that plans need to be more intrusive.  In their view, it is simply a matter of having the correct policy intentions and broad enough planning powers.

Planning, when motivated by the best of intentions, is the desire to do good.  But not all planning is so nobly motivated and, in any case, good is something of which there is always more to be done.  Sometimes, those promoting particular courses in the name of the best interests of "the community" are doing so knowing that other people bear the cost.  Those bearing the costs will often seek to avoid them, thereby undermining the plans.  And often, in pursuit of its objective, planning will show inadequate respect for people's liberties (particularly those of property owners).  Such approaches are always likely to rebound on the original egalitarian intentions.

These matters aside, there is a continual presumption that planning will be done by official paragons of virtue and intellect.  In practice, it is done by career-protecting bureaucrats making decisions within their comfort zones.  The decision-makers have poor information feedbacks on the effects of their decisions, which themselves are overlaid by political pressures.

Median income/median house price ratios across the settler-societies of North America vary from a ratio of median house prices being 2.2 times median income in Buffalo NY to median house prices being 11.5 times median income in Los Angeles. (94)  This indicates quite clearly that policy choices are central to housing outcomes.  Australia has such comparatively unaffordable metropolitan housing because it chooses to do so.  Australia has the lowest land-to-population ratio in the developed world and probably the most efficient house-building industry in the developed world.  That its metropolitan housing is so expensive (whether renting or buying), that the dream of owning one's own house requires such financial efforts, are major public policy outcomes.  These outcomes are the regrettable testimony to the efforts of public policy entrepreneurs.


ACKNOWLEDGED PLANNING FAILURES

As a concept, planning is ambiguous.  It can range from facilitating what people want to do (that is, plan for people) to requiring people to act according to the convenience of planners (people for the plan).

In many modern cities, public housing offers stark reminders of the distinction.  Public housing blocks, not without reason, are seldom home to the planners and their residents, as allocatees don't get a choice in the design features.  The notorious features (and frequent failures) of public housing often flow from blocked information feedbacks.

This makes them prime examples of the failure of central planning writ small.  Places where public housing has been better done incorporate more effective information feedbacks (such as Singapore, where local MPs are ex officio members of housing block committees;  or the shift to allowing residents to become owners or part-owners).  The desire to own one's own home is, above all, a desire for control -- to be able to plant and change and paint where one lives as one wishes.  Plans that work well, work with people's preferences.  Plans that work badly, work against them.

Unfortunately, in a market economy, "working badly" typically gets expressed through market outcomes.  This is then blamed on "capitalism", "developers", "speculators" or "greed" rather than the regulatory environment that constricted the ways in which the market could operate.  In turn, this then "justifies" more such restrictions, usually on the basis of the intentions of such policies (almost always at least superficially praiseworthy and easily conveyed in slogans and sound-bites), rather than their predictable outcomes (which often require somewhat more complicated reasoning and evidence to tease out).  Policy makers can also avoid taking responsibility for the consequences of policy regimes.  The Victorian (Kennett) Government Planning Minister Maclellan provided an excellent example of this:

It is not the government driving medium density housing, but market forces and consumer demand.  The people in this city want and need higher density housing. (95)

If there is a prime case of successful planning operating towards the more restrictive end of "planning", it would be Stockholm.  Sweden is often held up as being the premier social democratic state.  And Stockholm planning has a long history of dealing mostly intelligently with city growth -- seeing it as inevitable, and something to deal with, rather than pernicious, and thus something to frustrate.  Sweden had the advantage of being culturally homogeneous (thus minimising communication failures between officials and the public) and admirably democratic.  Yet, even in this prime case, problems of failing to plan for people were persistent.  In 1945, the overwhelming majority (90 per cent) of those who wished to live in suburbs did not want to live in apartment blocks.  Yet, as a result of regulatory restrictions, apartment blocks continued to dominate suburban housing construction for decades.  Construction failed to keep up with demand, with waiting lists lengthening to up to ten years (rationing by queue, rather than rationing by price).  Hence jokes such as:

A young couple decided to wait until they got a flat to get married.  "Why don't you move in with your parents?" the boyfriend was asked.  "Because they are still living with my grandparents".

By the 1970s, the mismatch between plans and public preferences resulted in a change in policy.  In 1970, more than 70 per cent of all new dwellings in Sweden were for rental properties.  By 1977, only 28 per cent were for rental, 72 per cent of completions were for private ownership.  By the mid-1980s, the majority of completions were single-family homes.  The planners disliked the new suburbs intensely.  In the words of one commentator obviously not sympathetic to the suburban model, they were

... closely packed houses in unimaginative uniform rows, reminiscent of the worst kind of American suburbia, but the demand was huge and they sold easily. (96)

If Swedes escape to the benefits of detached suburban living as soon as they are permitted to, it is unlikely that Australians will willingly display any less attachment to home-and-garden-they-can-control.  As, of course, they don't.

But, in a liberal democratic society, a conflict between the desire of families to control their living environment and the desires of planners to make such choices for them is, of necessity, obscured as much as possible.  Linguistic tricks disguise restrictions on property owners and home-builders profiting from responding to consumer preferences.  The entire rhetoric denouncing "sprawl" and "suburbia" is precisely about belittling people's living preferences.  The invocation of environmental concerns and worship of greenery is equally about such belittling.  Planning becomes a vision of Virtue in the eyes of the self-styled virtuous, with little connection to individual preferences.  Accordingly, it relies on the regulatory powers of the state in order to prevail against market preferences.


REGULATION AND HOUSING SUPPLY:  CONTRASTING GERMANY AND ENGLAND

The outcome of planning systems on new home prices was demonstrated in recent research on housing, Bigger Better Faster More, by Policy Exchange in Britain.  This offers firm evidence of the causes of the problem and its effects.  It compares Germany, where there is a pro-housing planning approach, with Britain where, like Australia, there is a restrictive approach to the availability of land for houses.

Some comparative statistics between Germany, the UK and Australia are shown in Table 2.

Britain abandoned the satellite town approach to growth in 1951, though one new town (Milton Keynes) was built after that.  Instead, a very exclusionary building permit regime was established with the 1947 Town and Country Planning Act.  This strongly constrained the availability of land for housing.  Bruegmann argues that:

The British growth management system, like all anti-sprawl policies was most favourable for what I have called the incumbents' club:  those who were already well off and happy with their existing circumstances. (97)

Table 2:  Population and housing statistics, Germany, UK and Australia

GermanyUKAustralia
Population (million)826020
Urban population share (%)889085
Population growth 1979-2005 (% pa)0.160.241.32
Decline in average household size 1980-2003 (persons)-0.3-0.3-0.4
Persons per km2230.9246.92.6
Growth of GDP/capita 1970-2003 (% pa)1.42.12.0
Average size of new dwelling (m2)109.276205.7
Completions per 1 .000 inhabitants (2003)3.253.146.54
Home ownership rate (%)40.56768
Vacancy rate (%)8.23.49.2
Real house price growth 1970-2003 (% pa)0 053.872.89

Source:  Evans, A.W., and Hartwich, O.M., Bigger Better Faster More, Policy Exchange, 2005.


Though the planning system has left many villages' architecture relatively frozen in time, the greater density that was the aim and, to some extent, the outcome of this did not prevent traffic congestion in spite of a considerable investment in public transport.

In Germany, houses are one-third bigger than those in Britain and, over the past 30 years, prices in real terms have shown a negligible increase compared with a doubling in Britain.  Germany has a slightly lower population growth and similar density to the UK, although its economy has grown less rapidly over the past decade.

Germany's negligible house price inflation is entirely due to the different approaches to allowing land to be made available for home building.  In Germany, landowners have much greater rights to use their land for the purposes they favour, including developing it for housing.  This is derived from Article 14 of the Basic Law and is called Baufreiheit (Freedom to Build).  In Britain and Australia, land use is dictated by planning agencies such as Victoria's Department of Sustainability and Environment, which severely restricts the areas where housing may be built.  Such laws would be unconstitutional in Germany.

German states (Lander) have highly bureaucratised and ornate planning systems, but the constitutional provision allowing a land owner to have control over his or her property is very powerful.  And the ultimate control rests with the municipality and not the state or federal government.

Local authorities also have a strong interest in development because, in addition to their rates, their share of federal income tax and state government grants is linked directly to the local tax revenue and the number of inhabitants (as is the income of the top local government public servants).  Typically, 40 per cent of a municipality's budget is derived from per capita transfers from state and federal governments.  Moreover, there are constitutional checks and balances on a local authority wishing to raise its rates. (98)

Germany's flexibility in housing supply means that every up-tick in prices is accompanied by an increase in new housing.  House prices themselves are not matters of keen interest to people in general, and rarely feature in newspapers and never on the front page.  Long-term stable home price levels are not newsworthy.  Home ownership levels are also lower, as there is no urgency to buy one's own house -- the benefit of a house as an inflation-beater is missing.


DEVELOPMENTS IN THE USA

The Red and the Blue States

The diversity of the US and the relative influence of local planning areas compared with Australia allow a considerable diversity of outcomes.  Many areas (best characterised by Texas and other Southern and Midwestern areas) have taken a supportive approach to development.  By contrast, California and many of the "rust bucket" states of the north-east have taken a far less permissive approach.  Some have characterised the dichotomy as a Red State/ Blue State issue. (99)  The Blue states, those voting Democrat, generally favour restrictions on new housing development, while the Red states are more permissive.  As Steve Sailer has pointed out, "Bush won the 26 states with the least inflation in housing prices between 1980 and 2004". (100)

This also reflects the preferences of those living in, or moving to, areas where housing is less constrained by planning restraints.  Those with such constraints have "smart" growth philosophies that are geared towards protecting open space and preventing denser developments, thereby raising the property values of incumbents.  Other states tend to favour the newcomers, and new houses are much cheaper.  Not unrelated to this, Sailer has also found a very strong correlation between birth rates per white female and the tendency to vote Republican/live in areas where house prices are lower.

This theme has found support among other commentators.  Thus, Morse (101) argues that:

One of the contributing factors to low fertility is delayed marriage and child-birth.  And one of the contributing factors to delayed marriage is the high cost of setting up an independent household.

It is difficult to assign this factor special prominence, however.  In the US, a market where there is great diversity and low-cost housing even in fast growing cities, the correlation between the lower priced areas and birth rates is relatively low.  This can be crudely done by assigning cities' household affordability in the Demographia data as proxies for affordability in the states in which they are located and comparing this with the number of children under the age of 18.  Such an analysis provides a correlation of only -0.14.  Doubtless there are more sophisticated methodologies that can be applied than the simple one used here, and there are further adjustments possible in terms of income, age profiles, religion, and so on.  Even so, it is difficult to recruit falling birth rates as support for liberalising the housing market on the data available to us.


I'll Take Manhattan

A painstaking study of home prices in Manhattan by Glaeser, Gyourko and Saks (102) has demonstrated the impact of regulation.  Although Manhattan has no developable land, its skyline demonstrates the use of airspace, of which there is a near infinite availability and which, on the face of things, offers little cause for opposition towards more high rise buildings.

There is, however, considerable opposition to new construction and prices have risen markedly over recent years.  During the 1950s, a massive surge in new units was accompanied by only a modest rise in prices while, in the 1980s and 1990s, a much less permissive planning regime brought supply deficits and real price increases of over 50 per cent.

An analysis of costs puts new apartment building costs at $300 per square foot in Manhattan.  This is considerably below the price of new apartments which actually sell at $600 per square foot.  As the authors note, the higher prices are caused by regulatory squeezes on building rights and they go on to say:

A high ratio of sales prices to construction costs does not imply that developers are making excess profits.  On the margin, the benefits of the very high prices should be competed away via legal bills, lobbying fees, the carry costs of invested capital during long delays, or any of the myriad other expenses associated with navigating the city's regulatory maze.  Regulatory barriers essentially function as a tax that adds to the fixed costs of building.


7 PRICE DEVELOPMENTS IN AUSTRALIA

INTERNATIONAL AND AUSTRALIAN PRICE COMPARISONS

Houses and apartment buildings are highly durable items, lasting up to a century or more.  This means that areas with falling populations, due to the loss of jobs, can undergo significant changes in their population profile, as people attracted to cheap housing move in -- particularly if they are not dependent on paid employment for their income. (103)  This process has been occurring in various depressed rural areas in Australia.  But this durability can also mean long periods of price rises well in excess of inflation, if supply of new housing stock is sufficiently restricted, as has been occurring in major capital cities, particularly Sydney.

The effects of this inertia in the case of restricted supply can be quite dramatic:

California homes, which cost on average some $600,000 and even more in the LA and Bay area, are unaffordable to professionals and causing labour supply problems.  The Sacramento campus of the University of California plans to build as many as 500 homes for faculty and staff on 25 acres it bought last year.  A 30 percent discount on homes below the region's median price will help assistant professors get into the housing market, which otherwise would be nearly impossible with a starting salary that averages $48,000. (104)

The data on the Demographia Website (105) provides an excellent resource, particularly when cross-referenced with US Census (106) and Community Survey (107) data.  The 72 US cities listed with their ratios of median income-to-median house prices (that is, their housing (un)affordability index -- as the higher the index, the less affordable the housing) can be examined against various characteristics.  These include population size, population growth, population density, percentage with advanced degrees, percentage living below the poverty line, percentage of population who are foreign born, percentage who speak a language other than English at home, percentage who are Afro-American, plus the percentage of dwellings with owner-occupiers, or percentage with under-18s present.

There is no correlation between housing (un)affordability and the percentage of population below the poverty line (-0.16), with advanced degrees (0.19), of dwellings with under-18s present (-0.14) or with population growth (or decline) since 1990 (0.17).  That is to say, there is no indication that demand factors separate the highly unaffordable cities from the highly affordable cities.  This is pertinent in rebutting analysis from some official sources.

Thus, the Productivity Commission considered that the impact of demand pressures on land prices may only have been:

accentuated by rigidities in the supply chain, such as government interventions which unduly limit the supply of additional land at the urban fringe or the construction of additional dwellings within cities.

Its report argued that:

Although there appears to have been a shortfall in housing supply at the urban fringe -- at least in Sydney -- it is the increased demand for existing dwellings in established areas that has been the primary reason for recent price rises. (108)

Similarly the OECD's Economic Outlook No. 78 only saw a subsidiary role for supply factors in global house price trends.  Its attribution of importance to that aspect was largely confined to the UK.

Clearly, the findings of such bodies will need to be revised in the light of the data being presented by Demographia, which show price responses in the US are related solely to land availability and not to such matters as demand growth per se.

In terms of multiples of household income levels, Australian house prices are now among the highest prices in the world. (109)

According to the Demographia 2006 International Housing Affordability Survey, Sydney ranked seventh in the least affordable housing market from their study of 100 cities in North America, New Zealand, Australia and the United Kingdom.  The study rates urban areas in terms of median housing costs and median income levels.

Table 3:  Twenty most unaffordable housing markets

RankHousing MarketMedian Multiple
1USLos Angeles11.2
2USSan Diego10.8
3USHonolulu10.6
4USVentura County9.6
5USSan Francisco9.3
6USMiami8.8
7AustraliaSydney8.5
8USNew York7.9
9USRiverside7.7
10USSan Jose7.4
11UKLondon6.9
12UKBristol6.8
12USFresno6.8
12USSacramento6.8
15NZAuckland6.6
15AustraliaHobart6.6
15CanadaVancouver6.6
18AustraliaAdelaide6.5
19USLas Vegas6.4
19AustraliaMelbourne6.4

Source:  Demographia;  http://www.demographia.com/dhi-ix2005q3.pdf


The most affordable cities, which include several of comparable size to Sydney, such as Pittsburgh, St Louis, Atlanta, Houston and Quebec, have median house prices that make them only one-third as expensive in relation to median income levels.  The key cause of this disparity is planning constraints that have reduced the availability of land for housing, and house-tax measures often in the guise of development contributions.

Raw land on the periphery suitable for housing has an alternative use of only a few thousand dollars per hectare.  Planning constraints, mandatory infrastructure contributions and housing-specific taxes result in Sydney prices at $300,000 a block and more.  Other cities fare little better.  Thus, land on Melbourne's outskirts in its alternative agricultural use may be worth $3,000 per hectare or a few hundred dollars per block.  The Government planning system creates shortages of housing land by strictly controlling if and when landowners are permitted to offer their property for housing development.

As a result, prices are inflated, pushing up the value of a block of raw land to over $50,000.  On top of this is the development to make the land suitable for housing.  These costs should never amount to more than $25,000 per block, but regulations double this.

Increased prices in existing zones are caused by government-created regulatory scarcity on the periphery, an effect that is often compounded by local NIMBY action designed to prevent more intensive land use.

Table 4:  Tax treatment of owner-occupied and investment housing across countries (110)

Owner-occupied housing

Imputed
rent
taxation
Interest
deducibility
Capital
gains
tax
AustraliaNoNoNo
CanadaNoNoNo
FranceNoNoNo
GermanyNoNo(e) No
JapanNoNoYes
NetherlandsYesYesNo
New ZealandNoNoNo
Sweden(d) YesYesYes
United KingdomNoNoNo
United StatesNoYes(a) No

Investment housing

Negative
gearing
Depreciation
allowances
Capital
gains
tax (a)
Stamp
duty
AustraliaNoYesDiscountYes
CanadaRestrictedYesDiscount(a) Yes
FranceRestrictedYesDiscountYes
GermanyRestrictedYesDiscountYes
JapanYesYesDiscountYes
NetherlandsNoNoDiscountYes
New ZealandYesYes(c) NoNo
SwedenYesYesYes
United KingdomNoYesYes
United StatesRestrictedYesYesNo

(a) "Discount" means less than 100 per cent of the capital gain is taxed
(b) In approximately half of all provinces
(c) Except for depreciation claw back
(d) Through property tax
(e) After two years


The vast dispersion of prices and of price trends provides unassailable empirical evidence that price increases are not due to some general phenomenal-like shifts in interest rates.  Nor is it plausible to attribute great influence to country-specific taxation measures.  The Productivity Commission placed undue influence on such policy measures as the lack of capital gains tax and the ability of rental investors to write off losses from unrelated sources of income.

Whether such measures could be called "concessions" is a moot point -- in the case of write-offs, every new product or service by an existing firm is, by definition, financed from income earned from on-going sales.  However, Table 4 offers little evidence that Australia was unique in its fiscal policy towards housing.

The Productivity Commission also considered whether the First Home Owners Scheme had had a stimulatory effect.  This offered grants of up to $14,000 during 2001 and remains at $7,000.

Doubtless, demand factors have an effect on prices and, in some cases, this can be marked.  But this can only remain so in the face of heavily constrained supply.  Given the size of a house as a purchasing item, it is easy to misunderstand the degree of flexibility of the supply industry.  This is especially so as, at any one time, accretions to the stock are likely to be under 3 per cent.

The supply of new houses is not intrinsically inflexible, however.  The house itself comprises sets of components, the production of which are readily increased.  Sanitary ware, planks, bricks, light fittings are all readily available and supply can be increased rapidly.  And although labour shortages might bring some bottlenecks, this and associated industries have almost doubled and halved in size in very short periods.  There is little in the industry that prevents it responding to demand stimuli differently from other industries.

In the case of the development of land, this takes a very short period of time -- some talk of four posts and a length of piping as being all that is required and, although this is an exaggeration, new land can be brought into the supply chain very quickly and cheaply.

Evidence abounds of the responsiveness of new housing to demand without this necessitating significant price rises.  The greatly varying outcome of house prices in different North American cities is particularly persuasive.  Indeed, it is the most rapidly growing urban areas that have shown the greatest price stability.  Within Australia, the very rapid growth of the southern Queensland Gold Coast area during the 1980s was not accompanied by significant price rises.

That demand pressures do not lead to house price escalation can be substantiated by using ABS and Demographia data.  The correlation between population growth since 1991 and housing (un)affordability in Australia's eight capital cities is mildly negative (-0.43) while the correlation between housing (un)affordability and population density is positive (0.60).  The faster growing cities tend to have more affordable housing, the more densely populated cities more unaffordable housing.

Figure 1:  Real house and land prices ($2003)

Since population growth is the prime demand factor, while density reflects supply constraints, supply factors clearly dominate house prices, at least in such a land-endowed country as Australia.  The significant factor in all cases of low price escalation of houses has been the absence of serious restraints on the availability of land.  There is inherent conflict between consumer choice, housing affordability and advocating greater urban density.


TRENDS IN AUSTRALIAN HOUSE PRICES

While house-building prices have shown little upward trend in real terms (in spite of a marked improvement in quality and features), prices of land have increased in most areas of Australia. (111)

Sydney has led the pack.  In real (2003) dollars, land prices rose sevenfold, on average, between 1973 and 2003 from $59,000 to $461,000, and while house-building costs over the period fluctuated, in 2003 they were only 4 per cent above 1973 levels.  Land prices have actually fallen considerably in Sydney over the past year or so but remain very high in historical terms.  In fact, 2003 land prices in Sydney were four-fold or more of those of other capital cities, but were only 20 per cent higher than Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth in 1973.

Figure 2:  Land prices, broadacre farms

Source:  ABARE farm survey


Unfortunately for new home buyers, land prices have been rising rapidly across the other major cities.  In Melbourne, prices actually fell in the decade to 1983 but in 2003 were two-and-a-half-fold 1973 levels.  A similar picture is evident in the other mainland capitals, although in the case of Adelaide, the price increase has been much more recent than other capitals.

In all cases except Brisbane, house-building costs have risen in real terms by around 15 per cent (in Brisbane house-building costs have risen strongly in the past ten years and in 2003 were 60 per cent above their 1973 levels;  to a major degree this has been driven by demand and quality factors).

Real long-term price levels and changes in the major capitals are shown in Figure 1.  This stands in sharp contrast to the price of rural land (Figure 2), which maintained an average of about $200 per hectare ($2003-04) throughout the 1980s and 1990s.

Looking at high rainfall and sheep-wheat land -- generally closer to capital cities than pastoral zone farms -- farm land in the wheat-sheep zone has shown little movement, averaging $630 per hectare ($2003-04) throughout the 1980s and 1990s.  High rainfall zone farm land, generally closest to the capital cities, has shown a significant increase in the last few years, but moved around an average of $1,180 per hectare ($2003-04) in the 1980s and 1990s.  (See Figure 3.)

The data does not cover market garden land -- which would be a better indicator of the value of land on the urban fringe -- but it is still clear enough that Australia has not been suffering from some general land scarcity.  A hardly surprising result.

Figure 3:  Farm prices, wheat-sheep and high rainfall zones

Source:  ABARE


The point is made even clearer when we compare the change in the average price of high rainfall farmland with changes in the average prices of existing new dwellings in capital cities (all adjusted for inflation) since 1988-89.  (See Figure 4.)

Farmers certainly haven't enjoyed booming prices for their major asset -- but then they are not subject to regulatory land-rationing.


PLANNING FOR HOUSING

Throughout Australia, State and local authorities have placed serious restraints on new building.  These restraints have been particularly severe in NSW, with the previous Premier placing a high priority on restraining population growth, but the same general trend is evident throughout Australia.  As a result, although house-building costs have been kept at around the general level of prices (something of an achievement in view of the increased regulatory impositions on the industry and the fact that new house sizes have gradually increased), new homes have risen markedly in price.  (See Figure 5.)

Figure 4:  Inflation-adjusted farm land and capital city dwelling prices, 1988-89 to 2003-04

Source:  ABARE, REIA


Figure 5:  Housing and material prices, 1985-2003

Source:  ABS (Consumer Price Index, Australia;
House Price Indexes:  Eight Capital Cities)


The land component, which in 1976-77 comprised 32 per cent of a new home in Sydney, in 2005 comprised 62 per cent.  Other capitals have fared little better.  This has been mainly due to the squeeze on land availability that originated in misplaced desires to prevent "urban sprawl".

In terms of the relative share of house and land in the housing package, building costs have been stable because they have not seen the draconian level of regulatory control that has squeezed the availability of land, especially around the capital cities.  As a proportion of the house-land package, all States have seen the land component move from being a minor to, in most cases, a dominant share over the past 30 years.  In Sydney, the land component went from 33 per cent to 78 per cent;  in Brisbane from 30 per cent to 55 per cent;  in Adelaide from 14 per cent to 61 per cent;  and in Perth from 35 per cent to 54 per cent.  Only in Melbourne did land remain under half the package cost, but only barely, as land rose from 33 per cent to 49 per cent of the total cost.

These trends are at the heart of the blow-out of Australian housing affordability.

It is difficult to assess the degree to which these prices have also been increased by development taxes.  By requiring those in new suburbs to bear the costs for sewerage systems, roads, parks, schools, community facilities etc., these upfront taxes discriminate in favour of those living in the established suburbs.

Table 5:  Share of House and Land in Housing Package

1973198319932003
Sydney
Land
House

0.33
0.68

0.40
0.60

0.47
0.53

0.73
0.22
Melbourne
Land
House

0.33
0.67

0.31
0.69

0.40
0.60

0.49
0.51
Brisbane
Land
House

0.30
0.70

0.42
0.58

0.46
0.54

0.55
0.45
Perth
Land
House

0.35
0.65

0.38
0.62

0.57
0.43

0.54
0.46
Adelaide
Land
House

0.14
0.86

0.38
0.63

0.47
0.53

0.61
0.39

Source:  HIA


Figure 6:  Medium density stamp duty and regulatory costs, 2006

Source:  UrbisJHD


As part of this regulatory price forcing, the HIA estimates that the direct regulatory "tax" on new subdivisions in western Sydney is $60,000.  Though some of this may contribute to the value of the subdivision, much of it is for social infrastructure such as "affordable housing contributions", local community facilities, public transport contributions and the employment of community liaison officers.

These costs are further amplified by joint actions between developers (often government-owned) and councils.  Thus, in NSW, the Government-owned Landcom uses its influence to obtain development rights, earning $150 million a year profit from sales of $320 million.  Moreover, such developers obtain the necessary rezoning of land by making commitments to local authorities for tennis courts, neighbourhood centres and other infrastructure over and above the already sizeable mandatory contributions.  Consumers have no opportunities to decide for themselves whether such expenditure meets their preferences -- the costs are rolled up in a price that they are obliged to pay.  Sydney has long been at the fore in applying such taxes, however Melbourne is also riding the bandwagon.  The Department of Sustainability and Environment has introduced a new tax on land released from its regulatory corset.  This tax is set at $2,700-$3,100 per block (11 blocks per hectare) for Urban Growth Boundary land already zoned for urban development, $4,000-$4,400 for such land that is not yet zoned, and $4,900-$5,400 for land brought within the UGB in November 2005.  These new taxes represent an attempt by the government to obtain a share of the scarcity value its planning regulations create.  They have little relationship to the costs of the infrastructure that people would otherwise willingly pay for.

Figure 7: Broadacre land and regulatory costs, 2006

Source:  Property Council of Australia


It is far from clear that the costs of the latter are less than those of the former, especially with regard to water and sewerage systems which are far more expensive to replace in crowded urban areas than in new suburbs.  Moreover, the transport systems (bearing in mind that at least 80 per cent of the costs of public transport are paid for by the community in general) can never be as intensive and useful in suburban developments as in densely populated central areas.

A survey of costs undertaken by UrbisJHD for the Property Council (112) placed a greater emphasis than this monograph on government cost impositions in bringing about price increases.  The survey identifies taxes as well as regulatory charges on development land and houses.  It estimates that government imposts range from 21 per cent to 35 per cent of the total of a broadacre new dwelling, and 21 per cent to 29 per cent for medium density developments well within existing boundaries.

The survey brings together invaluable information about the practical impacts of taxes and regulations.  Although it takes a wider view of tax imposts than some would regard as appropriate (it includes company tax as well as stamp duty, development requirements, building regulation costs and GST), it is a useful compilation of these taxes and impositions.

Figures 6, 7 and 8 illustrate the costs of government housing-specific taxes on the final cost.  Figure 6, for medium density housing, illustrates the regulatory, revenue and stamp duty impositions alongside the cost of land and the selling price of medium density properties.  Figure 7 examines the land and regulatory costs for broadacre lots.

Figure 8:  State Government revenue from taxes on conveyancing

Source:  State Budgets


It would be appropriate to add to the Property Council cost data, property-specific taxes levied by State Governments on financial instruments and on conveyancing.  These are both substantial (conveyancing taxes amount to some $10 billion or 8 per cent of total State revenues) and have demonstrated rapid growth over recent years.  Between 1999-2000 and 2004-05 growth has been over 73 per cent (over 55 per cent in real terms).  State governments also benefit from other taxes that are tied to the property boom (for example, taxes on insurance). (113)  The revenue collected from conveyancing taxes is illustrated in Figure 8.

Over the past year, revenues from these taxes have declined, especially in NSW, as a downturn in house prices has become evident.  However, the direct benefit that State governments receive as a result of house-price inflation increasing the value of their housing-specific taxes provides them with a disincentive to take measures to increase the availability of land.

It is not easy to disentangle what cost impositions for infrastructure and the like must be factored into the final price.  In some cases, for example, housing-specific taxes and most building regulations, the costs go directly to the final price of housing.  In others, such as GST and profits tax, they are part of the general tax regime.  Other taxes, such as developer contributions are more problematical;  rather than impositions made by governments to "claw back" the benefits that accrue to individuals from the land shortage price escalation their policies generate, in the main these constitute an additional impost on the new home buyer.

Table 6:  If housing in Australian capital cities were as
affordable as in the most affordable North American cities

Median
Household
Income ($)
Median
House Price
($)
Estimated
House Price
Multiple
Median
House Price
if Multiple
was 2.7 ($)
Ratio to
Actual
Median
House Price
Sydney61,000520,0008.5162,4133.2
Hobart40,100266,5006.6106,7662.5
Adelaide41,7OO272,0006.5111,0262.4
Melbourne56,000360,0006.4149,1002.4
Perth50,200308,0006.1133,6582.3
Brisbane52,000310,0006.0138,4502.2
Canberra72,600350,0004.8193,2981.8
Darwin69,400300,0004.3184,7781.6
Average of markets6.22.3

Source:  Demographia.com


These contributions doubtless create an additional cost, but we would be inclined to agree with the Productivity Commission that:

Notwithstanding the complexity of this area, some general messages emerge from the preceding discussion:

  • Infrastructure charges, like other costs of bringing housing to the market, have increased over time.  But they cannot explain the surge in house prices since the mid-1990s.  Indeed, the share of total house prices accounted for by infrastructure costs appears to have been declining in most Australian cities.
  • The claimed cost savings and improvements in affordability from reducing reliance on developer charges for infrastructure appear overstated:
    • Most categories of charges are justified and indeed are desirable on efficiency/equity grounds.  (Reduced reliance on developer contributions would bring a requirement for similar dedicated charges to be collected from home buyers.)
    • Housing affordability should not be significantly affected by greater reliance on upfront charging as opposed to charging over time.
    • Developer charges for those items of social or economic infrastructure that provide benefits in common across the wider community have generally been relatively small -- though such infrastructure should desirably be funded out of general revenue sources.

Nonetheless, though changes in the level and form of infrastructure charges are not responsible for recent sharp declines in housing affordability, compliance with some general charging principles will help to promote more efficient and equitable outcomes. (114)

Had land prices remained stable or increased only at the rate of underlying inflation, as occurs in almost all US jurisdictions where "smart growth planning restraints are not in place, average new house prices would have been 40 per cent to one-third lower than are presently observed.  The table below illustrates the price of houses in Australian capital cities if land prices had been allowed to remain competitive, as they have in Houston, Dallas-Fort Worth, St Louis, Atlanta, and other cities of comparable size to Sydney and Melbourne (as well as German cities such as Dortmund and Hamburg).

One effect of the Australian increase in land prices as a share of total costs has been a change in the type of housing.  This has meant smaller lot sizes.  It has also meant a skewing of housing supply towards apartments, an effect that might have been compounded by planning approval policies.

Overwhelmingly, people prefer to live in houses rather than apartments.  This has been demonstrated in a great many surveys.  One in the UK conducted by YouGov for the House Builders Federation indicated that only 8 per cent of people (17 per cent of those living in inner cities) preferred to live in an apartment rather than a house. (115)

Table 7:  New housing approvals, March 2006

NSWVicQldSAWATasNTACTTotal
Private sector houses (no.)1,2772.7082,3506771,85621778789,241
Total dwelling units (no.)2,3653,5813,6471,0782,16227716313713,410

Source:  ABS, Housing Approvals, March 2006.


It would be most unlikely that a smaller proportion of Australians would share this preference for detached housing.  In terms of housing stock, Australia is 78 per cent detached houses, 10 per cent semi-detached or terrace houses and 11 per cent apartments.  Reflecting cost considerations, for new dwellings, less than 70 per cent of approvals are now for houses, with only 55 per cent in NSW.


WHAT IF AUSTRALIA WERE MORE LIKE TEXAS?

Comparing Australia with Texas makes the effects of different regulatory regimes quite clear.  Australia and Texas are quite similar in lots of ways, as Table 8, a comparison of economic, geographic and demographic data shows.

Australia has a much larger land area, and thus a much lower population density.  Texas has a larger and faster-growing population, a larger economy and crams even more of its population into its five largest cities than does Australia.  Texas has more folk who speak a language other than English at home and more residents who were born outside its borders than does Australia.

Table 8:  Comparison of Australia and Texas

AustraliaTexas
Gross Product ($USm)
  Per capita ($US)
(a) 642,700
(a) 32,000
(b) 884,136
(b) 39,345
Population (census)
  (in 2004)
  % increase per year (d)
(c) 18,972,350
20,091,500
1.2
(d) 20,851,820
22,471,549
1.7
Area (sq km)
  (% water)
  Area covered by water (sq km)
  (% arable)
  Arable land (sq km)
7,686,850
1.0
76,869
6.55
503,489
696,241
2.5
17,784


Population density (per sq km)230.75
Foreign-born residents
  (% population)
(c) 4,105,444
21.6
(b) 3,393,204
15.1
Residents born outside State
  (% population)
n.a.
n.a.
6,336,977
28.2
Speak language other than English
  (% population)
(c) 2,853,851
15.0
(b) 7,190,896
32.0
Population of 5 largest cities
  (% population)
(c) 11,403,976
60.1
(b) 14,567,191
64.8

Source:  ABS, US Census Bureau, US Bureau of Economic Analysis, CIA Factbook

(a) 2005
(b) 2004
(c) 2001
(d) 2000


Nevertheless, they are broadly similar societies.

Since Texas has (much) less land, a greater population, is faster growing and is more productive (both overall and per person) and has an even larger share of its population in its five major metropolitan areas, it would seem likely that housing would be much more expensive in the metropolises of the Lone Star State than in the cities of our island continent.

Yet precisely the opposite is true (See Table 9.)

Table 9:  If Australia was more like Texas inland-use policy

Median
Household
Income ($)
Median
House
Price ($)
Multiple to
actual
house
prices
Estimated
House
Price
Multiple
Sydney
Austin
61,000
59,500
171,313
167,100
3.0

2.8
2.8
Melbourne
Dallas-Forth Worth
56,000
53,400
154,367
147,200
2.3

2.8
2.8
Brisbane
Houston
52,000
50,400
143,341
145,100
2.2

2.8
2.9
Perth
San Antonio
50,200
48,100
144,524
137,600
2.1

2.9
2.9
Adelaide
El Paso
41,700
34,300
116,164
95,550
2.3

2.8
2.8

Note:  All values in national currency


Policy clearly results in highly inflated house values in Australia.  Which is fine for people who already own a house, but unfortunate for those who merely hope to do so.

Consider also the income that Australians have to tie up in housing costs.  According to the US Census Bureau's 2004 Community Survey, median monthly housing costs for those paying a mortgage in Texas are $US1,166 a month (ranging from $US876 per month in El Paso to $US1,447 per month in Austin), for those renting the cost is $US648 a month (ranging from $US502 per month in El Paso to $US762 per month in Austin). (116)  While not strictly comparable, in 2002-03 Australians paid an average of $A1,066 in mortgage costs and $A819 in private rents per month.  Sydneysiders were paying an average of $A1,430 per month in mortgage costs and $A1,127 in private rents. (117)  Given that the term of mortgages can vary greatly, the much higher rental costs (in local dollar terms), particularly in Sydney, are a better indicator of the relative burden of housing costs imposed by the different policy regimes.

Texas is a much less linguistically homogenous jurisdiction than Australia, with a higher rate of population growth and migration-in of people born outside its borders.  But it is clearly much more able to provide housing policies which are in the general interests of its inhabitants, rather than the preferences of a narrow group of urban planners reflecting the interests of wealthier members of society.  In particular, it does not provide policies where, due to constricted supply, demand pressures from newcomers price people out of home ownership.  More liberal land use policies are themselves not an inconsiderable aid to social harmony in a diverse society.



8 POLICY CHANGES REQUIRED

There are some hopeful signs for reform in this area, not least of which were comments made by the Prime Minister on the issue in November 2005 at the opening of HIA's new NSW office, (118) at which he called for an expansion of land availability.

In the case of development approvals, winners are created as a result of the zoning system.  In order to plan their business futures, house builders and land developers take positions and buy land at the inflated prices that the regulations create.  They then have a vital interest in ensuring that the regulations do not leave them with an asset that is reduced in value at the stroke of the same administrative pen that brought the inflated value.  These forces are aided and abetted by very prosperous individuals living in areas that are relatively close to major urban areas but which have features of remoteness and exclusivity.

Land regulations, in particular zoning laws, also pose considerable dangers to the integrity of the political process.  When vast profits can be made by a politically directed and essentially arbitrary reclassification, there are grave dangers of political corruption. (119)  Those dangers extend beyond individuals' cupidity and can infect the political process by providing funds for political parties to use for electoral purposes.  In such cases, the community would be seeing its net real income levels reduced by a regulatory tax, with part of the proceeds diverted to the re-election of those purporting to represent their interests.

Unfortunately, the administration of planning regulations has become infested by elected busybodies and appointed experts who are determined to tell consumers what is good for them and to prevent them from doing anything else.  Although these regulatory trends have not yet escalated the costs of house building itself, they are poised to do so.  We have cost impositions requiring water storage, heating measures, and room layouts which are stopping entry into the industry.  The restraints on supply, together with the imposts placed on developers, have clearly been the major, if not the only, factors in pushing up the prices of housing.

Some of the differences in receptiveness of councils to new development proposals may be reflected in the time it takes to process them.  In addition to differences in approach, there are doubtless variations in efficiency between the various local authorities in their approval processes.  The UrbisJHD study undertaken for the Property Council found that the average time taken to approve broadacre land development proposals was around 15 weeks.  The time taken varied between 6 weeks (Tweed) and 30 weeks (Redland).

There are likely to be specific reasons why some approval processes are more prolonged than others, but measures taken to expedite processing by, for example, clearing over the Internet the separate steps required would mean economies and reductions in the stock of land that must be held.

All the costs involved, ranging from land use restrictions to inefficiencies in processing, are at the expense of the weakest and poorest members of society -- the mainly young first-home buyer.

The restoration of low costs for the home building industry requires measures such as:

  • relaxation of restraints on where homes may be built, even if this means the urban sprawl.  This might entail restricting area restraints only to areas of great natural beauty such as national parks.
  • considerably curtailing requirements on builders to set aside land for public use.
  • restraining the demands that can be placed on developers for expenditures on infrastructure by redefining infrastructure to mean such essential features as water, sanitation, and local roads and by recognising that much of the expenditure for these services is funded out of general State and local charges.

Cities such as Melbourne have declined in density.  People prefer to live in greater personal space, both internal and external, and detached somewhat from their neighbours.  Urban sprawl is not the "inevitable unhappy result of laissez-faire capitalism" but embodies individual preferences.  Technological developments and income growth allowed these consumer preferences to become manifest.  Once technology allowed rapid journeys -- first via rail and later by road -- the cities expanded.  Added to this, we have seen a great dispersal of work locations, partly due to the decline of large integrated factories, partly due to the changed nature of work:  especially the growth of service industries which tend to be geographically dispersed.

It is exceedingly difficult to construe the present operations of State planning rules as being compatible with ensuring the wisest and most economically advantageous use of land for activities normally associated with urban life.  Planning at its basic level is the response to the community's common infrastructure needs (roads, water provision etc.).  This involves weighing up different needs for housing, jobs, leisure facilities and commerce, and projecting them forward in time;  it means assessing consequential requirements for infrastructure, its costs and alternatives.

But this planning role can be abused -- instead of responding to consumers' market-based needs, planners have sought to impose their own preferences or have paid undue regard to those who have only an incidental interest in the development.  We should be most wary of giving rein to specialists in planning and other disciplines who make claims to be better placed than individual consumers in deciding the best use of resources.  In almost all other areas of economic activity such notions have been abandoned -- markets based on free exchange and property rights have brought better outcomes.

Proponents of the sort of detailed planning restrictions found in Victoria would doubtless maintain that they are merely engaging in setting broad parameters for activities and not micro-managing within those areas.  Some argue that this is not the case and that the extensive interaction between applicants and regulatory authorities demonstrates this.  Others, this author among them, would also argue that the planning requirements amount to a gross set of restrictions on land use, generate wasteful lobbying and restrict land availability for the purposes most valued by its owners and those seeking to make use of it.

Victoria's Department of Sustainability and the Environment (DSE) appears to be very supportive of the planning role it performs.  In its Development Contributions FACT SHEET, DSE says:

Decisions by State or local government to designate, rezone or subdivide land for urban development creates significant increases in land values.

This illustrates a serious misunderstanding of the economics of supply-shortage creation.  It is DSE's actions which give rise to the high values.  But unlike actions in the commercial world that create value by applying capital or skills or new technologies, the value of developable land arises largely because the government regulates its supply.  The Government, in reserving land from development, creates its scarcity.

The value of the scarcity which the government has created becomes apparent when some of the land is released, unfrozen, from the condition mandated by planning controls.  And such land can only be worth the sort of sums the Fact Sheet discusses ($300,000 to $400,000 per hectare) as long as an artificial scarcity remains in place.  Land used for alternative purposes to urban development (i.e. agriculture) on the periphery of Melbourne is worth only a few thousand dollars per hectare.  The fact that it sells for a premium, even before its release, reflects speculators' views that the authorities will eventually designate the land as usable for purposes the community actually values most.

Land prices on the urban boundary that are considerably in excess of agricultural land prices reflect the inflated scarcity value caused by regulatory restrictions on supply.  Any cost-based causes of high prices are dwarfed by those attributable to regulation-induced scarcity.  Were it not for this, it is barely conceivable that a block of land on the periphery of Melbourne would command a price in excess of some $60,000 per hectare and that much of this would be caused by development costs.

Land is a basic resource.  It should not be an arbitrarily or unnecessarily expensive one.



APPENDIX 1

MELBOURNE'S PLANNING HISTORY (120)

1922
Metropolitan Town Planning Commission is established.

1929
Report of the Metropolitan Town Planning Commission proposes a planning scheme to prevent "misuse" of land and protect property values, highlighting traffic congestion, the distribution of recreational open space and haphazard intermingling of land uses.

1954
First comprehensive planning scheme for the metropolitan area, prepared by the Melbourne and Metropolitan Board of Works (MMBW), introduces the concept of district business centres and focuses major retail activity on designated centres on the public transport system that also provide central locations for housing, transport, employment and community activity.

1971
The MMBW report, Planning Policies for the Melbourne Metropolitan Region, introduces long-term conservation and development policies through growth corridor and green wedge principles, and contains outward growth to a limited number of areas on the edge of the city.

1980
The MMBW's Metropolitan Strategy reinforces the 1954 policy on district centres, encourages development in existing areas, and concentrates housing, transport, employment and community facilities at highly accessible points.

1983
New district centre zones encourage office development in 14 centres and restrict it elsewhere.

1987
Shaping Melbourne's Future reinforces the thrust of the 1980 Strategy.

1995
Living Suburbs relaxes metropolitan-wide planning direction and controls, for example, on green wedge boundaries and the hierarchy of activity centres, and devolves much decision-making to the local level or on a case-by-case basis.

2002
Melbourne 2030 seeks to increasingly concentrate major change in strategic redevelopment sites such as activity centres and underdeveloped land and to shift away from growth on the fringe of the city.  Prevent urban expansion into surrounding rural land, to support demand for well-located apartment lifestyles around activity centres and an expanded and more attractive public transport system.



APPENDIX 2

VICTORIAN MUNICIPAL GRANTS

Estimated
Resident
Population
June 2004
General Purpose Grants
2005/2006
Local
Road
Lengths
June 2004
(kms)
Local Roads Grants
2005/2006
Amount
($)
Per Capita
($/Head)
Amount
($)
Per
Kilometre
($/km)
Alpine S13,1681,816,910138.0781807,9631,034.5
Ararat RC11,5392,163,116187.52,3861,598,232669.8
Ballarat C87,1486,498,94774.61,2591,386,7811,101.5
Banyule C117,3233,668,93931.3557708,2711,271.6
Bass Coast S28,5122,772,01597.21,044981,400940.0
Baw Baw S37,9353,868,259102.01,7581,953,4121,111.2
Bayside C89,2321,491,05016.7353364,5311,032.7
Benalla RC14,0671,685,020119.81,4001,042,610744.7
Boroondara C158,2902,644,99616.7572608,2901,063.4
Brimbank C174,4268,562,76149.18071,073,663l,330.4
Buloke S7,0582,032,069287.95,168l,511,348292.4
Campaspe S37,1934,673,308125.74,0932,912,250711.5
Cardinia S54,5434,287,23078.61,4211,591,3801,119.9
Casey C210,38910,513,22150.01,2051,408,8431,169.2
Central Goldfields S12,9641,786,765137.81,321890,835674.4
Colac-Otway S21,4952,445,685113.81,6681,771,2901,061.9
Corangamite S17,3272,485,810143.52,6622,278,538855.9
Darebin C127,5214,735,55837.1499647,6751,297.9
Docklands Authority3,OOO50,13016.7611,1131,852.2
East Gippsland S40,8266,799,942166.63,2993,733,1921,131.6
Frankston C118,9516,154,65451.7651808,3871,241.8
Gannawarra S11,8371,990,158168.12,4581,314,370534.7
Glen Eira C122,9012,053,65316.7426416,214977.0
Glenelg S20,2202,730,979135.12,6652,324,628872.5
Golden Plains S16,3192,101,377128.81,8191,420,056780.7
Greater Bendigo C94,6148,277,62187.52,9022,109,304726.8
Greater Dandenong C127,2306,359,49750.0594950,3111,599.9
Greater Geelong C202,61512,772,41563.01,9912,218,7481,114.4
Greater Shepparton C60,0255,356,81489.22,4442,074,324848.7
Hepburn S14,8281,913,388129.01,296968,461747.3
Hindmarsh S6,4071,702,480265.73,2541,156,743355.5
Hobsons Bay C83,1992,694,09732.4425493,6401,161.5
Horsham RC18,9012,303,362121.92,8941,427,571493.3
Hume C148,1956,182,30941.79161,219,2881,331.1
Indigo S15,0911,852,433122.81,8391,150,612625.7
Kingston C136,6842,451,64817.9609806,6081,324.5
Knox C150,0445,694,09037.9723922,6811,276.2
Latrobe C70,3156,291,65189.51,4291,683,2971,178.0
Loddon S8,4072,685,126319.44,7322,376,545502.2
Macedon Ranges S40,0043,223,05180.61,4671,403,468956.7
Manningham C113,9201,903,58216.7588581,541989.0
Mansfield S6,9971,271,537181.7807713,575884.2
Maribyrnong C62,0542,292,94237.0271334,8401,235.5
Maroondah C100,9433,659,55336.3483560,9761,161.4
Melbourne C58,670980,36516.7188461,3452,454.0
Melton S71,3505,149,86072.2711805,6741,133.2
Mildura RC51,2635,721,255111.65,0612,555,511504.9
Mitchell S31,5743,162,926100.21,3281,187,224894.0
Moira S27,4643,720,697135.53,5112,349,147669.1
Monash C161,5443,447,25021.3717786,7181,097.2
Moonee Valley C109,1652,444,92222.4422583,1591,381.9
Moorabool S26,1382,611,16499.91,4321,308,385913.7
Moreland C135,8435,229,15838.5516632,7991,226.4
Mornington Peninsula S138,7734,296,69531.01,6641,709,6881,027.5
Mount Alexander S17,2421,866,579108.31,2901,040,132806.3
Moyne S15,8512,387,333150.63,4712,727,840785.9
Murrindindi S13,9081,822,431131.01,1991,225,4611,022.1
Nillumbik S60,6232,015,84633.3790855,8971,083.4
Northern Grampians S12,7492,495,276195.73,4121,816,162532.3
Port Phillip C82,8571,384,52516.7211284,4271,348.0
Pyremees S6,5321,811,154277.32,0321,504,102740.2
Queenscliffe B3,212145,93545.44440,547921.5
South Gippsland S26,8883,375,801125.62,0792,364,0361,137.1
Southern Grampians S16,9022,749,953162.73,1662,205,337696.6
Stonnington C90,9031,518,97216.7257291,7541,135.2
Strathbogie S9,6161,817,412189.02,1761,458,089670.1
Surf Coast S22,4711,457,24464.81,011921,153911.1
Swan Hill RC21,4612,760,836128.63,1431,234,574392.8
Towong S6,2041,536,878247.71,2581,022,004812.4
Wangaratta RC26,6412,842,416106.72,0361,552,692762.6
Warnambool C30,7082,184,98471.2287452,3901,576.3
Wellington S41,4505,115,884123.43,3363,383,7601,014.3
West Wimmera S4,7411,829,335385.92,7301,687,443618.1
Whitehorse C144,9353,935,16927.2600606,6701,011.1
Whittlesea C126,2976,122,08248.5756953,4481,261.2
Wodonga RC34,8312,804,57080.5429603,2841,406.3
Wyndham C107,8686,368,87959.0799902,4041,129.4
Yarra C69,7491,165,49316.7215297,5641,384.0
Yarra Ranges S143,2287,845,08954.81,7702,488,1621,405.7
Yarriambiack S8,0141,930,680240.94,7971,432,287298.6
Total4,972,322276,955,19455.7128,786102,449,074795.5

Source:  Victorian Grants Commission Annual Report



APPENDIX 3

LOCAL GOVERNMENT REVENUE

Table A:  Local government revenue sources, 1997-98

Note:  Figures for the Northern Territory include municipalities, community councils and association councils.

Source:  ABS


Table B:  Local governments' cash flow statements, country-wide

NSWVicQldSAWATasNSTACTAust
Taxes received2,3872,0991,51667680019054..7,721
Receipts from sales of goods and services2,0479312,178247526226115..6,269
Grants and subsidies received7795586902132689977..2,685
Other receipts1,281256668212045749..2,536
Total6,4943,8445,0521,1561.798572295..19,211

Source:  ABS



REFERENCES

1National Times, 28 February 1973.  While Clem Jones was Lord Mayor of Brisbane, both Australia and Queensland saw their populations grow by one-third.

2.  A recent opinion poll conducted by Eureka Research for the Residential Development Council (an arm of the Property Council of Australia) found that 66.5 per cent of respondents supported, and only 17.3 per cent opposed, stripping local councils of the power to pass development approvals.  Anthony Klan, "Majority want DAs taken from councils:  survey", The Australian, 26 March 2006.

3.  Chang'an, the capital of T'ang China, had a population of about 600,000 at its zenith in the seventh and eight centuries.  Baghdad, the capital of the Abbasid Caliphate, had a population of 300-500,000 at its zenith in the ninth century.  In the early sixteenth century, the Aztec capital Tenochitlan, with a population of 60-130,000, was one of the largest cities in the world.

4.  Manhattan has some 27,000 inhabitants per square kilometre and the next densest US city area, Chicago, has 19,000.

5.  John Reader, Cities, 2005, page 123.

6.  Robert Bruegmann, Sprawl:  a Compact History, University of Chicago Press, 2005.

7.  http://www.spectator.co.uk/article_archive.php?id=7081&issue=200512-17.  In contrast to this, the UK Shadow Minister for Housing, Michael Gore, was a founder of Policy Exchange, an organisation that has campaigned strongly against planning restrictions.

8.  Max Nathan and Chris Urwin, "City people:  city centre living in the UK", http://www.ippr.org/ecomm/files/city_people_execsum.pdf.

9.  According to Mori and other research agencies, this accounts for some 95 per cent of respondents.

10.  Queensland, Smart Travel Choices for South East Queensland:  A Transport Green Paper, Brisbane:  Queensland Transport, December 2005.

11.  John Cox, "Labor stops 'common people' people from moving around", The Australian Financial Review, 20 June 2003.

12.  See J. Gans, "Road-use charge would force more to public transport", The Age, 8 March 2006.

13.  Australian cities are little different from most US cities in this respect.  Jose Gomes-Ibanez points out that US public transport fares cover only half the operating costs and make no contribution to capital costs.  See Jose Gomez-Ibanez, "Pricing" in Jose Gomez-Ibanez, William Tye and Clifford Winston, Essays in Transportation Economics and Policy:  A Handbook in Honour of John Meyer, Washington, DC, Brookings Institution, 1999, chapter 4, page 111.

14.  Margo Huxley, " 'This Suburb is of Value to the whole of Melbourne':  Save our Suburbs and the Struggle Against Inappropriate Development", Institute for Social Research Working Paper No. 6, July 2002 at http://www.apo.org.au/linkboard/results.chtml?filename_ num=15650.  The paper nowhere mentions, or shows any awareness of, the land rationing which lies behind the policy conflicts it examines.

15.  Clara H. Greed, Introducing Town Planning, Longmans, 1993, page 118.

16Ibid., page 64.

17Ibid., page 83.

18Ibid., page 84.

19Ibid., page 98.

20Ibid., pages 104-106.

21Ibid., page 100.

22Ibid., page 119.  Public housing is a local government responsibility in the UK.  Tenants found it difficult to move without losing their place in the waiting lists, which tended to "trap" people, regardless of local job prospects.  As public housing is a State government responsibility in Australia, people have been able to transfer around a much more economically varied territory.  Public housing estates became a more dominant feature of the housing market in the UK than in Australia (South Australia excepted).  While displaying similar characteristics, public housing in Australia (apart from indigenous housing) has generally not reached the UK levels of social dysfunction and nowhere near the level of social dysfunction, so dramatically displayed in 2005, of the public housing estates in France.

23Ibid., page 107.

24Ibid., page 107.

25Ibid., page 108.

26Ibid., page 110.

27Ibid., pages 112-113.

28Ibid., pages 111-112.

29.  Far from an exclusively British phenomenon.  An early report of the Brotherhood of St Laurence in Melbourne found that the Fitzroy clearances and Housing Commission high rise in Brunswick St had also resulted in a net loss of housing.

30.  Creed, op. cit., page 115.

31Ibid., page 109.

32Ibid., page 127.

33Ibid., pages 127-132.

34Ibid., pages 134 ff.

35Ibid., page 135.

36Ibid., page 136.

37.  Dean Baker, The Housing Bubble Fact Sheet, CEPR Issue Brief July 2005 at http://www.cepr.net/publications/housing_fact_2005_07.pdf;  and Dean Baker & David Rosnick, Will A Bursting Bubble Trouble Burnake?:  Evidence for a Housing Bubble, CEPR November 2005 at http://www.cepr.net/publications/housing_bubble_2005_11.pdf.

38.  Peter Harrison, "City Planning" in Peter Scott (ed.), Australian Cities and Public Policy, Georgian House, Melbourne, 1978, pages 141-173, page 142.

39Ibid., pages 142, 155.  Newcastle also saw an amalgamation of local councils into a large metropolitan council.

40Ibid., pages 142 ff.

41Ibid., pages 144 ff.

42.  http://www.lawlink.nsw.gov.au/lawlink/lec/ll_lec.nsf/pages/LEC_jurisdictionfull.

43.  Phil McManus, Vortex Cities to Sustainable Cities:  Australia's Urban Challenge, University of New South Wales Press, 2005, pages 43-44.

44Ibid., pages 46-47.

45Ibid., pages 55-56.

46.  Harrison, op. cit., pages 149 ff.

47.  See http://www.nre.vic.gov.au/CA256F310024B628/0/17675359D58FA4C1CA25713A0012D902/$File/Probity+and+Procuring+Valuations.pdf.  Also http://www.aharkness.org/_dbase_upl/Chapter%203%20-%20final.pdf and http://www.aic.gov.au/publications/tandi/ti143.pdf.

48.  McManus, op. cit., page 44.

49Ibid., pages 47, 57.

50Ibid., page 57.

51.  http://www.dse.vic.gov.au/melbourne2030online/content/policies_initiatives/02d_policy24.html

52.  Harrison, op. cit., pages 153 ff.

53.  McManus, op. cit., pages 44, 48.

54Ibid., pages 59-60.

55.  Harrison, op. cit., pages 155 ff.

56.  McManus, op. cit., pages 44, 47-48.

57Ibid., pages 58-59.

58.  Harrison, op. cit., pages 158 ff.

59.  McManus, op. cit., pages 45, 48-49, 60-61.

60.  Harrison, op. cit., pages 161-2.

61.  Max Neutze, "Urban Land" in Peter Scott (ed.), Australian Cities and Public Policy, Georgian House, Melbourne, 1978, pages 72-87, page 72.

62Ibid., pages 73-74.

63Ibid., page 76.

64Ibid., page 73.

65Ibid., page 74.

66Ibid., pages 74-75.

67Ibid., pages 74-75.

68Ibid., page 77.

69.  M. Baker, Shopping center industry benchmarks, ICSC, 2004.

70.  Perhaps stemming from concerns about citizens' excessive consumption of alcohol, many governments also act similarly in licensing liquor outlets.  Applicants need to demonstrate a need for a new outlet and existing facilities will invariably raise objections claiming that consumers' needs are already adequately catered for.

71.  Greed, op. cit., page 5.

72.  Interview on Counterpoint on Radio National, Monday 30 January 2006 at http://www.abc.net.au/rn/talks/counterpoint/stories/s1557886.htm.

73.  Hugh Stretton, "Housing Policy" in Peter Scott (ed,), Australian Cities and Public Policy, Georgian House, Melbourne, 1978, pages 105, 114.

74Ibid., page 109.

75Ibid., pages 105-122, page 114.

76Ibid., page 115.  This was probably due to a drop in provision for the lower end of the new home market.

77Ibid., page 110.

78Ibid., pages 117-118.

79.  William A Fischel, "An economic history of zoning and a cure for its exclusory effects", draft of 18 December 2001 at http://www.dartmouth.edu/~wfischel/Papers/02-03.pdf.

80.  Homepage at http://www.saveoursuburbs.org.au/index.htm.

81.  Policies are at http://www.saveoursuburbs.org.au/files/SOS_Policies_199807.pdf.

82.  SOS, "Response to Melbourne 2030", 14 February 2003, (page 4) at http://www.saveoursuburbs.org.au/files/SOS-M2030-RespFinal14.2.03.pdf.

83.  At http://home.vicnet.net.au/~tcpa/.

84.  SOS, "Response to DAF (Development Assessment Forum)", 30 June 2004, (page 4) at http://www.saveoursuburbs.org.au/files/SOSDAFsubmFinal30.6.04.pdf.

85.  SOS, "Response to 'Better Decisions Faster' ", August 2003, (page 1) at http://www.saveoursuburbs.org.au/files/BDF-SOS_final_subm.pdf.

86.  SOS, "Response to DAF (Development Assessment Forum)", 30 June 2004, (page 2).

87.  http://www.nytimes.com/2006/03/05/magazine/glaeser.1.html?pagewanted=1&ei=5090&en=58a9dac06ddaf7af&ex=1299214800&partner=rssuserland&emc=rss.

88.  SOS, "Response to Melbourne 2030", 14 February 2003, (page 6);  SOS, "Response to DAF (Development Assessment Forum)", 30 June 2004, (page 4);  SOS, "Response to "Better Decisions Faster", August 2003, (pages 2 ff).

89.  J. Fedako, Zoning is Theft, http://www.mises.org/story/2077.

90.  See William A Fischel, "An Economic History of Zoning and a Cure for Its Exclusionary Effects", draft of 18 December 2001 available at http://www.dartmouth.edu/~wfischel/Papers/02-03.pdf.

91.  Of course, if the population wasn't expanding, land rationing would be largely redundant.

92.  Since rent is a service from a durable asset -- and since people can move between the rental and home-purchasing markets -- in the short term, rents and house prices can move in opposite directions.

93.  The way in which governments, in order to maximise benefits delivered to specific constituencies, seek to entrench their decisions against reversal by their successors (creating high levels of policy inertia) is powerfully analysed by Murray J. Horn, then Secretary of the New Zealand Treasury, in The Political Economy of Pubic Administration:  Institutional Choice in the Public Sector, Cambridge University Press, 1995.

94.  At http://www.demographia.com/dhi-rank200502.htm.

95.  Quoted in Huxley, op. cit., page 18.

96.  John Reader, Cities 2005, pages 278-280.

97.  Bruegmann op. cit., page 178.

98.  In Australia, there is considerable scope to vary disbursements between different local authorities.  Thus, in Victoria, each municipality is only guaranteed one-third of the per capita level it would be entitled to on an unvarying level of allocation and for 2004-5, according to the State's Grants commission, "Bayside, Boroondara, Glen Eira, Melbourne, Manningham, Port Phillip, Stonnington and Yarra, together with the Docklands Authority -- would have been below the $16.71 per capita level.  The minimum grant principle has resulted in the general purpose grants to these councils being increased to that level." General purpose grants for 2005-6 range from $16.71 per head to $319.  See Appendix 2 and http://www.doi.vic.gov.au/doi/doielect.nsf/2a6bd98dee287482ca256915001cff0c/ 111fccc896503e8fca2570c3001a712b/$FILE/2004-05%20VGC%20A nnual%20Report.pdf.  The Commonwealth Grants Commission requires that every local authority receives at least 30 per cent of what it would receive if the grants were distributed solely according to population.  In NSW, the per capita minimum in 2005-6 is $16.68 and 20 councils received only this.

99.  See, for instance, http://www.calicocat.com/2004/08/blue-stateredstateand-high-cost-of.html

100.  http://www.isteve.com/2005_Dirt_Gap.htm.  Sailer also argues that development and other controls are used by residents to discourage foreign-born newcomers.  The evidence is rather that the "incumbents club" is advantaged if a significant proportion of potential housing-market entrants -- such as those from non-English speaking backgrounds -- are less well-integrated into local political systems, particularly if the local political culture is relatively sympathetic to the restriction of property rights.  An effect that does not apply in Texas (see below), presumably because Spanish-speakers are such a large proportion of the voter base (48 per cent of residents of the major Texan metropolises speak a language other than English at home compared with the US metropolitan average of 19 per cent) and the local political culture does not encourage restriction of property rights.

101.  Jennifer Roback Morse, Marriage in the City, at http://www.townhall.com/opinion/columns/JennniferRobackMorse/2006/03/20/190454.html.

102.  http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/glaeser/papers/Manhattan.pdf.

103.  Edward L. Glaesar & Joseph Gyuorko, Urban Decline and Durable Housing.  Available at http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/glaeser/papers/Durable_Housing.pdf.

104.  Jennifer Coleman, "Get a Job and a House", Sacramento Union, 13 January 2006.

105.  http://www.demographia.com/

106.  http://www.census.gov/

107.  http://www.census.gov/acs/www/

108First Home Owners Inquiry Report, March 2004, page 130 at http://www.pc.gov.au/inquiry/housing/finalreport/housing.pdf.

109.  See http://www.demographia.com/dhi-rank200502.htm.

110.  http://www.pc.gov.au/inquiry/housing/finalreport/index.html

111.  http://www.ipa.org.au/files/57-3-pricesandplanning.pdf.

112Residential Development Cost Benchmarking Study prepared for the Residential Development Council of the Property Council of Australia, March 2006.

113.  Some of these taxes, the tax on mortgages for example, are in the process of being removed as part of the Commonwealth/State agreements on the GST.

114.  http://www.pc.gov.au/inquiry/housing/finalreport/index.html, page 176.

115.  http://www.hbf.co.uk/fileadmin/documents/downloads/YouGov_Final_Results_18_May_2004_01.xls Survey size:  2070.

116.  At http://factfinder.census.gov/servlet/GRTSelectServlet?ds_name=ACS_2004_EST_G00_&_lang=en&_ts=156712951562.

117.  ABS, 4130.0.55.001 -- Housing Occupancy and Costs, Australia, 2002-03, at http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@.nsf/Latestproducts/4130.0.55.001Media%20Release12002-03?opendocument&tabname=Summary&prodno=4130.0.55.001&issue=2002-03&num=&view=.

118.  http://www.pm.gov.au/news/speeches/speech1681.html

119.  These same dangers are receiving attention in the UK with the publication of material about a shopping centre developer being awarded approval to build a 500 million pound centre in south London after secretly providing the Labour Party some 3 million pounds.  See http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/main.jhtml?xml=/news/2006/03/26/nloans26.xml&sSheet=/portal/2006/03/26/ixportaltop.html.

120.  Taken from http://www.dse.vic.gov.au/melbourne2030online/content/introduction/03_basis.html#history.