Monday, June 02, 1997

Submission to the New South Wales Committee of Inquiry Into Sale Of Electricity Assets

Submission

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Privatisation of the New South Wales electricity assets would bring immense benefits to the people of the State as taxpayers, consumers and workers.

Electricity supply industries are undergoing change throughout the world in recognition that the industry no longer needs to be operated as a single integrated entity.  Commercial rivalry among suppliers at both the generation and retail levels brings greater attention to cost cutting and meeting consumer needs.  The National Electricity Market means that no business can avoid continuously seeking improvements in its levels of service, and in pursuing cost reductions.

Privatisation of the State's electricity assets would inject at least $22 billion into development.  Such a sum presents an outstanding opportunity to repay debt, reduce taxes on business and employment that impede job creation, and increase infrastructure expenditure in areas not readily suitable for private capital provision.

The privatisation process in NSW can also benefit from the Victorian sale experience, which has demonstrated the value of electricity industry assets.  NSW has scope to float rather than trade-sale parts of its industry, thereby fostering significant Australian equity holdings.

In addition, privatisation offers scope to build upon the structural reform presently in place.  In this respect, it allows the Government further to split up the generator businesses and energyAustralia so that greater competition is fostered and the assets attract a wider degree of investor interest.

In terms of present employment, increased competition is likely to force some initial reductions in electricity industry jobs irrespective of any privatisation plans.  These will mainly be in distribution.  Generation in NSW is already relatively efficient and job losses will be minor.  Moreover, domestic and overseas business development opportunities available to private sector firms may well offset these losses.  More importantly, any job losses through rationalisations in the wake of privatisation will be dwarfed by the tens of thousands of new jobs that will follow from the effective increase in investment funds from by the privatisation proceeds.

Private ownership would also avoid conflict of interest situations.  These occur because the Government as the owner of particular businesses has a vested interest in outcomes that favour those businesses and, through its taxation powers, has the ability to negate any adverse outcomes on those businesses.

Privatisation will not have any adverse effects on customer service obligations or the environment.  These facets of the electricity industry are subject to regulation or direct Government expenditure.  In fact, private ownership, by removing a direct financial interest of the Government on these matters, is likely to lead to improved outcomes.  These will be reinforced by the commercial interest that private businesses have to foster their corporate images in the communities they serve.


INTRODUCTION:  THE SOCIAL
USEFULNESS OF ELECTRICITY ASSETS

Electricity in NSW accounts for over 2 per cent of state GSP.  Electrification has long been recognised as fundamental to the modern economy -- and in the Soviet Union in the 1920's electrification was equated to socialism, the ultimate accolade at that time.

Electricity is the essential commodity that is the building block of society's income generating capacity and the means to give its citizens the fundamental levels of comfort and consumer expectations required by the modern economy.  But the social usefulness of the assets is severely reduced if they are not operated at maximum efficiency.  Social usefulness is ill served by assets that incur excessive costs that must be borne by the taxpayer either in subsidies or in inadequate returns.


THE IMPACT OF PUBLIC OWNERSHIP ON
CONSUMERS AND THE ENVIRONMENT

CONSUMER ORIENTATION

As with many other essential aspects of a modern society, food, housing, transport, communications, etc. there is no reason why production and distribution of electricity should be under government ownership.  Indeed, all the evidence is that the provision of goods and services is more efficiently undertaken by privately owned businesses.

There are many reasons why this should be so.  Not the least of which is the intrinsically greater flexibility of private sector bodies, motivated by the goal of maximising shareholder wealth, to adapt their products to shifting consumer needs and to pare unnecessary costs.  In competitive markets, commercial rivalry will force lower costs to be passed on in lower prices.  To forego opportunities to reduce costs puts at risk the viability of private businesses.  By contrast, Government owned businesses are able to survive without such a heavy focus on these costs because they do not face the threat of takeover by others able to spot and implement the opportunities for profit by making savings.

In addition, private ownership markedly reduces the risk of government interference in the terms and conditions under which goods and services are provided.  This better allows the operation of the competitive market conditions that all states and territories have agreed to under CoAG.

Hence, while in principle there is no reason why private rather than public ownership should offer better outcomes to the consumer, the former is spurred more forcefully by profit considerations that require a very close customer focus.  Private businesses flourish when they can establish and hold customer loyalty and avoid poor reputations.  Indeed, the reform process in the Australian electricity industry was stimulated by observations of increased efficiency and lower costs observed in the mainly privately owned US industry and by the gains that were rapidly being seen in the newly privatised UK industry.

In Victoria, prior to privatisation, resolute government action from 1990 resulted in considerable savings in costs and improvements in efficiency.  Yet, in the period post privatisation of most of the businesses, further substantial improvements were brought about as a result of the focus on increasing shareholder value.  As illustrated in Table 1, this cost reduction process had not been at the expense of customer service.

Table 1:  Victorian Electricity Industry Performance Indicators

1990/11993/41996
Average System Outage (minutes)490251.7175
Availability of Generators79.882.792
Generator Labour Productivity (GWh/employee)6.716.2
Monthly Disconnections (residential)28001380

With respect to system outages, the measurements prior to 1994 excluded the 12 per cent of electricity that was distributed through the municipal authorities, which were generally far inferior to the SECV.  Hence the figures are far better than they appear to be.

In terms of other measures, privatisation has brought vast reductions in customer prices for contestable customers and reduced numbers of disconnections.  The private businesses have taken energetic steps in this latter direction partly to avoid the costs of re-connecting households and partly to raise their image in the communities they serve.


ENVIRONMENTAL ISSUES

In terms of environmental outcomes, public ownership brings neither a positive nor a negative outcome.  Such outcomes in terms of discharges from generators, visual impacts of wires, etc. can be and are legislated for irrespective of ownership.

Private businesses in fact often pay greater attention to environmental considerations because they do not have a government shareholder that seeks to shield them from cost disabilities and liabilities.  Moreover, environmental care is part of private business's overall marketing strategies and many private businesses are keen to tap the increasing market that this can bring.

Among both the privatised Victorian businesses and the publicly owned NSW businesses, there are firms that are seeking to position themselves to win customers by selling "green" power generated from new renewable sources.


EMPLOYMENT, SKILLS, TRAINING AND THE PROTECTION OF THE EXISTING WORKFORCE

In the past, many State Governments to a greater or lesser extent used their own corporations as means of providing jobs over and above the levels required for commercial operations.  They were able to do so because State electricity businesses were insulated from inter-state or intra-state competition

State Governments in effect subsidised the operations of their utilities by accepting a lower rate of return on the assets the taxpayer had sunk into them.  In Victoria, the net profit of the SECV was around $150 million per year in each of the four years 1989-92.  As the assets have been shown to be worth at least $20 billion this represented a return of less than one per cent.  The former Pacific Power, which would have had a market value of at least $12 billion did little better.  The business earned a net profit averaging $420 million per annum in the four years to 1995.  This represents a return of, at best, a little over 3 per cent on the assets.

This poor performance on the part of the State owned businesses is compounded by the fact that both Pacific Power and the SECV charged prices that were far higher than justified in a commercial market.  The following Figure, drawn from the NSW Energy Reform Statement of 1995, illustrates the 20 per cent real price reduction required.

Figure 1


The bulk of the price reductions are to come from generation costs, which as the following figure illustrates accounts for nearly 60 per cent of NSW overall electricity costs.

Figure 2


Given that vesting contract prices in NSW were set at $44.5 per MWh and that pool prices are presently some $20 per MWh (with some contract prices known to be around $14 per MWh), such a target would appear to be readily achievable.  However, the present low prices are a reflection of the customer segmentation that is still possible in the present transition to a national market as most customer load is not able to take advantage of the unregulated prices.

The present dual price structure reflects other inefficiencies that resulted from the previous monopolistic arrangements.  Many electricity businesses were operating in monopoly situations and were able to load their excessive costs on to customers particularly those customers who had little political power and little option but to remain captive of the supplier rather than relocate;  this usually meant smaller businesses and, though electricity was a relatively low proportion of the business' aggregate costs, the policy had an insidious, cumulative effect on competitiveness.

With open markets such approaches are not possible since buyers at low prices would find ways to on-sell to the penalised buyers.  In anticipation of this, regulated price reductions have been put in place in both NSW and Victoria that mean considerable customer benefits and a re-weighting of tariffs to remove the discrimination against smaller business customers.

There are now irresistible pressures on the remaining impediments to efficiency.  These are centred upon the competition reforms agreed to by all Australian government jurisdictions in April 1995 and applied to electricity in June 1996.  These reforms require freedom of trade between the states, commercialisation of state enterprises, elimination of access to natural monopolies and non-discrimination.  These measures and the progress to date of the national market for electricity are outlined in the Attachment.

It is certainly not desirable to return to the featherbedding and other inefficiencies that characterised Australian electricity industry for many decades.  The present arrangements mean it is also not possible.

The contemporary world is characterised by continuous structural change.  Where businesses -- private or publicly owned -- receive government favours that insulate them from this change, their inefficiencies are manifest in higher prices for consumers and reduced competitiveness for businesses.  The upshot of both these factors is fewer jobs throughout the economy.

Ironically, the way to sustainable job creation and skill levels that match needs is efficient production levels, which may in the first instance impact adversely on jobs.  The alternative is to face mounting losses in profits, with adverse impacts on the revenues available to the Government, and/or a loss of market share to new businesses or interstate competitors that have lowered their costs and designed their products to meet market needs.


Specific Measures likely to be Necessary

The spot prices in the NSW part of the national market are averaging only a little over $20.  These barely cover O&M costs and are only two thirds of the full costs of production.  NSW generators are cushioned from the full effects of the low spot prices, and the even lower contract prices, by the vesting prices that apply to 60 per cent of the customer load.

Nonetheless, the present trends demonstrate excess capacity in the NSW system.  In Victoria market forces have forced one generator into a care and maintenance basis.  Something similar is likely to be required in NSW with Munmorah (which has 290 employees) and part of Liddell (which has 320 employees) being the highest cost plants.

In this respect, NSW generation has avoided the excessive hiring practices of Victoria's SECV.  In Victoria, the 10,000 former employees in generation have been reduced to 3,400 (which includes contractors) under reformed Government ownership and latterly under private ownership.  NSW generators carry far more efficient staffing levels and job reductions either under privatisation or continued government ownership will be far more modest.

Similar pressure to reduce over-manning is likely, on a more disbursed basis, with the distribution businesses, and has already been recognised by the former management of energyAustralia.

The point about any possible job losses as a result of reform or privatisation in NSW is that they will be dwarfed by the opportunities for increased jobs.  Compared to the existing 11,500 MW of NSW capacity, private power plants under construction in China, India, S. Korea, Pakistan, Indonesia, Vietnam, Malaysia and the Philippines total some 78,000 MW. (1)  Only an efficient NSW industry would be able to offer credible bids for a significant share of this burgeoning business, and provide opportunities for far more jobs than would be lost as a result of the needed rationalisation.


IMPACT ON SPECIFIC GROUPS

Government owned electricity supply systems put in place various concessions to reduce costs to different types of consumer.  These are normally defined as Community Service Obligations (CSOs) and reflect a transfer of costs from other users (or the taxpayer).  At the core of CSOs are concessional tariffs to particular users, like pensioners, or equalising costs to those living in areas where power is more expensive to deliver.

Other obligations cover such matters as tree clearing, undergrounding of wires, concessional wires charges to small users, and extended payment terms for those in arrears.  Still other obligations form a part of the licence conditions.  These include requirements to supply within a particular territory, to form customer consultative committees and to maintain power supply failures within specified limits.

Most of the obligations that result in uncommercial costs on the industry have long been recognised and the Government makes explicit payment for them to the various corporations.  Some, for example disconnection policy, are undergoing experimentation in particular businesses.  Thus, in order to promote a strong public image, some of the privatised Victorian retailers have adopted a policy of avoiding disconnecting customers unable to pay their bills by offering telephone warnings in advance of any such action.

The point about all these obligations is that they can be maintained equally under a privatised regime as under one in government ownership.


WHETHER THE ORIGINAL PURPOSE OF THE ENTERPRISES'
OWNERSHIP ARRANGEMENTS REMAIN RELEVANT

There was a number of different reasons behind government exclusive or predominant ownership of electricity assets that was the norm in Australia and a great many other countries until recent years.

These included the view that electricity

  • was a public service and a natural monopoly and that rivalry would add unnecessary disruption;
  • its instantaneous supply and demand characteristics and its non-storability meant it had to be handled in an integrated manner under a single ownership structure;
  • it could be used as a tool to further a selective industry policy under which favoured activities could be given assistance (at the expense of other activities or the taxpayer);
  • it could be used to promote certain or regional social goals;
  • it could be used to soak up unemployment or as a mechanism for expanding training opportunities.

Whatever the original justification, none of these reasons remain valid today, the first three of which the NSW Government has already abandoned.  Rival organisations are in place under separate boards of directors and the natural monopoly aspects have been carefully defined and subjected to regulatory oversight.

Tariff orders are in place which, explicitly or implicitly, will prevent preferential treatment of certain industries.

And while the Government still wishes to promote certain social goals in electricity provision and prevent wide regional disparities, it now does so through the mechanism of explicit CSO's that can be put in place with equal effect irrespective of ownership structures.

Similarly, it is not part of Government policy to require businesses -- government or privately owned -- to carry costs that a commercially operated business would consider to be imprudent.  Corporatised businesses are, like private enterprises, charged with maximising shareholders' value in the entities.

Since corporatisation, the NSW electricity businesses have also moved rapidly to reduce their staffing levels.  Each of the six retail businesses has reduced its workforce by 10-25 per cent.  However, a consultancy study reportedly recommended the largest distributor, energyAustralia, cut its workforce to 1,800 from 3,800 (which is already a reduction from 4,500). (2)  The response of the board of energyAustralia in rejecting the report and dismissing the CEO does not appear consistent with the hard-nosed commercial framework within which businesses should operate.

Measures that result in excessive costs being carried, especially by businesses with market power, will bring excessive costs to customers.  The NSW consumer will forfeit gain both as a direct customer and as an income earner if high costs result in businesses paying higher prices, foregone capital investment and reduced competitiveness.

As a government owned industry, from the 1970s onwards the NSW electricity supply industry was much more commercially operated than that of Victoria (though less so than the Queensland system).  But all electricity businesses in Australia are improving their efficiency levels and each state has an interest in ensuring it remains competitive.  In this respect, studies by the Bureau of Industry Economics (3) put US investor-owned utilities Total Factor Productivity growth achieved between 1975/75 and 1993/4 at 50 per cent more than NSW.

The same analysis showed electricity sales per employee in NSW during 1993/4 to be lower than the average for thermal based systems in Australia and less than half the levels achieved in the better Canadian systems.


OTHER SOCIAL, REDISTRIBUTIVE AND
REGULATORY ROLES THAT HAVE EVOLVED

SOCIAL AND REDISTRIBUTIVE ROLES

In discussing CSOs it is apparent that government ownership has spawned goals and expectations of electricity supply arrangements and the terms and conditions of these to particular parties that were not originally present.  Some of these have been due to electricity supply being hostage to political demands as well as those of the marketplace which dominate the conditions of supply of goods and services in general.

The NSW Government may wish to retain some of these obligations, even where they impose a cost that other customers (or the taxpayer) must carry.  But its corporatisation procedures are designed to ensure that any such costs are explicitly provided for rather than hidden.

Among the issues that proved most tendentious in the Victorian corporatistion/privatisation were the risks that the cross subsidies that had favoured rural users would be unwound.  The Victorian Government took steps to avoid this by reassigning asset values on which line charges are based to reduce distribution tariffs in rural areas.

Such measures result in subsequent pressures.  Line charges that are boosted above their true costs bring incentives for by-pass.  Requirements that each distributor should "postage stamp" the line charges in its area are already resulting in tensions between distributors in diverse territories from customers who can readily observe lower charges in adjacent areas.  These tensions will however be present irrespective of whether or not the entities are privatised.


REGULATORY ROLES

As the Treasurer makes clear in his discussion paper A Plan for a Secure New South Wales, the present arrangements for electricity supply are not deregulation.  Indeed, there is a plethora of oversighting bodies.  At the national level these include the ACCC, the NCC, NEMMCO, and NECA.  Within NSW these include IPART on price regulation, the Department of Energy on retail licensing, the Office of Fair Trading for customer matters, and Transgrid on the market operations.

Some rationalisation of these bodies is necessary.  In particular, the licensing role of the Department of Energy seems to be redundant, especially in a national market where State Governments have expressed a view in favour of mutual recognition.  In fact, the different bodies in NSW has already led to some confusion where the market operator has not been aware of particular retailers and failed to inform them of changed procedures for reassigning customers.


RETENTION VALUES AGAINST SALE VALUES

Various values have been set as estimates of the State's electricity assets if sold to private entities or if floated to the public.  The precise sale value cannot be determined and much will depend on the mode of sale and the regulatory conditions.  In Victoria, which is only two thirds the size of the NSW system, generators and distributor/retailers will, with the completion of the sale process, have brought in some $20 billion.  This is a sum far in excess of that expected by the Victorian Government at the time the asset sales were planned.

The NSW Government 1997/8 revenue from its electricity assets is estimated to be $656 million in dividends plus $221 million in tax equivalent payments.  Even if the NSW assets were to fetch only the $20 billion achieved in Victoria -- and there is every reason to expect 30-40 per cent more -- this would represent an effective dividend and tax return of less than 4.4 per cent.  At the $22 billion Arthur Andersen valuation offered by the Treasurer, Mr. Egan, (4) this is less than 4 per cent.

Such a low return is typically to be found only among share assets that are expected to show very strong profit growth.  It is difficult to justify continued ownership by the Government if private sector entities value the assets at such a high level.

Even placing the funds from asset sales that realised $22 billion in long term Commonwealth bonds would give a yield the State a saving of $663 million plus that part of the (Commonwealth) tax equivalence of $221 million which would go indirectly to the people of NSW.  The Victorian Government budget papers estimate the revenue effect of that State's privatisation of $18 billion of assets as a net $718 million positive impact on the budget in 1997/98. (5)  Given the Victorian experience and the 1997/8 revenue from electricity businesses estimated in the NSW budget papers, the Treasurer's estimated savings to the NSW taxpayer could be highly conservative.

The Treasurer has offered a considerable number of expenditure options from the increased revenue the sale process would bring in.  These range from retiring debt to rebuilding roads, hospitals and sewerage systems to improving disabled accommodation and building schools.  Many of these expenditures are not mutually exclusive and a higher level of sale return would offer even greater scope for tax reductions.

Other alternatives to disbursing the fiscal windfall that a sale of electricity assets would bring are lowering of taxes on business and consumers.  In this respect, following the recent budgets in Victoria and NSW, the Victorian Treasurer has claimed that for the first time for a number of years Victorian taxes are lower than those in NSW.  Mr Stockdale claimed that the 1997/8 tax burden in NSW had risen to $2,112 per head compared with $1,916 per head in Victoria. (6)

The budgetary measures that might be taken in the wake of the increased revenue from electricity industry asset sales are political decisions.  What is certain is that with the sales the scope for a mix of tax cuts and needed expenditures elsewhere presents enviable alternatives that are not present in the absence of the sales.  The sale process would result in an injection of $20 billion plus into the NSW economy.  Irrespective of the manner of sale or the way the sale proceeds are used, much of that will incremental to the sums available within NSW.  Whether the proceeds are used in construction of new infrastructure or a lighter tax load on NSW industries and consumers, the sale process will result in the creation of many thousands of new jobs.

The privatisation process in NSW can also benefit from the Victorian sale experience, which has demonstrated the value of electricity industry assets.  NSW has scope to float rather than trade-sale parts of its industry, thereby fostering significant Australian equity holdings.


CURRENT MARKET STRUCTURE AND
ADMINISTRATIVE ECONOMIES OF SCALE

The notion of an electricity market that is a natural monopoly has long been discredited.  Only the poles and wires aspects can be so regarded, and NZ with virtually no regulation over the distribution of electricity has taken the view that monopolistic behaviour of the wires business is highly circumscribed by the ability of customers to by-pass their host distributor.

NSW already has competition in the retailing and generating sectors.  It is however the view of the Energy Forum that many of the entities in these two sectors are excessively large and could in the future exercise market dominance.  Thus, both Delta and Macquarie with four and two stations respectively each have over twice the capacity of the largest Victorian generator and over three times the capacity of the largest Queensland generator.  Similarly, with energyAustralia and to a lesser extent Integral Energy, the NSW Government has created two very large retail/distribution entities.  EnergyAustralia approaches the size of the entire Victorian system and has more than half of the NSW market.  Integral Energy, covering the western suburbs of Sydney, is 40 per cent larger than the two biggest Victorian distribution companies.

There has been considerable debate about the optimum size for distributors and retailers.  That debate is dictated partly by geography and customer profiles and partly by a perception that there are some economies of scale in retailing and in distribution.  The evidence for such economies has never been persuasive.

In most electricity supply industries, retailing and distribution represents almost one third of electricity costs.

Table 2 shows the relative size of Australian distributor/retailers.

Table 2:  The Size of Australian Retailers

Retail businessNumber of customers (000s)Sales (GWh) (000s)
Victoria
Powercor5377.3
Solaris2343.5
CitiPower2334.4
United Energy5276.4
Eastern Energy4705.1
NSW
Energy Australia130620
Integral Energy68111.8
NorthPower3363.4
Advance Energy1131.77
Energy South2183.4
Australian Inland Energy210.3
ETSA7009.2
Queensland
SEQUEB87411.7
Capricornia871.4
Far North920.7
Mackay480.7
North Queensland931
South West910.5
Wide Bay850.5
HEC2398

Source:  ESAA


The greater part of a distributor/retailer's assets and workforce are employed in the distribution aspects of the business.  Typically, distribution will contribute 90 per cent of profitability.  However, the ten per cent of profit deriving from retail activity plays a vital role in promoting customer orientation and, seeking out innovative marketing approaches, and achieving a better match between energy supplies and demands.


DISTRIBUTION

Distribution involves breaking down the high voltage power and reticulating it locally to the vast bulk of customers not on the high voltage network.  The main functions are "poles and wires" business operations -- maintenance and expansion of the network in response to customer demand.  Much of this work can be and is increasingly outsourced.

In New Zealand, a 1989 Ministry of Energy report found the optimum size of distributor/retailers to be about 2000 GWh.  London Economics work has tended to show much higher levels of scale economies -- around 25,000 GWh or half the total NSW load. (7)

New Zealand, with a population of 3.5 million, inherited 61 distributors but a spate of takeover activity is reducing this number to a level forecast to become as few as 10.  At that number each would average 150,000 customers.

Norway, with a population of 4.5 million has some 200 distributors, while Switzerland has 1,600 distributors based on local communities.

Reviewing the evidence, the Queensland Electricity Industry Task Force (8) cited submissions to it that claimed economies of scale on the basis of better access to capital markets, retention and training of skilled workforce, synergies in pooling information technology and administrative and billing functions.  In its analysis, the Task Force tended to emphasise the location specific factors.  It said, "... network scale economy measures need to be interpreted carefully.  It is not sufficient to simply compare the average costs of production with output.  The characteristics of the network, in terms of its density is the key driver.  For example a distributor that serves a densely populated area (high customer density) will be more efficient than a distribution entity that serves a sparsely populated area with customers that consume a comparatively low amount of energy."

Nonetheless, the Queensland Electricity Task Force came out in favour of amalgamating the distributors other than SEQEB into two groupings.  The Queensland Government has decided to retain the seven existing distributors, noting that these distribution corporations will be subjected to extensive regulation to ensure that costs are minimised.  However, it is to split off the retailing functions from the distributors and divide the initial market between three retailers along lines recommended by the Task Force.  The government sees this as providing advantages of capitalising on the trading opportunities a competitive electricity market offers.

In Victoria the choice of five distributors/host retailers was determined by the need to ensure competition and a wish to create businesses that would be attractive to private sector buyers.  Part of this entailed designing territories that had an even spread of customers and giving each retailer/distributor a sizeable urban population.  It was also complicated by the existence of 13 metropolitan local authority owned retail/distributors which were tied to the SEC and many of which were extremely inefficient.

New South Wales amalgamated its previous 25 electricity distribution businesses into six firms, and has taken steps to open the retail market to competition both between these firms and between new businesses.  As previously discussed, energyAustralia is very large.

There are risks in creating a dominant retailer/distributor like energyAustralia in that it could exercise undue market power over customer information and line charges that could give it an unfair advantage over its competitors.  The Victorian distribution businesses appear to have demonstrated that there are no economies of scale beyond the 200,000 plus customer size in this industry.  The smaller businesses consider that improved work practices and savings in overhead costs have resulted from bringing supervisory levels closer to the working operations.

A major safeguard against distributors charging customers higher prices than those warranted by their costs is the ability of a customer or rival distributors to by-pass part of the distributor's system.  Under the Victorian regime there is some ambiguity in the ability to by-pass prior to the year 2000, stemming from the conditions under which distributors were sold.  The NSW regime clearly allows by-pass.  This will ensure from the outset that there are tighter disciplines on cost-reflective tariffs.


RETAILING

Energy retailing entails:

  • making bulk contracts and purchasing from the pool and subdividing these to meet the needs of different customers or customer classes
  • metering and billing.

The UK regulator, OFFER, has estimated retail costs as follows:

Figure 3

In a competitive market, retailers will need to be customer focussed in order to win and maintain market share.  This is already entailing a much more active business stance in those markets where customers are contestable.  It is leading retailers to pay particular attention to market research, seeking matching load and power profiles, ensuring that tariffs are cost-reflective and seeking custom by offering advice on energy management.  Some retailers (e.g. United Energy in Victoria) are also seeking to develop synergies by offering retail services in similar businesses like telecommunications.  It is widely anticipated that electricity retailers will offer gas and water services once these utilities are opened to competition.

Under a competitive market, retailers need to manage price risks in a system where price is volatile, and market risks where customers are free to take their business to a rival.  In Victoria some 40 per cent of contestable customers have contracted for power with a non-host retailer.  Similar changes have been experienced in the UK.  New Zealand however has seen only 7.5 per cent of power being delivered to customers in competing retailers' territories.  This is largely due to all customers in New Zealand being contestable and the difficulty of the 50 per cent of the load comprising small users to justify the added costs of sophisticated metering without which rival retailers are reluctant to seek business.

With regard to optimum size, David Harbord, London Economic and Fay, Richwhite (9) found in an analysis of US retailers that costs were 10 per cent lower for retailers of between 10-20 GWh than for both smaller and larger retailers.  The same data however found that costs per customer increased with size.

It is difficult to find persuasive evidence of economies accruing to size of retailer per se.  This is not to dispute the potential for negotiating lower prices where high volumes are purchased.  In Norway, brokers have emerged to undertake power purchasing on behalf of retail/distributors.  The 750 kWh per year customer contestability program in Victoria demonstrated the ability of customers being able to obtain considerable discounts by acting in large groupings and negotiating favourable terms from rival suppliers.


GENERATION

The efficiency of generation in NSW is at levels comparable to those in Victoria.  In terms of thermal efficiency, NSW black coal generators convert more coal to energy than do the Victorian brown coal generators because of the latters' intrinsically lower quality coal.

In most respects recognition was received of the greater operational efficiency of private sector generators as long ago as the 1989 Industry Commission report on electricity.  In Victoria, the privately owned Anglesea power station consistently outperformed newer SECV stations, as did the Mission Energy operated Loy Yang B station.

Such local evidence of superior private sector operational efficiency reinforced the overseas experience.  This was documented by the BIE in its benchmarking of electricity.  In terms of electricity sold per employee, which is of course only a partial indicator of cost-efficiency, this showed NSW to have achieved less than one third the productivity of comparable thermal based Canadian systems and considerably less than Victoria.  But NSW generators, for the most part operate with lean labour forces as shown in Table 3, and the efficiency savings are most likely to be found in distribution and transmission.

In terms of availability, the poor levels in both States five years ago, with availabilities averaging about 80 per cent, have been transformed in recent years.  Three of the privatised Victorian brown coal generators now operate at over 95 per cent availability which is close to world's best practice.  Impressive gains have also been made been made by NSW generators, though only one presently operates at the 95 per cent availability level.

Forced outage rates have shown comparable levels of improvement in both states, although again the rates are somewhat higher in NSW.

The table below documents some of the changes that have taken place.  Although NSW has achieved considerable gains over recent years, it would appear that new management with a sharp focus on commercial efficiency would see opportunities for further gains.  This is likely to increase the price of the assets would realise.

1994/95 Efficiency Estimates

Output (GWh) per Employee 1996/7Equivalent Availability FactorForced Outage FactorThermal Efficiency
Loy Yang Power26*94.32.1
Yallourn16*88.65.130
Hazelwood16*92.62.824
Southern Hydro88.81.2
Ecogen960.936.9
Loy Yang B96.30.931
Eraring4195.51.536.3
Munmorah377.99.532.7
Vales Point2683.82.936.2
Bayswater5091.72.936.8
Liddell1688532.9
Wallerawang1374.67.532.2
Mount Piper3890.65.135.9

Source:  ESAA and individual businesses.

* Figures for Victoria are not directly comparable with NSW because they
include coal mining and some head office staff excluded in the NSW figures.


There is no evidence that smaller entities whether generation or distribution, are less efficient than larger ones.  While it is theoretically possible to achieve cost savings with large integrated utilities, the information requirements to do so have prevented them being realised.  In the process, the larger entities tend to lose the entrepreneurial elan and become excessively bureaucratised.

Deficiencies in the existing arrangements of public ownership are revealed in the present struggle for the 750 MWh per year customers in NSW.  Retailers have been offering very low prices to customers, in the main backed by contracts from generators.  Whereas a vesting price of around $44.5 per MWh for captive customers represented the Government's best view on the long term price of electricity, contracts have been signed at a reported price of $14 per MWh.  Our information is that purely in terms of O&M and coal costs, the average NSW generator costs are Delta $23/MWh, and Pacific Power and Macquarie $19/MWh.

The NSW generators are not covering their costs at present contract prices and are only able to offer the low prices prevailing because the vesting contracts allow cross subsidisation.  This is in effect a transfer from domestic and small business customers to large customers.  Table 4 summarises our estimates of the costs of the three main NSW generation businesses.

Table 4:  NSW Costs of Generation per MWh

O&M plus CoalTotal Costs exc. Profit
Delta2333
Pacific Power1933
Macquarie1930

The total costs of NSW generators are probably lower than those of their Victorian counterparts because the latter have had their capital revalued to market prices as a result of the sale process.  O&M costs in Victoria are lower because of cheaper coal and are estimated at $10-$15 for the three main ex-SECV generators, Loy Yang Power, Yallourn Energy and Hazelwood Power.

The very low contract prices being negotiated for contestable customers would have been a factor in the NSW Government determining to impose a new tax at 0.55 cents per kwh on these sales in the 1997/8 budget.  The tax is estimated to raise $100 million.  It has drawn criticism from the Commonwealth Government, customers and business groups and from interstate competitors.  It effectively allows the Government as shareholder to be indifferent as to the market behaviour of the entities it owns since they can win business while allowing the shareholder to recoup losses where that business is gained at uncommercial prices.

Over the longer term such merging of roles between governments as owners and governments as revenue raisers is inconsistent with the free and fair trade provisions of the CoAG agreements.  The National Competition Council has been charged with reporting to the Commonwealth the performance of the different jurisdictions in meeting their obligations.  Should the NCC advise that the behaviour of a jurisdiction is not in accordance with the principles agreed, payment may be withheld.

Irrespective of whether or not the new tax on electricity had an anti-competitive effect, a government which stands to gain by such measures through the assets it owns is vulnerable to the charge of interfering with market processes in contravention to its obligations under the CoAG agreements.  This adds a further forceful reason why the assets should be privatised.


TRANSMISSION

The NSW transmission business, Transgrid, is responsible both for the network, and for the power exchange and system security services.  In Victoria these two functions are split in Victoria between Powernet and VPX.  This is in accordance with the National Electricity Code and allows decisions to be taken that cannot be claimed to carry a vested interest.

A complex matter with regard to transmission is how to ensure that there are efficiency drivers in place for a facility that involves a considerable degree of natural monopoly.  The national market envisages incentives to ensure the appropriate expenditure on transmission through permitting "entrepreneurial" interconnects, whereby businesses will build lines where they spot an opportunity for profit and charge those using the facility.

The precise means of arranging for such charges has not been fully explored.  Moreover, the traditional planning mechanism remain in place so that the system controller can direct new developments and augmentations with the costs borne collectively.  A "free" resource of this nature tends to freeze out the opportunities for profit driven activity.  In doing so it leaves inadequate incentives for efficient location.  It would, for example, leave a cogeneration facility relatively indifferent about whether it locates in Botany near to the centre of demand or at Armidale where its usefulness would require considerable expenditure in transmission lines.

The means to ensure efficiency in transmission is not yet resolved.  However, the housing of system security and transmission within one entity, as in NSW, gives rise to perverse incentives since the same business has nothing to lose by requiring augmentations which are paid for by a levy on other bodies.

Divorcing the system control functions from the transmission business would not fully resolve the present deficiency in the national market whereby transmission is centrally planned rather than market driven but it would move a step towards this.  Moreover, such a divorce is essential if the transmission business is to be sold since it would be totally inconsistent to have one market player standing to gain by dint of its abilities to impose costs on others.



Attachment:
THE EXISTING REFORM AGENDA

HILMER REPORT

The microeconomic reform process which is driving structural change in the Australian electricity industry commenced before, but is consistent with, the recommendations of the report of the Committee of Inquiry into National Competition Policy, commissioned by the Australian Government in 1992 ("the Hilmer Report").

Previous government inquiries had established that there was considerable scope for increased efficiency and competition in the Australian electricity industries.  The Hilmer Report pointed out that the introduction of effective competition into markets traditionally supplied by public monopolies often required more than the removal of regulatory restrictions on competition.  The excess market power held by such public monopolies is likely to impede the introduction of effective competition, and therefore reform requires the dismantling of monopolies in addition to the removal of regulatory restrictions on competition.

The Hilmer Report identified three separate types of structural reform which may be required in any particular industry:

  • the separation of regulatory and commercial functions which could create a potential conflict of interest in a competitive market;
  • the separation of natural monopoly elements from potentially competitive activities, because control over access to a natural monopoly might be used to stifle or prevent competition in the market, or if not exercised in that way the potential to do so may deter new entrants into the market;  and
  • the separation of potentially competitive activities by splitting or dismantling entities with substantial market power into a number of distinct competitive entities capable of competing with each other.

COUNCIL OF AUSTRALIAN GOVERNMENTS

In April 1995, the Council of Australian Governments ("COAG") signed the National Competition Policy Agreements ("NCP Agreements") which adopted the recommendations of the Hilmer Report and formalised the Governments' intent to promote a more competitive domestic trading environment and improve Australia's position in the international market.  To that end, the NCP Agreements lay down a set of principles for the structural reform and prices oversight of public monopolies and hence have significant application to the electricity supply industry.

The guiding objectives determined by the COAG in the building of the national electricity market ("NEM") were:

  • freedom of choice for electricity buyers;
  • non-discriminatory access to the interconnected transmission and distribution networks;
  • merit order dispatch based on bid price;
  • no discriminatory legislative or regulatory barriers to entry for new participants in electricity generation or retail supply;
  • no barriers to inter-state or intra-state trade;  and
  • uniform and cost reflective grid pricing.

ADOPTION OF HILMER AND COAG INITIATIVES VIA SPECIAL PAYMENT MECHANISM

One of the measures agreed to in the NCP Agreements was the development of an interim competitive NEM during 1997 and completion of the transition to a fully competitive NEM by 1 July 1999.

The incentive, to meet this deadline, was provided by the NCP Agreements themselves.  Under the NCP Agreements, the Commonwealth agreed to make special payments to States and Territories that made satisfactory progress in implementing the national competition policy reforms.  If a State or Territory does not take the required action within the specified time, its share of the payments will be withheld.  The National Competition Council ("NCC") will assess, prior to 1July 1997, 1 July 1999 and 1 July 2001, whether the conditions for payments to the States and Territories, to commence from those dates, have been met.

The money which has been allocated to these special payments is set out in Figure 4 below (estimated nominal $ million).

Figure 4:  Competition Payments

1997-1998428
1998-1999646
1999-20001113
2000-20011369
2001-20021888
2002-20032184
2003-20042499
2004-20052833
2005-20063188
TOTAL16147

Source:  National Competition Council Brochure (October 1996)


PROGRESS TO DATE

The NEM was first scheduled to commence on July 1994.  The scheduled commencement date has been deferred a number of times.

It was determined in late 1996 that there would be a phased implementation of the NEM.  These stages would be known as NEM1 (Phase 1 and Phase 2), NEM2 and NEM3.  More particularly:

NEM1 Phase 1 commenced April 1997 and links the Victorian and New South Wales markets.  That is:

  • electricity will flow in and between the State markets based on competitive bid offers received in both markets;
  • initial limits on flows between markets will be progressively removed;
  • power system security responsibilities will remain with each State;  and
  • separate Snowy Traders in each State will manage the bidding into each State market;

NEM1 Phase 2 (1 July 1997) will see:

  • the removal of initial limitations on interstate trading;
  • power system security managed on a national basis;
  • a single entity being responsible for Snowy participation in the NEM;
  • a common approach to ancillary services;  and
  • a NEM approach to losses;

NEM2 will commence after the National Electricity Law is enacted and the Code is authorised by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission ("ACCC") and accepted as an access undertaking.  As systems consistent with the Code's market rules (Chapter 3) and system security (Chapter 4) provisions of the Code are not envisaged to be available at that stage, these elements will still be governed by the provisions of State codes.  However, other chapters of the Code will apply.  NEM2 is anticipated to start in mid-1997, but it is not expected to have any material impact on wholesale market trading;  and

NEM3 is the fully operative national market.  It is anticipated to start in early 1998, once NEMMCO has fully tested and taken delivery of the national market systems.  That is, when all chapters of the Code apply and the State codes no longer apply.


EXPECTED ACTUAL COMMENCEMENT

A significant step towards implementing the NEM took place in May 1996, when the Governments of New South Wales, Victoria, Queensland, South Australia and the Australian Capital Territory executed an intergovernmental agreement to introduce the NEM through legislation ("the National Electricity Law") to apply in each jurisdiction.

As required by that agreement, in June 1996 South Australia enacted "lead legislation" containing the National Electricity Law (which in turn provides for the establishment of the National Electricity Code ("the Code").  The other participating jurisdictions are now in the course of preparing their own "application legislation" to apply the National Electricity Law and the Code.

The Code has been prepared through a consultative process conducted by the participating jurisdictions and involving industry participants.  The Code was submitted to the ACCC in December 1996 for authorisation under Part VII of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth).  Accompanying the Code was a draft access regime, which is also being examined by the ACCC pursuant to Part IIIA of that Act.

The commencement of the National Electricity Law and the Code in each jurisdiction will not take place until the ACCC has authorised the Code and accepted as an access undertaking.  While the expected commencement of NEM1 (Phase 1) is 14 days after a positive determination is received from the ACCC, the National Electricity Law and the Code are currently scheduled to commence mid 1998.



ENDNOTES

1The Economist 14 June 1997, p. 72.

2Australian Financial Review, September 26, p. 40.

3Electricity 1996, International Benchmarking, Productivity Commission, Canberra 1996.

4A Plan for a Secure New South Wales, Discussion Paper to Pacific Power and the Electricity Unions, 22 May 1997.

5.  Victorian 1997/98 Budget No. 2 p.131.  The Auditor General's Report estimated somewhat lower savings than this, at $549 million in 1997/8.

6.  Hansard, 21 May 1997.

7.  "Economies of Scale in the Electricity Generation and Distribution Sector", Report to the NSW Treasury, London Economics, August 1994.

8Reform of the Queensland Electricity Supply Industry, Volume II p. 164, December 1996.

9.  "Introducing Competition in Electricity Retailing in NSW:  Market Power Considerations", David Harbord and Associates, London Economics and Fay, Richwhite, Final Report Volume 2 p. 22-32.

Whither Labor?

Backgrounder

The two major forces in Australian politics, the Australian Labor Party and the Coalition, do not operate in a vacuum, ignorant of the thoughts and intentions of the other.  The parties compete for votes, and they watch each other closely.  To some extent, the ability to advance policy successfully arises from this competition, so that an analysis of the fall of the Keating Labor government is as important to the Coalition as it is to Labor.

This Backgrounder argues that Labor's drive for economic reform began to stall by 1989 and that the electorate had grown tired of the difficult issues involved in that reform.  Consequently, a gap opened up in public dialogue into which well-defined and visible issues flowed, backed by well-organised and often publicly-funded advocates.  Labor sought to harness these votes in order to regain lost ground.  While this strategy worked for some time, the majority of voters came to feel more and more removed from the debate.  In the public's mind, their views were taking second place to those of "minority" opinion.

If economic reform is to return to centre stage, and draw at least tacit approval from the electorate, the vast majority of voters will have to be reassured that their interests are being addressed.  The way back to economic reform is not to crush minority views, but to develop national themes that have an appeal across the electorate no matter what the ethnicity, race, sex, or sexual preference of the voter.  The lesson for the Howard Government is that if it fails to build a national consensus around non-economic issues, it will probably fail to advance its economic reform agenda.


INTRODUCTION

If the Federal Labor Government had not been defeated at the 1996 election, it almost certainly would have imploded during its sixth term.

Only the enormous discipline of being in government, and the huge authority of Prime Minister Keating had managed to bury a string of policy difficulties that were emerging.  Not the least of these was repairing the Federal Budget which, incidentally, both parties chose to ignore during the election, and the pain of which would almost certainly have fallen on the broad mass of taxpayers.

Labor in a sixth term would have faced the need to balance the Budget (or the retirement of government debt), without the sale of Telstra, without the savings from labour market programmes, without the cuts to ATSIC and a string of other probable "irreducibles".  The temptation to raise taxes, especially through the widening of the net of indirect taxes, would have ushered in a virtual goods and services tax.

While its record on employment creation was laudable, it left government with unemployment only marginally lower than when it commenced, and most of the advice to government for lowering unemployment, like further deregulation of the labour market, pointed squarely at its own constituency.

But Labor never was going to win a sixth term, and so it was saved from itself, to govern again at a later date.

Govern for whom though, to what ends?  Why would anyone want to join the Australian Labor Party?  The issues which stirred over five generations of Australians to join the oldest political party in Australia, and one of the oldest democratic socialist parties in the world, are not so apparent in 1997.

Labor for much of its history was deeply protectionist in trade and industrial matters, (1) and deeply xenophobic and conservative in cultural matters like immigration and race. (2)  In the last 25 years it has been decidedly liberal:  free trade, freer wage bargaining, non-discriminatory in race, creed and gender.  It was probably that very liberalism though, opening up on so many fronts, from the sale of government assets, to cutting tariffs, supporting women into the workforce, and the human rights agenda, that ultimately led to its defeat.

Unless a citizen was a member of an interest group (disadvantaged or not) such as greens, homosexuals, aboriginals, they no longer felt represented.  This feeling was even true for clear winners, such as pensioners or recipients of a host of direct payments such as child care, family and Austudy payments.

Public discourse in the last few years appeared to be for, and run by, those intent on winning their own place in society, or imposing their own view rather than the progress of the society as a whole.  The struggle of the visible minorities was not necessarily synonymous with the struggle of the majority.

Society had to wait while every imperfection was eradicated, and society waited so long that it grew impatient.  The course of the Labor government was entangled with the continual criticism of the world inhabited by most Australians.  Australian citizens were told that they were racist, bigoted, sexist, rapacious, and were being watched by better persons, either in their own government or by international organisations such as the United Nations.

Even the proposed establishment of an Australian Republic seemed to be a demand to give up the past rather than a challenge to create the future.

It appeared that social cohesion was enforced by a consensus of the interest groups, that together monopolised public discourse.  There was a code by which one had to live, but the code was remote from the lives of most citizens.

The themes that Bob Hawke brought to government -- recovery (economic), reconstruction (infrastructure), and reconciliation (industrial) were universals applying to all citizens.  The themes that Paul Keating left in government -- rights (individual), receipts (benefits) and reconciliation (racial) were not universals, they were divisive themes.  The nadir of the controlled intellectual climate of the Keating government was the Racial Hatred Bill.  This was legislation that could never have been enforced and it came to represent the repression of thought as well as speech.

Australian citizens had made some progress in understanding what was required to make Australia a better place, by changing the economy and being more tolerant, but they did not necessarily share those views and resented being told they had to respect them.  If the United Nations and the Australian Government had declared a "Year of Just Getting on with It" the nation would have breathed a sigh of relief.

In short, Australians were and are being asked to cope with an enormous array of changes, many of which they do not like and do not agree with.

This Backgrounder will argue that there has been a loss of consensus about the national purpose.  The consequence is that energies are being dissipated on narrow agendas, and the loss of social cohesion will make the pursuit of essential changes to the Australian economy more difficult than at most times in the past.

It will also argue that the ALP is a mainstream party but that it lost the mantle in its last years of government, and that it needs to secure its position as a mainstream party by reforming its structure in the light of the loss of its base (a long time coming but masked by incumbency), and its need for a new legitimacy.

It can retain its philosophy -- of the need for collective action through lawful means -- but for national purposes, and not just for the purpose of single-interest groups.

Three examples of policies with a national purpose, and which promote social cohesion, will be explored.


A NATIONAL CONSENSUS

Although the underlying direction of the Labor government from 1983 to 1996 was the same -- the internationalisation of the Australian economy, and a fair sharing of the benefits and burdens of change -- this theme began to fail in the public mind by about 1989.  Until that time there were appeals to the electorate to be involved in the major national task, but when the discipline of keeping their eye on the main task proved too taxing for too many, Labor turned to sectoral support.  At the 1990 election, Labor's two-party-preferred vote held, with the support of conservationists, and again in 1993 with a combination of expanded middle-class welfare -- particularly the easing of means-testing of payments and pensions, the promise of tax cuts to middle income earners, and of course, the demonisation of the Coalition's Goods and Services Tax.

Eating away at that appeal to the major task, however, were the driving agendas of the organised interest groups, the so-called "minorities".  The full agenda of the groups was outlined by Altman in 1979, (3) and indeed predicted by the ALP's National Inquiry of 1979. (4)  As former Labor leader Bill Hayden remarked:

Personal rights, often narrowly conceived, are emphasised at the expense of community duties. ... Political policy-making proceeds too much on the basis of appeasing the demands and threats of some of these (single issue) groups. ... All of this leads to a growing sense of neglect, of the alienation from the political processes of the vast number of people. (5)

By 1996 the ALP was identified by many as the party of the minorities and their articulate, well-educated supporters.  This caused the party to lose the mantle of a mainstream party, which by definition governs on behalf of the majority, and the majority's definition of the national interest.  This does not require a belief that minority interests conflict with the achievement of the majority interests, for only occasionally will the two be irreconcilable.  But in a period of triumph for the minorities' agendas there had to be a few triumphs for everyone else:  unfortunately, these were hard to come by.

The major political task in 1997 and in the near future is the restoration of the social cohesion that was apparent in 1983 but which declined thereafter, and has not been restored by the Coalition government.  Both the ALP and the Coalition agree on the essential elements of the future -- a market economy increasingly subject to the disciplines of international competition, government intervention to encourage competition in all sectors, and a welfare safety net that is not universally available -- but the means of advancing these are not so apparent.

In addition to the traditional schism of labour and capital and their "class" backers, there is also a schism of individual rights and the achievement of the national purpose, a working class (poor or comfortable) at odds with an educated, articulate elite determined to eradicate every blemish in society, but in doing so creating a real moral burden for all.  This burden is that everyone has become everyone else's keeper in a way more pervasive than the most devoted socialist's welfare state could ever have been.  Individual causes have a myriad manifestations, causes for all are often invisible.  In terms of political activity, "relatively unrepresentative groups are usually more effective in manipulating the state than are widespread but diffuse interests." (6)

This same division of agendas expresses itself within the ALP.  It is now bound up with the minority causes its articulate middle-class backers are most interested in.  But so many of those interests affront the old base.  It has to reconcile these divisions in its own ranks in precisely the same way that the nation has to, and by implication the Howard government.  It needs to develop policies that achieve at one and the same time a win for all.

One way to achieve this is to choose themes that incorporate the wishes of both the majority and the minority.  Three examples of this approach will be discussed later -- drawn from the environment, the social structure, and the economy.  These three examples are not grand themes like the Republic, but themes nevertheless that produce an outcome that most can share.  These are, that:

  • A given number of people will share in the wealth, and share in the responsibility of caring for this country;
  • Almost all Australians live in, or did live in, or want to live in, or want to live in again, a family;
  • All Australians want to work (or have a recognised role in the society).

Politics often involves creating agendas, and the minorities' agendas have squeezed out those that have more universal application.  The political challenge is to create universal themes that, while not antithetical to the rights of individuals, direct energies to common causes.  This is a role that only government can perform, and is in stark contrast with the role of the courts, for instance, which generally make advances for individuals or small groups by exception.  These wins for gays, greens, feminists, or indigenes intensify the belief that all matters are amenable to legal remedy.  Unfortunately, the agenda for legal redress grows (as with the call for a Bill of Rights) to such an extent, that it goes to the question of resources of "who gets what", (7) and these are matters for politics and economics which inevitably end with political solutions, decided by political means.

The ALP needs to develop policies that create a comfort zone for the electorate, policies that are clearly in the interests of the nation, but explicitly for the "majority".  Before doing that, however, the party needs to understand why it was defeated in 1996, what lessons can be drawn from its period in government, and what changes the party must undertake itself.


REASONS FOR THE 1996 LABOR DEFEAT

There is no doubt in the mind of Malcolm Mackerras why Labor was defeated:  "The result in March 1996 has a single and simple description.  It was the general election of March 1993 delayed by three years." (8)  But even if he is right, there is the need to explain why that defeat occurred.  Polling conducted for the ALP by UMR Research Pty Ltd on election day indicated that the "it's time" factor was most important:  34 per cent of respondents ranked it first.  Like the Mackerras explanation, though, it really only explains when, not why.

The loss of seats was not uniform throughout the nation. (9)  The national two-party-preferred swing was 5.1 per cent, but the damage to Labor was in three States in terms of the votes:  Queensland 8.6 per cent, New South Wales 7 per cent and South Australia 4.6 per cent.  In terms of seats, though, the damage was in New South Wales, 13 seats lost, and Queensland, 11 seats lost.  The simple explanation is that the Labor vote and the number of seats held was historically high in New South Wales and Queensland, so they had most to lose.  Both had unpopular State Labor administrations which helped to set an adverse mood compounding the adverse mood generated by Labor federally.  But setting the mood does not explain the mood.

Labor's loss was a parting of the ways between Labor and its constituency:

The Government had made as many changes and more as it [thought it] could get away with and in return the electorate had squeezed as much as it could from this particular Government.  Labor had pushed its constituency on privatisation, workplace change and human and civil rights and the constituency bled as much as it could in transfer payments -- pensions, benefits, parenting allowances, child care rebates etc. (10)

Barry Jones MP notes that "losing the election was the second worst consequence ... the worst was the realisation that we deluded ourselves that there was national consensus on issues of race, sexuality, gender and tolerance, and acted accordingly". (11)  The theme was reinforced by Lindsay Tanner MP, who wrote under the heading "Restraining the New Elite":

Labor's doctrine is now dominated by a world view of the tertiary educated generation of the 1970s ... the Keating Government agenda of deregulation, internationalism, multiculturalism and aboriginal reconciliation was dominated by this generation's outlook. ... Unfortunately much of the rest of Australia, including large sections of Labor's base, does not share these views, they no longer merely tolerate or ignore these, in the 1996 Federal election many actively rebelled against them. (12)

Governments are usually defeated for economic incompetence or because of an association with bad economic times. (13) This was true of the Whitlam Government 1972-1975, and the Fraser Government 1975-1983, but even accepting the 1993 election as an aberrant result, the 1996 defeat displays a much wider and deeper set of causes than economic issues.

The most exhaustive list of explanations has been compiled by Barry Jones MP (summarised in the Endnotes) (14) which reinforces the wide variety of possible causes for Labor's defeat.  Laurie Ferguson MP, representing an inner-city Sydney Labor seat with a high concentration of ethnic voters, was clear in his explanation for Labor's defeat.  In his estimation:

The two big negatives for the Government were the questions of migration and multiculturalism.  Unfortunately, the party became convinced that dancing polkas and going to the mosque means that some Iman can deliver 20,000 votes to you tomorrow morning. (15)

Another important theme is explained by Bob Hogg, former National Secretary of the ALP:

In 1989, there was the first sign of the government abdicating responsibility when it essentially handed over environment issues ... to interest groups ... over the last three years politics became very bad.  When a Minister hands over to a constitutional lawyer the future of his ministry ..., like Hindmarsh Island, well that is an abdication of political responsibility, and you're asking for trouble. (16)

There was the enduring "Great Angst", the phrase coined by Hugh Mackay in Reinventing Australia, (17) which, if applied to the election would apply to a government of Labor or Coalition persuasion.  The mood of anxiety applied to the whole list of changes taking place in society, and the accumulated grievances that the electorate held against Labor.  As Hugh Emy explains, "after a decade of upheaval many voters simply wish normal service to be resumed". (18)


THE TRUE BELIEVERS

Who did and who did not vote Labor in 1996?

Labor's traditional base, the blue-collar working-class vote, has been sorely tested in the last two decades.  Gone is the certainty of employment and the value attached to certain acquired skills.  Gone are even some of those skills.  Life at home is not the same, nor are the schools, nor even the football teams.  So much has changed that any Labor base is hard to recognise, or so it would seem if old labels are used to identify the base.  If the archetypal Labor supporter was blue-collar male (and by association his wife) in full-time employment, in a highly unionised workplace and, in Keating's famous term, "rusted on" to the ALP, then the future looks bleak for Labor.

All the elements of this picture have changed dramatically in recent years.  There are fewer workers engaged in manual work, fewer of these are based in highly unionised workplaces, many of the jobs are part-time and many of the workers have retired early.  The spouse is more often than not working, and more likely to engage in a wider circle of life beyond the home.

On the other hand, white-collar workers, many of whom are women, are employees (supposedly the defining element of the struggle between capital and labour) and so some of the change to the picture is just re-labelling.

Somewhere between re-labelling and fundamental shifts there are elements at work that may change significantly the "worker's" attachment to Labor:

  • Less peer pressure arising from the workplace, including the highly unionised public sector, where employment has dropped from 26 per cent of the workforce to 19 per cent between 1979 and 1996.
  • The experience of women being more autonomous than was once the case, particularly through their greater participation in the workforce.
  • The large rise in the number of self-employed -- from 9 per cent in 1979 to 20 per cent in 1996 -- who are now on the other side of the employer/employee or labour/capital divide.
  • The large rise in the early-retired, whose source of income is no longer dependent on a wage, but on the return from capital.
  • Denial of the need to fight for protective industrial relations measures that are now in legislation (which is not to argue that it will always be thus) -- the problems of the "free riders".
  • A rise in the level of affluence for a large number of individuals, such that the struggle is not what it was and the needs not so urgent.

These changes mean that Labor cannot take any segment of the electorate for granted.  While Labor's political leadership knows that only too well, some are hopeful that a new coalition of interests will emerge to bridge some of the new divisions.

Mark Latham MP argues that the size, rather than the source of a people's income will be the determining influence of their economic and political interest:

The economic interests of semi skilled, blue-collar workers now have more in common with a small retailer (technically an owner of capital) in the main street of Werribee than a multi media specialist (part of the labour force) ... working in South Yarra. (19)

Debate on the nature of the Labor base will continue for a long while yet.  Some will argue that the working class has just changed its colour from blue to white-collar, (20) while others argue that, in a post-industrial society, values have changed such that some voters are less concerned with physical and material security and more with individual rights and personal development.

Both of these views may be valid.  There are white-collar workers who have working-class attitudes and voting behaviour, but there is also a new set of values afoot, post-materialist values that may or may not be averse to Labor voting, but which are at odds with "older" materialist "working-class" values.  The battles between the Greens and the forestry union workers over woodchip exports is the prime example of a reversal of class allegiance for Labor.

The 1990s' elections as a whole, though, surely indicate that voters will shift back and forth between the parties depending upon the importance of the issues and how well the party represents the voters' views at the time, and be less inclined to vote on the basis of previous allegiance.

The same can probably be said of the "ethnic vote" which supposedly attaches so heavily to Labor.  As Laurie Ferguson has stated (above) this claim is vastly over-rated, and was almost certainly never universally true.  The origins and the length of time in Australia of immigrants are determinants of the ethnic vote, and that allegiance is not as monolithic as public policy appears to take for granted.  As Economou concludes:

Ethnic voting is in fact a subset of blue-collar voting, and as such is part of Labor's core blue-collar constituency.  However, in terms of transfer of seats ... ethnicity is not a major factor in Australian elections. (21)

Others are not so convinced, (22) but note that support for Labor among Southern Europeans declined by 3 percentage points between 1993 and 1996, compared to their Australian-born counterparts, and that Eastern Europeans returned to their pro-Coalition voting pattern after moving to Labor in 1993.

On the surface, Liberal Party research seems to have borne out Kemp's (23) predictions of long ago that Labor's base would dry up along with the middle-classing or embourgeoisement of the Australian electorate.  The 1996 election showed:

That Labor's vote among the blue-collar workers fell from nearly 50% in 1993 to 39% in 1996.  The Coalition blue-collar vote jumped 5 points to 47.5% ... Labor's vote among Catholics followed a very similar pattern with the Coalition turning an 8 point deficit in 1993 into a 10 point lead in 1996 -- 47% to 37%. (24)

Liberal Party Federal Director Andrew Robb's explanation is convincing:

It owes much to Labor's attempts over 15 years or more to chase the votes of the socially progressive, often highly educated, affluent end of middle-class Australia.  However, along the way Paul Keating and his colleagues came to reflect far more closely the value and priorities of this narrow, affluent, middle-class group -- values and priorities which in many ways are quite at odds with the values and priorities of workers and their families. (25)

There is some bitterness about this in Labor ranks.  Witness Mark Latham's comment that:  "as a long serving government we attracted a generation of hangers-on.  In Opposition the chattering classes have already started to move on.  Some still look to be lost in the Dandenong Ranges". (26)

The fact is that Labor hunted for votes among non-traditional constituencies and was for a long time electorally successful in doing so, but there came a time when some of the themes of its two bases were irreconcilable.  That does not imply that the Coalition now owns the "battlers" or that Labor won't be competitive again.  The parties are much too wise for that.


LESSONS OF GOVERNMENT

It appears that political parties can be less sure in the future of the allegiance of voters.  Although 78 per cent of voters in 1996 identified with one or other of the major parties, 16 per cent rejected any form of party loyalty, three times the proportion in 1987.

A quarter of a century ago, 9 out of every 10 voters identified with one or other of the major parties, and 1 in 3 were strong partisans.  Today, less than 8 of 10 identify with the major parties and less than 1 in 5 are strong partisans. (27)

In short, Labor faces a radically different market for votes to the one it started to serve in 1983, and the one it was preparing to serve for seven years prior.

It faces that market, however, with some important lessons from the Hawke-Keating years, which in turn built on the lessons of the Whitlam years.  In stark contrast with the Whitlam years, the Hawke-Keating Governments were initially very disciplined.  It was a determination to have a Labor reign, not just a government or two.  And yet a reign can be too long, governments run dry, forget why they are there, lose their best and brightest advocates through fatigue, or damage relations with their own base by going to the "well" too many times asking for changes that are not in the Party Platform, nor even in the mind-set of the broad mass of supporters.

Just as Labor learned the lessons from the Whitlam years, a number of lessons arise from the Hawke-Keating years which will have to be contemplated by a future Labor government:

  • Australian citizens have truly become their brothers' keepers.  There are now so many visible causes, needs and victims that there is "compassion fatigue".
  • Power was ceded to the non-elected, to client groups and institutions which ran their own agendas, and ignored the needs and wants of the vast majority of Australians.
  • The electorate did not share the same vision of the future as the government, so they became distracted, even withdrawn.
  • Discipline of government creates its own hierarchy of authority and ideas, which can cause remoteness which becomes worse with longevity.
  • When government sets the electorate a task it should thank them, and report on progress and failure -- i.e., "Government as coach".

The opening up of the role of the Federal government in 1972 and its continuation unabated has created a paradox.  Federal governments have appeared to be all-powerful and have taken on a huge array of issues, but ultimately lift expectations as they do so.  In the face of so many changes the government thus appears to be less powerful than it is because it cannot satisfy all of those heightened expectations.

Labor also faces a radically different market for policy.  It is unlikely that a future Labor government would reverse any of the major changes of the Howard Government, not to mention a number initiated by Labor.  Telstra, ANL (Australian National Line), the Commonwealth Bank, the Commonwealth Serum Laboratory, the Federal Airports Corporation and a host of others would certainly not be re-purchased.  Tax incentives for private health insurance would not be abolished and nor would (if introduced) Medicare co-payments and a goods and services tax.

What would be left to do?  Both sides of politics would have tried out their policies to reduce unemployment -- Labor's massive retraining schemes, and mild changes to the labour market;  and the Coalition's minimal retraining schemes and more radical change to the labour market.

Labor obviously cannot persist with its "socialist objective" -- the socialisation of the means of production, distribution and exchange -- but it can continue in the tradition of parties like the German Social Democrats, that "the law and the state, not the invisible hand, ultimately protected the community from the anti-social consequences which could result from giving too much rein to market forces." (28)  This is consistent with Whitlam's recent recalling of his 1969 Election speech as Labor leader, "We of the Labor Party have an enduring commitment to a view about society ... opportunities for all citizens ... can be provided only if governments, the community itself acting through its elected representatives, will provide them." (29)

The social democratic philosophy does mean, though, that the ALP is more likely to be both more sympathetic and more vulnerable to the wishes of the "minorities".  The term "social justice" has become the ALP's catch-all concept to attempt to incorporate the diversity of "single" issues to come before the ALP, but it is not universally accepted within the party.  At Federal Caucus meetings in the 1990s, Members would often ask (tongue-in-cheek), the leading proponent (30) of the term to explain the "social justice" implications of some obscure matter, like a Bill to do with pig production!  Such calls served as a reminder that it was better to say "no" to a constituency than to justify the demand in the name of a particular philosophy.

Some argue that the ALP has lost its way because it was too much the social democratic party, that there has been an "emptying out" (31) of the Labor tradition in the past decade-and-a-half.  Much of that emptying out, however, was a discarding of a more radical language (socialist), that was itself a long way from Labor tradition, which in the main has been quite pragmatic.


PARTY LEGITIMACY

The challenge for Labor is not so much to contemplate its philosophy, but its role.  The challenge that it has in common with the other major parties is a loss of public faith that has accompanied a decline in membership, and a propensity to shift to independents, single-issue groups, and to pursue action by direct means, such as through the courts.

The ALP is a mainstream party, and as such must advance the interests of the majority, and be seen to do so.  It must also establish what the interests of the majority are, as well as those of minorities, and indeed the national interest.  In the latter, in particular, its role in Australian political life is to lead (along with other mainstream parties) the debate about the future of Australia.  This is a role that single-issue groups and non-party Members of Parliament find difficult to achieve.  A Parliament of independents could of course deliberate and vote, but in the course of so doing, would probably begin to develop "tendencies", or meetings of like-minded people, and eventually to caucus, and even to form a party.

The electorate's apparent fascination with independents like Pauline Hanson who, despite her enormous media coverage, only commands (a word used advisedly) around 5 per cent of opinion poll support, is clearly a sign of frustration with the apparent powerlessness of government to deliver all that the electorate wants.  It is highly unlikely, however, that independents will ever play more than the classic role of "populist", delivering to the voter, in Ronald Reagan style, tax cuts and no reduction in services but a blow-out in the budget.  In any case, such opportunities only arise in the circumstance where the independent has the balance of power, and then is used not so much to veto government policy, but to exchange a vote for a reward to the Member's constituency, as is the case, for example, with Senator Harradine.

The challenge for Labor and the Coalition is that their membership is now so small that they cannot pretend to be mainstream in terms of their base, but must remain so in terms of voter appeal.

The issue arises, who, if not the narrow band of members, is to select the candidate for party endorsement?  If the electorate at large is to choose, for example through a system of primaries, then apart from the practical difficulties of requiring party registration, many of the advantages of the party system are likely to be lost.  The disciplines imposed by parties, for instance by the threat of dis-endorsement, or more positively the protection afforded Members of Parliament (because voters respect the strength of parties that are united), act as a restraint on populism.

The ability of a party to provide support to Members in the face of elector criticism is, especially for anyone interested in economic reform, a crucial part of the democratic process.  To diminish that instrument is to diminish the instrument of government itself, and is clearly not in the interests of the advocates of long-term economic reform, even that section of whom seek smaller government.

Who now owns the ALP?  Is it just a brand name consisting of professionals running the show for their own purpose and using considerable public funds to boot?  In this regard the National Committee of Inquiry Report, which was established following the 1977 election, reads as a remarkable premonition of 1997.  The constituencies it identified for special attention are, because of the way they were handled, the very ones that hastened its demise.  For example, the ethnic component of the party has been so well-entrenched that it is difficult to have a debate on immigration or multiculturalism without the fear of reprisal.

The pre-selection of Martin Ferguson for the inner-Melbourne seat of Batman was a clear signal from the National Executive that the branch-stacking based on ethnic minorities had damaged the party.  In terms of organisation, the ethnic "bubble" had burst when the ethnically-correct Labor candidate for Wills was twice defeated by the independent, Phil Cleary, following the retirement of Bob Hawke from the seat of Wills in 1992.  Despite Wills and Batman consisting of a large number of voters of non-English-speaking background, this did not translate into a solid ethnic Labor vote, nor should it have been assumed.

The feminists' hold over Paul Keating (though not the party), was quite out of character for him and still unexplained as to its force during the 1993 election.  The announcement of improved child-care subsidies to working mothers (and fathers) during the campaign brought such a swift and loud howl from mothers at home, that the subsidy was immediately broadened to incorporate all parents.  This episode brought home the distinction between women's views and feminists' views.  Although Labor did bridge the gender gap:

it was not Labor's 1993 campaign that was essentially attractive to women, but the level of women's support for Labor in 1993 was mostly due to ... gradual changes over time. (32)

In organisational terms, Labor has struggled mightily to incorporate more women in its parliamentary representation, especially following the 1994 Conference decision on affirmative action.  But the electoral tide proved more powerful than affirmative action, with a large number of Coalition women being elected for the first time, and few Labor women being re-elected.  While this is more bad timing than bad organisation, the failure to recruit women to the Labor ranks is a difficulty that may be overcome in time, but the number of young men who have spent 10 or more years working away at securing a seat are not going to give way easily to new female participants.

While any political party can be subject to takeover, that should not imply that the ALP is but a franchise, a product that prospective candidates can purchase before running for election.  One test of this thesis is whether a reasonable proportion of candidates shop around, in other words, have been a member of another party.  The Australian Candidate Study (33) casts doubt on the thesis, reporting that, of 434 candidates at the 1996 election, 97.2 per cent of ALP candidates had never been a candidate for another major party (Liberal, National, Democrat).  The figure for Coalition candidates is 90.9 per cent if those swapping between Liberal and National are included.

The ALP's decline from mass party status has been a long time coming.  "In 1939, 53 in every 1,000 Australians was an ALP member:  now [1991] less than 3 in every 1,000 is". (34)  The extent of the ALP's claim to be a mass party died at the time of the "split" in 1957 and the loss of members to the DLP and elsewhere.  In the years of falling numbers, there was a flight of activists to other parties and movements.  To that extent the party has often been a training ground or staging post for political activists.  Of course, the period 1983-1996 was extraordinarily difficult for the party because so much that members understood to be policy was jettisoned.  Many accepted the changes (and many did not) in the belief that the party had a responsibility to the nation.  So part of the fall in numbers in the period was as a direct result of incumbency.

The decline in party membership is not just confined to the ALP.  Senator Minchin has voiced his doubts about the Liberal Party's legitimacy, with its membership in South Australia declining from 30,000 to 10,000 in the last 20 years. (35)

The loss of the ALP's status as a mass party warrants some change to its structure and processes.  In a mass organisation, public scrutiny is not essential, as sufficient numbers are involved to lend legitimacy to the organisation.  In a smaller party, though, legitimacy must be proved by ensuring open and visible processes.

If legitimacy has been diminished with the decline in numbers of each of the major parties, then one way of restoring it is to ensure that important party processes, like policy-making and candidate selection, are open and visible.  If the voter can see how policy is formulated, and how candidates are selected, the gain will be considerable.

The pivotal role of the branch member is to form part of the electoral college for pre-selection.  Other roles like engaging in debate for the purposes of policy formulation, and for fund-raising are more local affairs to assist the candidate or act as a sounding board.  They do form an important part of electoral feedback, but in the main the relationship is more teacher-pupil than delegate-advocate.

On the question of candidate selection the ultimate step may well be legislation on party plebiscites and scrutiny by the Australian Electoral Commission (discussed elsewhere by the author) (36) as is the case in union ballots.  The use of primaries is another, though somewhat extreme variant, but with the amount of public funding for elections and for the reasons of legitimacy stated above, these ideas are likely to gain currency.

The policy process must also be subject to public scrutiny, and as a by-product become more democratic.  ALP national conferences have, since the 1979 conference, been very public, as Labor leader Bill Hayden remarked:

For a decade now, the Labor party has been concentrating on broadening its structures and opening them more and more to public scrutiny. (37)

This was especially so when the National Committee of Inquiry Report (38) noted that the basic structure of National Conference had not changed since 1902, and called for a larger and more representative body with direct representation of party members.  The former has been achieved but not the latter.  The conference has doubled in size during the 1983-1996 period, and is a showpiece of Labor policy-making in action.  It is not, however, built on the direct representation of unions or branch members.  It retains its federal structure with most delegates being elected in teams from State conferences.

Unfortunately, National Conference is totally beholden to the factional system based in each State.  The recommendation of the National Committee of Inquiry, (39) that delegates be elected by and from federal electorate organisations, was roundly rejected.

This highly centralised and restricted form of representation of the National Conference is a major road-block to policy formulation in the years ahead. (40)  The best way to revitalise debate -- and public faith in the debate -- in the Labor Party is to allow competition at electorate level for positions at National Conference.  Although this solution does not guarantee a broader range of views, and has been raised before, (41) it would not only send a powerful signal to the membership that they can make a difference, but to the public that the ALP represents mainstream interests.  This process could become the equivalent of the "primaries" in the USA parties, in this case with application to policy rather than pre-selection.

The added element in the ALP's role is its link to the trade unions.  Despite the occasional call to sever the links between the ALP and the trade unions, to do so would simply deprive the party of a great deal of organisational support and income.  Rather than distance itself from a very important part of its base, the ALP should ensure that the representation is open, democratic and adequate.

Unions have a large degree of power over State conferences, not only because of the mandated proportion of delegates to which they are entitled, but also because those delegates invariably vote as a block.

The trade union influence over the ALP would be modified if union delegates to party conferences were elected by the union membership directly, rather than hand-chosen by the secretary in the time-honoured, winner-take-all manner.


POPULATION POLICY

Besides changing its structure and processes the Labor Party needs to construct a new coalition of forces that will not only bring it to power but also sustain the national purpose.  The key goals of a decent standard of living for the greatest number, and the social cohesion of the society must be realised on a sustainable basis, that is, by protecting the environment.

Irrespective of advances in non-polluting and resource-efficient technologies, there is a correlation between damage to the environment and the number of people using it.  Australia will make a far better fist of protecting its environment if there are fewer people using it.

If the one responsibility a government has to its constituents is to look after them, then the sustainability of a population is critical.  There is a convincing body of evidence suggesting that Australia needs a population policy;  that governments need to start thinking about stabilising population growth.  The debate echoes calls from an earlier period, best explored by Charles Birch, who concluded that "Australia has a particular responsibility to establish a stable population, to maintain its own quality of life and to use its resources to raise the quality of life in neighbouring countries." (42)

The largest element of current population growth amenable to government control is immigration.  To follow the argument of Cocks, (43) Australia should try to stabilise its population as soon as possible.  He argues that this can be achieved by restricting the annual net migration to fewer than 50,000, in order to produce a stable population of between 20 million to 23 million by 2045.  The 1996-1997 net immigration figure will be about 50,000:  in other words, the policy of stabilising the population is readily achievable.

The ALP has recently released a discussion document (44) which indicates a move in this direction.  The recommendation to be presented at the next National Conference, is to seek a policy for a net immigration target of between 50,000 and 80,000 per annum which implies a population of 23-30 million by 2045.  These figures were based on a House of Representatives report, (45) and seek to obtain a mid-point between the report's "population stabilisation" and "modest growth" options.

The reasons for the current level of immigration are not the same reasons as when the policy commenced.  The original arguments about immigration -- for defence and to take Europe's poor and displaced after the wars, and as a stimulus to development -- are no longer valid.  The real reason is to win the votes of the immigrant community through the family reunion programme.

The defence and broader "populate or perish" arguments are now a nonsense.  Australia can never have sufficient population to be safe from invasion (should anyone wish to invade us) and there is no convincing evidence for economies of scale arising from a larger population, and so no reason on that score to keep growing.  The moral argument is looking shallow, not the least because Australia's intake of immigrants is so small in world terms, and because many of our immigrants have high levels of skill and are not the "poor" of the world by any stretch of the imagination.  Our humanitarian refugee intake is the real moral base of immigration and as such should remain.

Stephen Fitzgerald's 1988 report on the immigration programme (46) warned the government at the time that there was no convincing rationale for Australia's immigration programme, and as a consequence very poor public support for it.  The Australian population has overwhelmingly disapproved of the level of immigration to Australia under both Labor and Coalition administrations for many years.

That rationale is even thinner today.  The immigration and race debates of the past months and years have been horribly miscast.  The racial elements of the immigration debate are often raised as a defensive ploy by the supporters of immigration, which is a shame, because race has not been a serious element of the immigration debate -- in the sense that any major political party has advocated a racially selective programme -- for a generation.

To the extent that there is some racism amongst mainly working-class Australians, it probably arises because the working class live near new arrivals.  The middle class never get closer to a new arrival than a popular ethnic restaurant.  The working class, on the other hand, are confronted (many quite happily) with the disappearance of their own shopkeepers to be replaced by new unfamiliar names, products, language, signs and odours.

As Hage (47) observes, though, "people are racist one second and not racist another second, or racist or not racist at the same time".  This is simply the product of settling in with new neighbours, and is not a cause for serious disquiet as some would have it.

A level of immigration low enough to allow Australia's population to stabilise within a generation would allow the Labor Party to win significant support from its own blue-collar base, while at the same time maintain the support of the middle-class "post-materialists".  The ethnic lobby should not be at all insulted by such a policy because it is not an anti-multicultural move.  The only losers will be the branch stackers in the major parties who have used the ethnic communities mercilessly to build a power base.  A population policy could give Australians a rest from one set of policies being thrust at the electorate, and for the most venal of reasons.

Australia has been opened up to the world already, this is not 1945, and this is the next step in the population policy a full 50 years since the great waves of post-war immigration commenced.  While the number of new permanent residents in Australia measures in tens of thousands per year (60,000-140,000), the number of visitors and temporary residents is around 2.5 million per year.  In other words, the extent of Australia's interaction with the world is vastly greater than its immigration programme.  An immigration policy based on population stabilisation will not harm or even impede Australia's interaction with the rest of the world.

The number of Australians today who, on a regular basis, have significant interaction with other parts of the world -- through trade, tourism, cultural and sporting exchange -- is vastly greater (accounting for population size) than was ever the case at the height of our intake of migrants.

The politics of population policy may be difficult, but they will be overwhelmingly positive both in national interest terms, and most importantly will allow the "majority" to have a win, and to be seen to have a win.


FAMILY POLICY

There is quite another constituency to be regained for Labor, and that is the growing number of people who are struggling with the breakup of marriage and its aftermath.  The historian Laurence Stone observes that "the scale of marital breakdown in the West since 1960 has no historical precedent and seems unique.  There has been nothing like it for the last 2,000 years ..." (48)

Such events are not class-based.  Both rich and poor divorce, and fight just the same for the custody of children, and over the division of the assets of the marriage.  The change to family law, the no-fault basis of divorce and the recognition of each partner's contribution to the marriage are unassailable policies.  However, they have drawn government more than ever into the lives of more Australians and to some extent bring the purposes and standing of government into disrepute.

If votes change on the basis of strong feelings, then the response to the Commonwealth Parliament's Joint Select Committee on "Certain Changes to Family Law" (49) was a goldmine -- or perhaps just a minefield for politicians.  The solutions to these problems are not at all obvious, but there is a need to change the approach.

Especially following the passage of the Family Law Act 1975 and the development of the Family Court, government has sometimes been tagged as referee in the breakup of marriages and sometimes as perpetrator of broken marriages.  This is a position from which government can never win.  Government has to be in a position to assist individuals to sort out their own problems having first told them of the need for stability in family life, and the responsibilities for and pitfalls of failure.

This is not a regression into moralising, rather it is a signal that the government will attempt to protect an institution that is still overwhelmingly preferred as a living arrangement by most Australians.  Governments do not have to feel frightened of offending the singles as a constituency, or the women's movement who want women to break out of unsatisfactory marriages, or gays who argue for the legal recognition of their relationships.  Rather, it is reinforcing and being seen to argue the case for the importance of marriage, especially for the purpose of raising children.

Like the immigration debate, the first phase of policy has outlived its rationale and that rationale has now become a hindrance to a larger purpose.  So too with marriage or family policy.  The no-fault divorce laws (commencing in 1959 and enhanced in 1975), have achieved their aim of allowing partners to separate where necessary.  But the institution itself has changed.  Marriage has been strengthened as a more equal relationship but the "new" marriage requires stability for the sake of all those who enter it, and all those who want it to remain.

As Trainor states:

A divorce law should attempt to recognise both the liberal concerns that spouses should have the freedom to exit from marriages that they find intolerable and the conservative concern that divorce laws should protect and reinforce the stability of family and the framework of stability it provides for them. (50)

One of the most powerful statistics that argues for some further debate in family law, in addition to the considerable body of evidence that suggests that marriage is generally good for the well-being of both partners and their children, is that:

as many as 50% of men and at least 25% of women feel later that divorce was the wrong decision and wish they were still married. (51)

If one assumes that this is the regret of the initiator of proceedings then clearly a great deal of pain and money could be saved.  The questions are, whether government can achieve any success in this field, and whether the issue requires either more, or less, or perhaps just different, forms of intervention.

There are two valuable suggestions that deserve serious consideration.  Maley (52) seeks to amend family law in order to open up the possibility that proven "fault", or serious misconduct in a marriage, should influence the determination of the ancillaries of a divorce settlement.

An application for divorce would go ahead as now after one year's separation, and the divorce would be granted as at present.  However, a partner responding to a divorce application would have the option of charging the petitioning partner with serious misconduct or failure during the marriage and demanding that the Court should take this into account in determining the terms of settlement.

The other suggestion, by Edgar (53) does not seek to regain the former and formal significance of the marriage contract, but rather to acknowledge the contract as a contract, by way of insuring a better preparation for marriage.  He argues that since the one ground of breakdown in a relationship has been enshrined in law, it must be assumed that both parties contribute to that breakdown even if it is known not to be true and that, for instance, one or both are bad characters.  Edgar does not advocate a return to the notion of fault and acknowledges that there are criminal sanctions -- for example, for wife bashing, family violence and child abuse.  However, there are no legal remedies for the lack of satisfaction of a poor marriage.

Edgar's solution to what he calls the revolution of the rise in expectations of marriage is for a more sensible approach to marriage preparation and what might reasonably constitute a "good enough" marriage.  The way to encourage better preparation is to change the focus of the law from after separation to before the marriage contract is signed.  The law could make every couple intending marriage to work out in advance a "Marriage Agreement" that specifies which pieces of each individual's property will become shared assets, which will be excluded from it, and which pieces will be assumed to develop as joint property as a result of the agreed union.  Further, such a contract should be drawn up following a complete exploration of all facets of a married life including domestic arrangements, the care of children, and so on

Family law is in effect back to front, in the same way that marriage counselling is being put ahead of marriage education.  Few societies have allowed marriages to proceed without a clear understanding of who gains the assets of a marriage once the marriage is dissolved.  Being aware of the consequences of marriage is especially important in a society where traditional customs have been weakened or no longer exist.  Specific conditions for each marriage should be negotiated upfront to suit the diverse circumstances of couples who chose each other freely and on an individual basis.

There is a warning (54) of this contractual approach, that there might arise two forms of contract, a solid legally-enforceable private contract and a merely ceremonial legally-unenforceable public contract.  Nevertheless, these two approaches, one before and the other following the dissolution of marriage deserve serious discussion.  Once again, a political party should not be frightened away from the debate by those who believe they own the policy because of "wins" in recent years.  Marriage is at the centre of family life, and family life is an important part of the happiness of the nation.

Whether it is amenable to public policy intervention is debatable, but given that government and the law has its hands on the marriage contract presently, it is hardly breaking new ground to re-enter the debate.

What is more, a government should send a signal that it is attempting to bring stability to an important area of the nation's life, even if part of the reason is to provide an area of policy respite, knowing that further major changes will have to be made in other areas of public policy.


EMPLOYMENT

The area where much change is yet to be made is the Australian economy.  Unemployment is surely the root cause of enormous misery in Australian society.  All manner of problems arise with high levels of unemployment, from divorce, to poverty, to youth suicide.

There is a danger of a failure of resolve on the part of government to tackle the problem or to allow the employed public to accept the fact of high unemployment.

The key political value goal espoused in this paper is social cohesion.  The key political strategy is, in the two chosen examples, to give the majority a win on population policy (and reconciling the positions of the environmentalists and the majority), and a more stable approach on marriage (providing an island of policy stability).  This may then free some energy to re-enter the most important debate, ensuring that all those who want to work can.

The latest in a long list of estimates of the level of unemployment suggests that:

85% of the workforce are employed and living well as "insiders", 15% are unemployed, under-employed or disguised unemployed and poor "outsiders" concentrated in low social economic neighbourhoods marked by low labour force participation, high unemployment, poor educational achievement and poor health. (55)

Dorrance and Hughes argue that unless fundamental policy changes are made speedily, the insider proportion of Australia could be reduced to 80 per cent, leaving 20 per cent, or one person in five, to be poor outsiders.  These words echo Langmore and Quiggan:  "... about three quarters of a million people who would like to work are unable to do so." (56)  But Langmore and Quiggan suggest solutions at vast variance to those of Dorrance and Hughes.  The former argue that there is no shortage of jobs that need to be done, and advocate a major expansion of employment in publicly-funded community services.  The latter advocate a broad agenda of micro-economic reform, in order to improve the productivity of labour and capital.

So who to believe?  Is the "problem" caused by unions or capitalists, does the solution lie in the dictates of rational economics, or in overthrowing them?

The broad elements of the debate over the economic future of Australia have been fairly and reasonably encapsulated by Argy (57) with respect to a long-term economic strategy, including the national debate on savings. (58)  It appears that there are clear directions and disciplines which will have to be undertaken by Australian governments so that each of the intermediary objectives -- such as sustainability of low inflation, high levels of savings, and speedier growth -- are to be achieved.  Within that framework, and placing to one side the logic of being able to buy the nation's way into full employment which appears to be the major argument of Langmore and Quiggan, Labor has to ask itself what particular part it can play in achieving the goal of sustainable full employment.  Further, it has to answer that question in a manner that does not appear to be adverse to the interests of its own constituency.

The most trusted approach has been through the Accord process, the agreement between the Labor government and the peak trade unions which, in its many manifestations, sought to break the links between prices and incomes.

The prices and incomes policies devised by Labour parties have now had a very long history.  British Labour Prime Minister Harold Wilson (59) made much of the idea during the term of his governments, though Labour in Britain could not implement a successful prices and incomes policy before they fell to Margaret Thatcher's conservatives.

In Australia, it was the work of Sheehan (60) amongst others, who introduced some plans for a local version of a prices and incomes policy.  The terrible experience of the Whitlam Government's attempts to control prices, in return for wage control, damaged relations between Labor and the union movement.  Bob Hawke, as president of the ACTU, was the architect of the wagerise push seeking to compensate workers for the sharp rise in prices being experienced at the time.  While no incomes policy could have coped with the sharp rise in prices in the period in question, a successful one may have mollified the worst excesses and consequences of that period, the massive level of unemployment which followed and continues today.

As Sheehan argued, all governments have an incomes policy just as they have budgetary or monetary policies -- the trick is to devise a successful one.  Debate will ensue about whether Labor's 1983-1996 Accords were successful.  At the very least it ought to be conceded that incomes policy is a feature of all government policies.  Even the minimal interventionists may concede that it is better to have another "lever" of economic policy than not.

Labour market reform, essential to the achievement of full employment, is a difficult policy area for Labor, as it appears to require having to ask more and more of its own constituency.  Nevertheless, it is on each party's shopping list of policies required to solve Australia's economic problems.  Hughes's (61) work on achieving full employment gives a high priority, among many other areas of market reform, to the system of wage bargaining in Australia.  That priority must be maintained, but the important new element is that Labor needs to join another constituency to the task.  The small business constituency now so large, and when snubbed even by its own side (Hewson in 1993) so powerful, must be joined by Labor to create a new Accord.

By way of example of one element of a future incomes policy, labour costs are a significant and all too obvious cost to small employers.  The former Labor Government's own Green Paper on full employment posed the hard question,

are we prepared to reduce constraints to business expansion, such as disincentives to hire people ...? (62)

This was the same issue raised by Treasury Secretary Ted Evans in 1993, (63) when he spoke of the high level of unemployment as being a matter of choice.  The importance of the price of labour as a cause of high unemployment is hotly disputed by some, (64) and indeed labour cannot be equated to other commodities, but the operations of the labour market are vastly important to job creation, and wealth creation, and they fall squarely in the policy backyard of the ALP.

Incomes policies have traditionally attempted to gain the benefits of freeing the labour market or lowering labour costs without causing either short-term discomfort to the employed or transitional costs to the unemployed.  A paper from EPAC, (65) and work in progress at the Full Employment Project (66) suggest that, amongst other factors, labour on-costs may be a significant cause of unemployment.  On-costs, such as payroll tax, workers' compensation, redundancy payments, and superannuation have increased in relative importance, rising from 11.6 per cent of wages and salaries in 1986-7 to 13.1 per cent in 1993-94. (67)  These figures are significant as they are not costs that can generally be negotiated in return for productivity improvements, and as such are moving against the desire to have a closer fit between productivity and reward.

While the control of wages would be less possible in the future and incomes policy, "can at best deliver changes in money wages rather than real" (68) (real wages, not nominal must be adjusted to clear the labour market), it is nevertheless true that it is a choice as to whether some costs are loaded on to the employer and therefore built into the decision whether to hire labour.  If, as Hughes and many others have argued, that "payroll taxes penalise employment", (69) then it is likely to be true for other costs such as superannuation.

The policy option of seeking to reduce real labour costs is hardly fair on the workforce, or industrially feasible.  It is better to work on improving the productivity backing those costs.  There may be scope, however, for taking certain on-costs out of the employment contract altogether, as was the case with money wages under the Accord processes.  The purpose of such a move lies in the recognition that such costs dampen the demand for labour.  Whether these costs shifted to the general taxpayer ultimately represent a real reduction in labour costs is debatable.  It depends on the degree to which the costs rebound through increased taxes.

The aim of the exercise is to use a political mechanism that may achieve an outcome not feasible by other, more direct means.  The wages of the lower paid are in effect subsidised now by means of the Family Allowance system.  Allowing wages to adjust in order to clear the market can be achieved in a number of different ways.  Surely the best is to employ individuals in jobs where there is demand and to do this by removing some of the direct cost of employment.

The costs of employer superannuation contributions will have a major impact on employment in years to come, particularly for the marginal employee.  It has become a real cost of employment that need not be carried by the employer.  The achievement of a compulsory near-universal superannuation system was a major achievement of the Labor government, but the particular means of its implementation was somewhat accidental.

The labour movement has already accepted the political costs of apparently low wage increases through the Accord, but a dose of wage realism under the Coalition should provide the Labor Party with the political ammunition to re-enter this area of debate.  It is certainly worth exploring the potential to employ more Australians by means of a further Accord, specifically an agreement between Labor in government, the union movement and the small business community.  Such an Accord must ensure that all the good being done on the savings front in the new superannuation regime not be undone by acting as a disincentive to employ.  Of course, the small business constituency will jump at the chance to shed some costs if someone else will pay for them.  The unions will probably agree to shifting costs elsewhere so long as the move does not shift money into the pockets of employers or result in a diminution of income by other means, for example by higher taxes.

Superannuation for the marginal employee must be paid through the budget, paid for by taxation revenue.  Of course the public will have to pay the bill, but that is what Accords are for, to ensure that a deal can be delivered that no taxpayer would vote for if put to them directly, but which, subject to further analysis, holds the potential to employ more Australians.

There are a great many areas of reform in the Australian economy that are being undertaken in order to make Australian industry more competitive.  An agreement to shift the cost of employing people onto the public purse should not disturb the drive for efficiency, but for a given level of demand for goods and services may enable more Australians to be hired.


CONCLUSION

Labor has drifted from its base constituency, and at the same time that constituency has changed.  Labor needs to devise policies, and to change the way it conducts its business, in order to win it back.  The message from the 1996 election is that Labor appeared to govern for a collection of minorities who were changing the face of Australian society in unacceptable ways.

However, as a responsible future government, it cannot afford to avoid issues that are necessary to reform Australia's economy.  Labor in government will have to continue to change the face of Australia against the apparent interests of most voters, but the task will be made easier if it can concentrate on some areas that address the interests of the majority -- population and marriage policy are two key examples -- and to use some old tools, like incomes policy, where it can ease the transition to full employment that a harsher deregulatory agenda may not be able to do alone.

It will need to re-join the environment debate through population policy, re-cast the ethnic alliance, provide a stable direction in marriage, and join the small business constituency to the task of job creation.

Labor in Opposition needs to bring new legitimacy to the party, but above all, it needs to be brave enough to at least have the debate.  After all, that is the reason most people join or vote for a political party.  But there are other good reasons why someone would join the ALP:  in order to advance the causes in which they believe, and where the tradition of social democratic thought offers a solution;  because its policy and candidate selection processes are open and subject to public scrutiny;  and, that it can provide a training ground for political activists.



ENDNOTES

1.  Jim Hagan, The History of the A.C.T.U., Longman Cheshire, 1981, page 45.

2.  Brian McKinlay, A Documentary History of the Australian Labor Movement, Drummond, 1979

3.  Dennis Altman, Rehearsals for Change:  politics and culture in Australia, Fontana/Collins, 1979.

4.  Australian Labor Party, National Committee of Inquiry:  report and recommendations to the national executive, March 1979.

5.  Bill Hayden, Hayden:  an autobiography, Angus and Robertson, 1996, page 571.

6.  Marcus Olson, quoted in Alan Tapper, The Family in the Welfare State, Allen and Unwin and AIPP, 1990, introduction.

7.  Gary Johns, "Courting Problems in the Quest for Bill of Rights", The Australian Financial Review, 21 August 1995.

8.  Malcolm Mackerras, General Election 2 March 1996:  Statistical Analysis of the Results, Unpublished paper, page 1.

9.  Mackerras, op. cit., Table 6, Table 2, Table 3.

10.  Gary Johns, "Cult of Rights Rejected", The Age, 4 March 1996.

11.  Barry Jones MP, "Notes on Election Defeat", unpublished, 29 July 1996.

12.  Lindsay Tanner MP, "Building an Inclusive Society", paper delivered to Fabian Society Conference, Melbourne, 28 July 1996, page 9.

13.  Simon Jackman and Gary N. Marks, "Forecasting Australian Elections:  1993 and All That", Australian Journal of Political Science, Volume 29 (2), July 1994.

14.  Barry Jones op. cit., lists 34 problems for Labor, the most important not already mentioned in the text are -- community anxiety, accumulated grievances, isolation of the leadership, economic recovery encouraged mood for change, Carmen Lawrence's Penny Easton affair, foreign debt, caucus lacked courage to criticise the leadership, change fatigue, eroding role of government, the 1993 budget.

15.  Laurie Ferguson MP, Transcript of Australian Federal Election Symposium, 15 April 1996, Centre for Corporate Public Affairs, Melbourne, page 29.

16.  Bob Hogg, Transcript of Australian Federal Election Symposium, 15 April 1996, Centre for Corporate Public Affairs, Melbourne, page 30.

17.  Hugh Mackay, Reinventing Australia:  The Mind and the Mood of Australia in the 90s, Angus and Robertson, Sydney, 1993.

18.  Hugh Emy, "Cracks in the Polity:  Reflections on the Federal Election", Australia And World Affairs, Number 29, 1996, page 9.

19.  Mark Latham MP, "Social Inclusiveness in an Open Economy", Australian Fabian Society Conference, Melbourne, 28 July 1996, page 3.

20.  Haydon Manning, "Why Labor Won the 1993 Federal Election:  an Unconventional View", Policy, Organisation and Society, Number 7, Summer 1994.

21.  Nick Economou, "An Overstated Electoral Importance?  A Note on 'Ethnic' Voting and Federal Election Outcomes", People and Place, Volume 2, Number 4, 1994.

22.  Ian McAllister and Clive Bean, Long Term Electoral Trends in the 1996 Election, unpublished, June 1996.

23.  David Kemp, Society and Electoral Behaviour in Australia, University of Queensland Press, 1978.

24.  Andrew Robb, "Lessons from the 1996 Campaign", The Sydney Papers, Autumn 1996, page 107.

25.  Andrew Robb op. cit., page 108.

26.  Mark Latham op. cit., page 10.

27.  McAllister and Bean op. cit., pages 2 and 4.

28.  Hugh Emy, From the Free Market to the Social Market:  a new agenda for the ALP?, Pluto Press, 1993, page 15.

29.  Gough Whitlam, "Gough's Call to Arms", The Australian, 10 February 1997

30.  Andrew C. Theophanous, Understanding Social Justice:  an Australian perspective, Elikia Books, 2nd edition, 1994.

31.  Peter Beilharz, Transforming Labor:  labor tradition and the labor decade in Australia, Cambridge University Press, 1994.

32.  Gary N. Marks and John Mitchell, "Explaining Labor's Win at the 1993 Australian Federal Election", International Journal of Public Opinion Research, 1994, Volume 6, Number 3, page 258.

33.  Australian Candidate Study 1996, Social Science Data Archives, August 1996, page 2.

34.  Ian Ward, "The Changing Organisational Nature of Australian Political Parties" Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, Volume 29, 1991, page 156.

35.  Senator Nick Minchin, "Debating pre-selection reform in the Liberal Party ...", in The Paradox of Parties, Marian Simms ed., Allen and Unwin, 1996, page 62.

36.  Gary Johns, "Party versus Conscience" in Ethics and the Public Sector, Allen and Unwin, forthcoming.

37.  Bill Hayden, forward to, Brian McKinlay, op. cit.

38.  ALP, National Committee of Inquiry:  op. cit.

39.  ALP, National Committee of Inquiry.  op. cit., page 45.

40.  Australian Labor Party, Platform Constitution and Rules, 1994, pages 319-321, outlines the structure of the National Conference.

41.  Gary Johns, "The Extension of Democracy" in The Socialist Objective, edited by Bruce O'Meagher, Hale and Iremonger, 1983.

42.  Charles Birch, Confronting the Future:  Australia and the World:  the next hundred years, Penguin, 1975, page 150.

43.  Doug Cocks, People Policy:  Australia's Population Choices, University of NSW Press, 1996.

44.  Duncan Kerr, MHR, Population Policy, paper released on 12 August 1996.

45.  House of Representatives Standing Committee for Long Term Strategies, Australia's Population Carrying Capacity:  One Nation-Two Ecologies, AGPS, December 1994.

46.  Stephen Fitzgerald, Committee to Advise on Australia's Immigration Policies 1988, Immigration:  A Commitment to Australia, AGPS, Canberra.

47.  Ghassan Hage, "Race Crisis a Myth", Weekend Australian, 9-10 November 1996, page 6.

48.  In Alan Tapper, op. cit., page 261.

49.  Select Committee, On Certain Aspects of the Operation of the Family Law Act, 1995, Commonwealth of Australia.

50.  Brian Trainor, "Why Australia's Divorce Law Should Be Reformed", Policy, Autumn 1992, page 26.

51.  Patricia Morgan, "Conflict and Divorce", page 73 in Home Repairs:  Building Stronger Families to Resist Social Decay, Centre for Independent Studies, 1996.

52.  Barry Maley, Wedlock and Well-Being, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy Monographs No. 33, 1996.

53.  Dr Don Edgar, "The Certainty of Uncertainty:  Let's Aim for Equity and Live with That" paper delivered to the 7th National Family Law Conference, October 1996.

54.  Brian Trainor, op. cit., page 29.

55.  Graham Dorrance and Helen Hughes, Divided Nation:  Full Employment and Unemployment in Australia, The Full Employment Project, September 1996.

56.  John Langmore MP and John Quiggan, Work for All:  Full Employment in the Nineties, Melbourne University Press, 1994.

57.  Fred Argy, A Long Term Economic Strategy for Australia, an interim Report for CEDA, Longman Cheshire, 1992.

58.  Fred Argy, "A Review of the National Savings Debate", Business Council Bulletin, Number 129, April 1996.

59.  Harold Wilson, Final Term:  The Labour Government 1974-1976, Weidenfeld & Nicolson & Michael Joseph 1979.

60.  Peter Sheehan, Crisis in Abundance, Penguin Books, 1980.

61.  Helen Hughes, Achieving Full Employment, The Full Employment Project, Discussion Paper No. 1, 1994.

62.  The Prime Minister's Committee on Employment Opportunities.  Restoring Full Employment, Green Paper, Issues Brief, December 1993, page 22.

63.  Ted Evans, reported by Gerard Henderson "11 Percent Unemployment:  A Matter of Choice", Commercial Issues, The Sydney Institute, Spring 1993, page 3.

64.  Will Hutton.  The State We're In, Jonathan Cape, London, 1995, page 99.

65.  Dan Dao, Office of EPAC, "A Model of Unemployment".  Background Paper No. 12, Prime Minister's Committee on Employment Opportunities, December 1993.

66.  John Freebairn, The Full Employment Project, Research Workshop, unpublished, University of Melbourne, November 1996.

67.  Freebairn, op. cit., page 7.

68.  Dan Dao, op. cit., page 20.

69.  Helen Hughes, op. cit., page 21.