Sunday, July 25, 1999

Time is Ripe for Debate on Ethics

Wrongdoers will always exist.  So regardless of how many rules of conduct or codes of ethics are in place, at some stage most organisations and institutions are likely to discover a certain amount of sleaze in their ranks.  The really important issues are whether it is easy to bring such mischief to light, and what happens to those who are found out.

The motivations of the people who expose the mischief don't matter much.  Perhaps, as John Laws is suggesting, the ABC Media Watch story about his squalid arrangement with the banks went to air only because "small spiteful people" were filled with "a desperate desire to make something of their lives by crawling out of their gutter" to destroy the king of talkback radio.

But if so, then more fool Laws.  If he really believes that his opponents are totally consumed with envy of his success, he should have taken even greater care to avoid situations which might provide the means that would allow such people to pull themselves "out of their gutter".  He may have convinced himself that his behaviour raises no ethical concerns, but it certainly raises questions about his own good sense and understanding of the Australian public.

And maybe the person who leaked to the Media Watch team holds a grudge against the Australian Bankers' Association, or some other outfit associated with the scheme to pay Laws a handsome sum to rethink his opinions about the banks.  Corporate restructuring often produces disgruntled employees, and a confidential memo about an underhand $1.2 million scheme would present a wonderful opportunity for someone to really vent their spleen.

Positive social benefits may result from disagreeable motives, just as the most high-minded aims can lead to disaster.  No doubt John Laws and the banks would like to discover the identity and intentions of the whistle blower;  but for the rest of us such information is unlikely to change anything.  The crucial issue is the relationship between Laws and the Australian Bankers' Association, and that seems all too clear.

I am not convinced that it is really necessary to have six separate enquiries into the matter.  Whatever their outcomes, the credibility of John Laws has been severely wounded.  He may still be able to entertain his audience and brighten up their day, but his chances of convincing them that they are getting reliable information and candid opinions are not so good.

And while the banks were obviously suffering from the bashing that Laws had been offering to his two million listeners before the deal went through, there are now many millions more people who have serious and justifiable doubts about the ethical basis of the banks' business practices.  So just as politicians became much more careful about their expenses after the travel rorts affair, a great many corporations and broadcasters will be drawing some clear lessons from the present scandal.

But the most important lesson is that our system of democratic institutions, a free media and market oriented corporations ultimately provides a pretty good safeguard against deception.  It may take a little time -- a few months in the present instance -- but clandestine schemes designed to mislead have a habit of coming to the surface.  And when they do, the costs to those involved are often very much larger than the benefits they were originally intended to bring.

In other words, it is not difficult to achieve reasonable standards of ethical behaviour even in a society where saints are thin on the ground.  What is necessary is the existence of effective mechanisms to channel and balance human self-interest in ways which will convince potential sinners that they are likely to do serious damage to themselves if they behave badly.

However, others have attempted to draw different lessons from the Laws affair.  The Media Watch program has clearly proved its worth in this case, so some are arguing that the ABC and other government-funded institutions need more resources.  But they forget that a desire for money is not the only root of wickedness, and that fraud and deceit are not confined to private enterprise.

One prominent academic writing in the southern press even suggested that private funding inevitably corrupts public debate, and attempted to tar think tanks such as the Centre for Independent Studies with the John Laws brush.

But I never made any secret of the fact that my financial backing comes from a wide range of individuals and companies, including banks, the mining industry and other important sectors of the Australian economy.  The funding is structured to ensure that no company or sector is in a position to exert undue influence over my activities, and all major publications are vetted by outside experts.

Certainly, there have been a few occasions in the past when financial supporters have indicated that they would like me to take a certain position on a particular issue.  But such requests have always been resisted.  This is not because I am necessarily more virtuous than my righteous opponents.

Were I to allow the expectation of funding -- or the threat of its withdrawal -- to tempt me into changing my arguments and assessments, this would eventually come out into the open, and I would be finished as a researcher and a commentator.  These considerations apply to any public intellectual, and especially those which ruffle feathers by challenging the fashions of the intelligentsia.

Nevertheless, all citizens, irrespective of their social or political beliefs, have an interest in ensuring that promises of money, power, or other inappropriate rewards are not used to obtain a particular opinion from a public commentator.  By unintentionally causing such a serious issue to come out into the open, John Laws and the Australian Bankers Association have done us all a favour.

Wednesday, July 21, 1999

We all lose when opinion is for sale

The John Laws affair is likely to bring about a revolution in talk-back radio akin to the "payola" scandals in US pop music stations.  Under "payola", pop music disc jockeys were being paid by their ostensible employer, the radio stations, and again by the record companies to put particular pieces to air.

Talk-back radio is a highly influential shaper of public opinion.  For whatever reason, the talk-back hosts have obtained a credibility beyond that of any other public personalities.

To survive and flourish, firms need to be well regarded by their customers.  The powerful personalities of the airwaves can destroy or shore up that public perception.  This offers the talk-back hosts an "opportunity" -- and it offers a route for a firm to hire a secret gun in order to undermine a competitor in the market.

Business is both a victim and a promoter of these unethical standards.  It also has to deal with a plethora of well-resourced anti-business advocacy groups.

The media need to do more housecleaning.  If business feels that its opponents are given lots of automatic free kicks, the temptation to engage in hidden funding must increase.  But business must also realise that what it does now can come back and haunt it later.  In a deregulated environment, it is no longer enough to merely stick to the letter of the law.  It must build its own long-term relationships with the public and appropriate interest groups -- something which the banks, in particular, coming from a previous environment of pervasive regulation, have not been good at doing.

Media Watch has disclosed practices which need to be exposed and that many business people have been fighting against.  The furore over the Laws affair contains its own remedies.  Public exposure of the truth and public condemnation is an appropriate sanction.  Australia does not, however, want the heavy hand of government -- not a disinterested party -- regulating in detail media-third party interactions.

The publicity of the Laws case demonstrates the potency of democratic institutions in combating misuse of the media.  The blowtorch of publicity offered by a free press, even if it is in a feeding frenzy on the issue, will doubtless provide its own remedy.  Business, chastened by the counter-productive outcome of the ABA/ Laws deal, is likely to be more careful in defining the line beyond which advertising and PR become unethical payments.  The talk-back host and the media, anxious to maintain or restore their public image, are likely to tighten the terms and conditions under which they conduct their business.

Robert Manne's article, "The Opinion Business", on this page yesterday, opens a further dimension to the issue.  Manne associates me with talk-back hosts' practices.  He seems to be saying that private-sector funding inevitably pollutes an analyst's views.  Robert Manne originally came to public prominence through his editorship of Quadrant, a privately-funded magazine.  (The Age, indeed all other newspapers, are also privately funded).

Manne's suggestion that only government bodies are capable of purveying the truth is a ludicrous reversal of the truth -- government monopolies on media are a prescription for tyranny.  Government media monopolies are the antithesis of a free press.

In fact, the lack of diversity of views in government-funded universities, which are themselves increasingly seeking private-sector funding, creates the need for public intellectuals like myself.  Indeed, Manne acknowledges my integrity and credentials as an expert who is not likely to be hired by most university departments because I offend their own Politically Correct agendas.  My work is independent of my funders.

I go to great lengths to keep research activity separated from funding.  Like The Age, I put procedures in place to ensure my views are not coloured by my funders' interests.  It is only by such efforts that public debate can be kept where it belongs -- concerned with logic and evidence, not money and personal attacks.

I often pioneer changing opinion.  Accordingly, I have to be more rigorous in my marshalling of facts than those simply promoting established beliefs.  My funding base and resources are modest.  My influence lives and dies on my arguments.  I am as threatened by the buying of opinion as anyone -- a society of bought opinion has no place for public intellectuals.

Tuesday, July 13, 1999

Property Rights and Competition Policy

Address to Industry Economics Conference 1999
Melbourne, 12 July 1999


PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE ECONOMIC GROWTH PROCESS

The conditions that led to England and other parts of Europe suddenly increasing their income levels from the end of the seventeenth century have rightly occupied great attention among economic historians.

There has been much analysis of its causes -- the Protestant Ethic, climatic conditions and the overthrow of feudalism have all been cited.  Many of these aspects had an importance but the overwhelming cause, painstakingly documented by Tom Bethell (1) was the security over property rights that the English and later other Europeans enjoyed.  Secure property rights allow basic human goals to be pursued by allowing those who are successful, frugal or hard working to enjoy the benefits without having to share them.

Though referred to in other contexts, including by Marx, the industrial revolution as a phenomena that occurred in England was only named as such in 1880, by Arnold Toynbee.  For its roots we go to John Locke, whose writings described the highly unusual restraints on the political power of English kings and nobles.  Henry Bracton, a judge in the fifteenth century wrote, uncontroversialy, "the king must not be subject to any man but to God and the law."  And added "for there is no king where will and not law bears rule".

One is reminded of the "Mad Max" film where Tina Turner had established herself as the potentate of a primitive island of brutal civilisation.  She was obliged to allow Mel Gibson to go free after prevailing in mortal combat because the Law required it.  Perhaps the scriptwriters were unaware, but they had happened on the circumstances where commerce could take place, namely the rule of law rather than, as is the case in dictatorships, the rule by law that upholds the interests of the ruler rather than of all.

The English Civil War marked the attempt by the Stuart kings to assert power over property which the common law had defined gradually since the thirteenth century.  The issue remained open until the Glorious Revolution of 1688 finally confirmed Locke's views on the sanctity of private property from royal takings.  And it was only after 1688 that Locke's work was published under his name in England.  (Prior to then, in a version of the present day phone tap, Locke's dining hall conversations were monitored by government lip-readers).

Although property rights had been generally accepted elsewhere in Europe, in England the security was greater and more extensive since it also included tenants' rights.  One nation with similar property rights was Holland, which however was an early victim of loss of competitiveness to England.  The Dutch were unable to run their empire as frugally as England and paid an average level of taxation three times that of England.

The early economists talked little of property rights as a means of generating wealth, largely because those rights were so entrenched that they were taken for granted.  The first of Smith's Lectures on Jurisprudence (1760 but not published until 1978) stated "the first and chief design of every system of government is to maintain justice:  to prevent members of society encroaching on each others' property, or seizing what is not their own."  The Wealth of Nations itself was more concerned with the division of labour and free trade.  Jean-Baptiste Say, writing in 1803, probably spoke for the whole profession when he wrote that only with secure property rights "can the sources of production ... attain their utmost degree of fecundity", a truth he regarded as "so completely self-evident that demonstration is quite superfluous." (p.98)

In this, he was echoing something long familiar to the ancient philosophers.  Aristotle noted that

What is common to the greatest number gets the least amount of care.  Men pay most attention to what is their own:  they care less for what is common.  (Politics, Book II, Chap 3.)

From the middle of the nineteenth century until quite recently, economists have tended to regard property rights as secondary.  Of course Marx was the great example but even within the mainstream, there came to a view that property ownership was irrelevant.  JS Mill described the distribution of property as of little material importance in the economic growth process.  Marshall, his heir to leadership of the profession, codified marginal analysis and hoped that individual property would be less important in the future.  And the founders of the American Economic Association in 1885 wished to create a society that would build a theory to assist in the development of the new more moral world that they foresaw.

The ultimate verdict on the impossibility of economic prosperity without secure, individually owned property rights had to await the fall of the Berlin Wall ten years ago and its immediate aftermath.

As early as 1944, Hayek had predicted the economic decline and loss of liberty that would follow from socialism, but he was a footnote to most of the profession.  In the meantime, the study of law and economics at the University of Chicago under Coase, Stigler, Posner and Alchian was restoring the importance of property rights to economic analysis.

The central theme of the Coase theorem was that, with trade, externalities could be internalised by re-assigning rights.  This would allow efficient solutions.  But this was pregnant with even greater interventions -- the government would re-arrange property rights so that the most efficient party was granted them.  In fact, in the past, common law judges had not determined cases on the basis of efficiency, which was Posner's extension of the Coase Theorem, but on the basis of making property more secure more easily tradable and encouraging competition.  It was the incidental effect of this that has enhanced economic efficiency.

While the failure of the centrally planned socialist economies demonstrated the importance of property rights and the rule of law at the economy-wide level, the success of privatisation demonstrates the potency of individual property rights at the level of the individual firm.  The study of some 1370 firm-years by Dewenter and Malatesta (2) shows that private firms have a superior return on assets (actually over twice the return).  In addition, the data shows that returns on assets and equity increased more rapidly for firms that were privatised than had been found in the period prior to privatisation.  This latter finding is important because governments normally take energetic steps to improve the management of state-owned firms prior to privatisation.  In doing so, they will have already implemented of the most easily won improvements.


COMPETITION AND REGULATION

PROMOTING COMPETITION AND ASSAULTING REGULATION

The potency of competition has long been a, and probably the, dominant tenet of economics.  The Smithian values turned on free trade in what was then a major idealogical dispute with the mercantalists.

It goes without saying that the debate was never completely won.  The world shifted from a free trade area to one of autarky after 1914 and saw a considerable reduction in living standards.  We should not assume the inevitability of the advances in free trade we have enjoyed since 1945 will continue.

Free trade was one aspect of commerce that England in its internal market enjoyed over most of continental Europe.  But allowing competition to bring increased income requires more than free trade.

Trade impositions are only a sub-set of the regulatory restraints that can stifle the economic growth process.  Here again, the experience of the English economic take-off is useful.  The 200 years to the 1870's marked a systematic culling of laws and regulations.  Of the 18,110 Acts passed since the Thirteenth Century, over four-fifths were repealed.

Building upon a reform perspective that dates back to the early years of the Hawke Government, Australian Governments have sought to reduce regulatory impediments to the efficient operations of business.  Prime Minister Hawke, addressing the Business Council of Australia in September 1984, said:

I am convinced that after eighty-four years of federation, we have accumulated an excessive and often irrelevant and obstructive body of laws and regulations.  We will examine critically the whole range of business regulation, most importantly with a view to assessing its contribution to long term growth performance.  We will maintain regulation which upon careful analysis, clearly promotes economic efficiency, or which is clearly an effective means of achieving more equitable income distribution.  And we will abandon regulation which fails these tests.

The dominant theme running through this quotation was to "excessive and irrelevant regulation".  This offered a clear signal favouring deregulation -- perhaps the clearest such signal previously given by an incumbent Government in Australia.  But it was tempered by an agnostic view that some regulation promotes economic efficiency and that some regulation may be a justifiable means to the promotion of equity in income distribution.

Following the Hawke initiative, regulation review units were set up in the Commonwealth and most States with a view of arresting and reducing the plethora of regulatory barriers to the supplier/consumer interface.  Insufficient powers and resources were given for these regulation review watchdogs to have a major impact.  But the initiative marked a change in attitude of government intervention in the economy.  Previously government leaders had largely taken the view that their actions were unambiguous in bringing benefits.  The initiative recognised that the sand thrown in the wheels of commerce by governments was itself often the problem.

In this respect, the Hawke initiative echoed, albeit palely, the reforms that underpinned the economic take-off that we call the (English) industrial revolution.

In Australia, most areas of intervention of governments in business decisions have been much reduced over recent years.  Social regulation over standards, pollution and the like has tended to mount but the regulation of businesses through tariffs and subsidies, and directions to offer services, has been much reduced.  The net position has been little change in the explosive growth in regulation, which is illustrated in the chart below.

REGULATION TO PROMOTE COMPETITION

There are two areas where regulation has been increased, ostensibly on the basis that increased regulation is necessary to promote competition.  One is access to monopoly services.  The other is regulation to control mergers of firms where this may bring diminished numbers of rivals.

Since stable property rights and competition are the twin engines of prosperity, is there a role for government to intervene to promote competition?  If such a role exists, it is necessary to:

  • examine where there might be a conflict between the exercise of private property rights and the assurances of workable competition;
  • determine, if such a conflict occurs, the criteria for overriding property rights;  and
  • establish institutional arrangements that generate the minimum of waste and paperburden costs in addressing the issue.

While competition undoubtedly generates increased efficiency, will government intervention select the appropriate competitive model?  And will it lead to the diversion of entrepreneurial energies into avenues that are unproductive?

The Control of Natural Monopolies or Essential Facilities

The notion of essential facilities is both elusive and subject to change.  In the US, the regulatory authorities have ceased controlling AT&T as it has become clear that there is ample competition in what was once thought to be an archetypal essential facility.  By contrast, in Australia the ACCC is urging Telstra to offer access to its network on terms it does not favour.

The most entrenched monopolies -- perhaps the only ones with durability -- are those supported by government.  The central purpose of the Australian competition reforms was to smash these.  In part, this meant hiving off the clearly contestable part (e.g. generation of electricity).  What is left is a set of residual apparent monopolies covering wires, pipes, ports and roads.  Most of the recent policy debate has focused on the price and access conditions for then use of these facilities.

With perfect knowledge, the wise and incorruptible bureaucrat could devise a transmission system that would prevent monopolistic waste and could also bring about a great many of the dynamic gains achieved with commercial rivalry.  However, these conditions are not present.  Producers and carriers will be reluctant to reveal to competitors and customers alike the extent of their costs;  and they too have imperfect knowledge of these.  Buyers will seek to keep options open to the maximum degree, and will not reveal the full extent of their demand, their alternative means of having it supplied and their preferred means of supply.

While government should, in the interests of economic efficiency, insist on certain access rules for its own facilities, it must be careful not to impose these on private facilities that are already in existence and that were built under different contractual arrangements.  Government seized monopoly powers when it built or nationalised its own facilities, but private firms often built them without a monopoly.  And if a private firm took risk and placed itself in a situation of commanding some market power because of its success, to penalize it by denying it the ability to profit from this will deter other such entrepreneurial activity.

In this respect please allow me the indulgence to quote from a paper I wrote for EPAC some years ago before the importance of property rights had assumed the mini-revival we have seen over the past few years.  In that paper (3) I argued,

... all business decisions are based on the prospect of obtaining a residual income from the capital, labour ad other inputs that comprise the goods and services that are sold.  The lure of these rewards is the energy source for economic efficiency.  Unless totally unexpected and not envisaged to be repeated, measures that bring the attenuation of these high profits diminish the pursuit of promising but risky opportunities.  This diminution is to the detriment of economic flexibility and efficiency.

It is from fears of the deterrent power that requiring open access might entail that the "Efficient Components Rule" was devised.  This gives firms forced to open their networks to competitors the profits they thereby forego.  That particular rule is not much loved by regulators and planners and its use may be specifically precluded by the Competition Policy Reform Act.  But as a specification of "fairness", it has far greater merit than a regulator determining what should be a reasonable return for a business to earn, and therefore price at.

Requiring private firms to provide access to competitors or others will diminish their incentive to build a facility or will distort the nature of that facility if built.  Well-established property rights are, however, consistent with open access at a commercial price.  For example, it is generally agreed that patents which assign ownership to ideas and products encourage innovation for the benefit of all.  Access of such ideas and products can then be arranged under mutually accepted licensing agreements.

The requirement for open access to these facilities might have perverse effects both on the competitive process itself and on economic efficiency.  Some entrepreneurs will want to have greater control of the sources of supply and the throughput of the facility than would be permitted under open access.  Either they would build a sub-optimal facility so that only their own booked capacity is transmitted, or they may be discouraged from building any facility, with consequent loss of additional supply to the market.

Even when the private owner had been granted a monopoly by the Government it should not be lightly taken away.  Where a government has created a property right through mandating a shortage the excess profit is often capitalised and sold.  Sound government, even in cases like taxi plates where the monopoly right is clearly a contrived one, should compensate the monopoly owners if it wishes to disturb their monopoly in totally unpredictable ways.

Using Competition to Bring About Optimal Access Conditions

With regard to wires, ports and pipelines, we can say with some certainty that the lowest consumer prices and the optimum production rates will be achieved if there are many customers competing for the capacity and many independently owned producers vying to supply those customers.

The Hilmer recommendations (4) rightly focus upon the importance of competition in bringing about a more efficient and productive economy.  Government should do everything possible to prevent its own agencies and institutions from inhibiting this process.  This means abandoning exploitative monopolies in the form of utilities and outlawing procedures that create barriers to commercial entrants or prevent the full force of competition.

The codes covering access and pricing to gas and electricity networks are subject to requirements on price and access that presume they are monopolies.  Yet recent events have demonstrated the potential for active competition in this area of supply.  Even with electricity, in Victoria rival distributors are planning to drive new lines into each others' territory.  Further evidence of the potential is observable in the skill that AGL has shown over many years in setting its NSW pipeline charges at a level that allows it to profitably ward off rival facilities.  AGL has responded to competitive threats by reducing prices in areas where those threats have greatest potential.

The nightmare for a utility business is that if it adopts too hard-nosed an approach to pricing and service, it will invite competition and leave the existing asset "stranded".  Fear of having "stranded" assets means that little by-pass is likely to eventuate.  But the control over excess prices that competition brings does not require that a competitor physically emerges.  Contestability for the market is quite adequate.

Competition or contestability is much superior to regulation.  Indeed, the regulator's role is to make judgements that, in his view, correspond to those that would emerge in a competitive market.  The problem with a regulated price is that it is likely to bring distortions.  If set too high, and the facility is indeed a monopoly, excessive prices will shift customers towards activities and expenditures that offer less value than would be the case with market determined prices.  Of course, if the facility is not a genuine monopoly, prices set too high are irrelevant because competition will force them down to market determined levels.  If prices are set too low, competition will be pre-empted and the facility owner will have inadequate incentive to properly maintain and expand the system.

A well-structured competitive regime on wires and pipes would ensure that all barriers to entry were removed and that the incumbent businesses were unable to block new rivals.  The New Zealand regime operates very successfully in this way without any price regulation (the breakdown of electricity supply into Auckland in early 1998 was unrelated to this feature).

If any price cap is to be set, it should apply only to those areas that were connected at a subsidised rate for community service reasons.  Ideally, a subsidy should be paid from general revenue but it could be made a condition of sale where the facility is privatised (with the government therefore accepting a lower sale price).  For the rest, the initial price should be established as if contracted at present levels, with downward pressure on incumbents' prices provided by rival suppliers.  After all, customers have willingly connected at the present price and suffer no disadvantage from the status quo.

No facility -- at least no facility unprotected by government franchise -- has untempered monopoly powers.  Many facilities can be by-passed and almost all others supply products, like gas, that compete with electricity.  That facilities have an element of natural monopoly is not cause of itself for the suppression of property rights.  Nor is it incompatible with the concept of access for others' product.  Where excess capacity exists, access can be marketed at a price which reflects the tremendous level of capital and expertise necessary to construct a large-scale system.  The alternative to a market based on the assignment of property rights may be significant under-investment in the gas sector, at a significant loss to suppliers and consumers.

Auctioning the Right to a Monopoly Facility

Should it be determined that only one pipeline facility is economic and there are many suitors for that pipeline, one option is to auction its approval.  The selected supplier is the one offering the lowest charges or other benefits.

This is an option favoured by the gas Code.  While more market oriented than most options, there is seldom a situation where several suitors would be available unless the opportunity to build the pipeline has been previously suppressed by government regulation.  And if a proposal is to be opened to tender by those who did not spot the opportunity in the first place, the incentive to search for new ways to profitably meet consumer requirements will be reduced.


CONTROL OF MERGERS

The Regulatory Framework

The other arm of competition policy covers takeovers and mergers.  These fall under the control of the ACCC.

The form of natural monopoly that was the harbinger of contemporary merger laws was monopoly obtained by entrepreneurial excellence.  The US Sherman Act 1896 was targeted against the Rockerfeller dominance of kerosene as much as against railroads.  In the case of the former, the monopoly lasted for only a few years before new oil finds in Texas and Iran brought a great many new competitors.

The pattern of constant technological change and increasing openness that characterises the world economy calls into question regulations that combat merger activity.  Markets are constantly redefining themselves, with market players spilling over into areas that would once have been considered unrelated diversifications.

Earlier concerns that a business could obtain a stranglehold on a market have been blunted by the ability of rivals to move into each others' territories and international firms to offer services once the preserve of locally domiciled concerns.  These same pressures are forcing suppliers to look at economies in production, marketing and systems to obtain savings so that they an better compete.

Draft Merger Guidelines were published by the ACCC's predecessor, the Trade Practices Commission in November 1992 (5) following a change in the law that widened the ambit of oversight from one that focused on dominance to one that looked more closely at the ability of merged entities to exercise any form of market power.  The Draft Merger Guidelines specify "safe harbours" where mergers can proceed without ACCC scrutiny.  They also outline the criteria and procedures necessary to obtain ACCC clearance of mergers and takeovers.  The Industry Commission (6) considered these Draft Merger Guidelines to be too onerous, time consuming, excessively focused on consumer price benefits and likely to inhibit efficiency enhancing mergers.

In performing its duties, the ACCC must be alive to the twin building blocks of efficiency:  competition and property rights.  It must be conscious of the incentive firms have to seek higher profits -- economic "rent" to some -- and that such activity is harmful only where there is a monopoly that cannot be challenged.  Monopolies of this nature are very rare indeed.  It used to be said IBM was in such a position but the US Justice Department abandoned its decade-long litigation against the firm only when it was clear that its monopoly had disappeared under the avalanche of new rivals.  Even firms in a dominant position must behave as though they are subject to competition as long as the market is open to competitors.

Some Issues in Australian Controls of Mergers

Although fewer than 10% of the 150 or so mergers examined by the ACCC each year are opposed in a formal sense, others "voluntarily" change the terms and conditions from those initially preferred.  Still other possible acquisitions are not contemplated due to the known hostility of the ACCC.  In part these perceptions stem from some high-profile decisions of the ACCC that have indicated a strong ideological position regarding mergers.  The ACCC has tended to oppose mergers even where strong efficiencies have been demonstrated reduce competitive pressures on firms or in favour of using mergers to force their proponents to provide rivals greater competitive opportunities.  Some of these are examined below.

Westpac/Bank of Melbourne

The ACCC received a lengthy submission seeking clearance for a merger between the two banks on 15 April 1997, some twelve days after the merger proposal was announced.  It announced its decision on 25 July 1997.  During this time the customer uncertainty at the Bank of Melbourne (BML) resulted in a considerable loss of business and the two entities were pressed to agree to the Commission's requirements.

In its examination of the proposed merger, the ACCC addressed six features of the banking market:  deposits, home loans, personal loans, small business banking, credit cards, and transaction accounts.  Each of these market segments was addressed from the ACCC perspective of whether the segment was a state or national market.  The criteria used were the ACCC "safe harbour" rules which allow a merger to proceed if:

  • the merged entity comprises less than 40% of the market;  and
  • the combined market power of the four largest firms is less than 75% of the market or where the four largest firms had more than 75% of the market, the merged firm had less than 15%.

In terms of overall matters, the existence of four major banks and a great number of smaller entities competing in the various segments should have been assurance enough of continued robust competitive conditions, as the Bank of Melbourne's market share was less than 2%.  However in different segments, especially on a State basis, that share would be much more significant.

By considering the market as State based, ACCC managed to define two of the six segments as crossing its threshold.  Thus, although the two entities each only had 9% of the Victorian deposit market, this was sufficient to cause "concern".  Similarly, although the merged entity had only 20% of the Victorian transaction accounts, "concern" was again triggered.

On the basis of these findings, the ACCC obtained s87 undertakings, which included:

  • maintaining significant local decision-making autonomy;
  • maintaining BML's extended trading hours;
  • preserving the entitlement of existing transaction account customers to fee exemptions (subject to certain qualifications);  and
  • granting access to their electronic networks by new and small Victorian competitors for their Victorian customers for a reasonable period.

These measures represent an imposition on the parties of the ACCC's preferred competitive paradigm.  They cannot be said to represent the outcome of normal market processes.

It is hardly the role of the ACCC to dictate to businesses how they should manage their hierarchies.  Requiring local autonomy might offer some comfort for the Melbourne-based staff of BML but management decision making is surely the function of the firm's executive.  It is not apparent that the ACCC has expertise in corporate organisational arrangements and would surely not claim such qualifications in respect of a commercial organisation.

It is also not clear why the ACCC should require the former BML branches to remain open on Saturday mornings.  Longer banking hours offer benefits to consumers but these are traded off by business organisations conscious of costs.  It might have been no less appropriate for the undertaking to require all the merged branches to open on a Saturday morning or open for even longer hours.

Similarly, requiring the entity to maintain particular conditions for small depositors is an unfortunate intervention in business activities.  Such decisions should be based on commercial considerations.  If the ACCC thinks them to be appropriate it should require all financial institutions to follow them.

Perhaps the most egregious undertaking is that which requires the payment system to be opened to other competitors on terms that are not considered commercial by the owners.  On one plane, payment systems so opened allow more competitors and brings lower costs.  But there are considerable investments in devising such systems.  If owners of a successful system are forced to make it available to competitors, this reduces the incentives to take the risk of building it in the first place.  Firms will await the activities of their competitors and free ride (or cheap ride) on systems that turn out to obtain strong market acceptance.  Innovation will be the casualty.  In this and other respects, the ACCC makes the mistake of assuming a system is in place and then seeking that its owners allow full use of it by others.  The short term gain to competition is a long-term loss to incentive.

Ampol/Caltex merger

In its consideration of this merger, the ACCC forced the parties to offer undertakings on:

  • sale of certain terminals in major cities;  this provision was made even though there were already independently owned terminals in Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth owned by major businesses and the cost of new terminal construction is only $10-20 million;
  • to supply at least a billion litres of petrol per annum on reasonable commercial terms to independents;  and
  • to sell at least 35 metropolitan and 15 country sites.

There were concerns (7) expressed about:

  • the high level of concentration in refining;
  • refinery exchange agreements (swaps) and borrow and loan arrangements between the majors that allowed each a presence in States where they have no refinery capacity;
  • vertical integration of the majors;  and
  • the subsidisation by the majors of low retail margins through high refining margins.

High concentration.  The ACCC has recognised that Australian refineries are old and under-sized.  Minimum efficient size is thought to be at least 200,000 barrels per day and may be closer to 300,000.  The largest Australian refinery is 120,00 barrels per day and the total demand would accommodate little more than one world-scale refinery.  In fact, the concentration in refining is clearly too low for an efficient industry.  This is a matter that has recently been highlighted by rumoured merger talks between Shell and another major.

Refinery Exchanges and borrow-and-loan arrangements.  The Commission's objection to these seems to be twofold.  First, they fuel suspicion of a cartelized industry.  Second, they are not normally available to businesses other than those with refining capacity in Australia.

As for the first of these objections, it would seem that if a cartel were operating, it has been highly ineffective.  The profits of the oil industry are very low.  Moreover, the classic signs of a cartel -- stable market shares -- are absent.  The borrow-and-loan arrangements have been acknowledged by the ACCC's consultant, C.E. Hyde, as contributing to greater competition by allowing a presence in each market (ACCC, 1996, Inquiry into the Petroleum Products Declaration, vol. 2, AGPS, Canberra:  Appendix O.)

As for the second objection, the rationale behind the co-operative arrangements needs to be understood.  If the swaps were to be arranged through the financial system they would attract a taxation penalty.  Firms without an ability to offer reciprocal arrangements offer no advantage to those with refining capacity.

Vertical integration.  The decisions on whether firms seek to control their production through to retailing is one based on their views of efficiency.  Firms that adopt such an approach often see benefits of ensuring a consistent consumer image of the firm, to allow more effective integration of promotional campaigns, and so forth.  Commonly, such strategies are combined with franchising to fuse the overall policy with a greater enterprise which is often shown by small business.

The majors' subsidisation of low retail margins through high refining margins and strategies to constrain independent operators.  The ACCC has apparently come to a view that the majors act in collusion to pursue particular strategies designed to squeeze out opposition.  Professor Allan Fels, Chairman of the ACCC, stated that the proposed merger would result in a substantial lessening of competition, would bring "unilateral" price increases and facilitate "tacit and possibly explicit collusion", and higher retail prices.  He went on to state that there was little if any prospect of independents supplying petrol, (8) an astonishing statement since it was made at a time when independents (mainly supermarkets) were making massive incursions into many markets across the world.  The subsequent entry of Woolworth's into the Australian market was claimed as an outcome of the ACCC's market engineering.

The ACCC justifies its position in the petroleum industry by (unsubstantiated) claims of collusion.  Its determination concerned a market where there are clear inefficiencies caused by inadequate scale, a long history of price regulation and regulation of vertical integration, and very low returns on investment.  It is also a market that has seen the exit of some of the world's largest businesses as a result of poor profits.

The subsequent entry of independents using imported product was greatly facilitated by the regulatory arrangements forced on the incumbents, in particular the limitations on ownership of retailers, a limitation exacerbated by the ACCC determination, and by requirements to supply competitors on terms and conditions not necessarily to the liking of the refiners.

The ACCC in effect tilted the playing field in favour of new competitors, new competitors that did not even have a claim to legitimacy for such treatment that they are small businesses.

Australis/Foxtel

On 14 October 1997, the ACCC announced that it would block the proposed merger between Foxtel and Australis Media.  Australis Media had secured access to a key library of Hollywood movies but had done so at a high price.  It had been attempting to merge with Foxtel (a joint Testra/Murdoch business) for the previous two years but the ACCC had prevented this.

The ACCC claimed the merger would have given the entity a high market share.  The outcome of the decision was to place Australis Media in bankruptcy.  The loss of a significant market player occurred in any event.  But the shareholders in the company and what the Chairman of the ACCC referred to in a press release as "American junk bond holders" (who had $US375 million at stake) sustained losses.

The Chairman of the ACCC was reported as saying it was not the ACCC that caused Australis to have problems but the fact that it paid $184 million to acquire pay television licences and extremely high prices for their film material.  Professor Fels was reported as saying (Australian, 6 May 1998) that with a combined Foxtel/Australis "there was a real possibility that Optus (the main rival) would have disappeared from the scene".

The upshot is that the ACCC made a determination that the structure of the market required it to take action to ensure that one player, Optus, was not swamped by another.  Determining that specific firms should continue in business is a very bold decision for a regulator to make.  Sacrificing the interests of one set of shareholders to those of another requires the wisdom of Solomon.  Moreover, the market for pay-TV is one with a great deal of fluidity.  The content competes with other outlets (free-to-air TV, video stores and the general entertainment industry) and is characterised by very rapid market and technological change (it is likely that means of fast downloading film material through the Internet will provide meaningful competition before any of the present participants are operating profitably).

Different Policy Approaches to Mergers

Competition is not an end in itself:  it is valued because economic experience tells us that, as a rule, competition is the best way to maximise the community's welfare through enhanced efficiency.  Mergers allow economies to be made.  They allow sharing of production and marketing overheads and the rationalisation of facilities.  They therefore make possible improved efficiency.

In the USA, anti-trust activity has undergone a transformation.  In the past, the focus was on firms that dominated industries, although some decisions shifted from the targeting of firms that dominate industries to one that examines the likely impact on consumers.  There have been many examples of merger proposals that have been disallowed have covered some very minor parts of an industry.

In general the US approach has focused on the degree of concentration in markets.  A measure of market power, the Hirfindahl-Hirschman index, first applied by the United States Department of Justice following its 1986 report on gas pipelines (see Laine (9)) has been used.  This takes as a proxy the existence of four similarly sized firms as providing a low risk of the exercise of market power.  The ACCC's "safe harbour" approach mirrors this.

However, this approach was largely abandoned soon after its adoption.  The US regulatory authorities took a relaxed view of all types of mergers following the growth in the influence of contestability theory which emphasised that any market power was likely to be transitory because it would attract competitors.  Such an approach is favoured in this paper.

More recently there has been a further development.  The 1998 Economic Report of the President includes a major chapter on merger policy that indicates a more selective and possibly more interventionist approach.  An article "The Economics of Antitrust" in The Economist (2 May 1998) offers some insights into why this may be so.  The article points out that markets such as that for soft drinks, dominated by just two firms, are intensely competitive, while firms in others where there is apparent high degrees of rivalry and few entry barriers can be interpreted to exhibit market power.

In line with the Economic Report of the President, the US Department of Justice has now moved to a model that examines the case for blocking mergers on the basis of the likely effects on price.  By examining scanner based price information in markets where two competitors are close substitutes, and comparing the outcomes in regions where they both compete compared with outcomes where that competition is absent, the likely immediate effects on consumers can be seen.  In one case, concerning the merger of two firms that were market leaders in white bread, the merger was disallowed on these grounds.  In another case, Bell Atlantic and NYNEX, a merger was permitted to proceed even though the combined firm would have a dominant share in a major market because an examination of the likely actions of rival firms indicated that the dominance would be subject to challenge.

While the "safe harbour" basis of action adopted by the ACCC is clearly highly inflexible (and recognised as such by the ACCC, which supplements it with other criteria) its replacement by an approach which examines likely price outcomes is also unsatisfactory.

Regulatory measures to forestall price increases in markets may detract from efficiency.  Where two firms are engaged in cut-throat competition, the outcome will often be that one is driven out of business or exits the particular market segment.  A merger of two such firms can avoid this outcome and restore normal profits in a less socially wasteful manner.  Accordingly, it is incorrect to oppose a rationalisation of two business entities on the grounds that this might bring increased prices.  If lower prices are merely the result of a continued existence of surplus labour and capital forcibly retained within a production facility, improved resource allocation can be brought about by their shift to other activities.  In this sense, preventing the industry rationalisation is akin to imposing a high tariff to arrest a domestic industry contraction.  Although a tariff is designed to bring increased prices, and measures to prevent a rationalisation are designed to bring reduced prices, both can have the effect of establishing a larger industry than economic fundamentals would prescribe.

Hence, in effect actions to prevent rationalisations, especially where there are few entry barriers, are actions to force an enlarged industry and lower prices.  With respect to the latter, it is generally recognised that imposing price reductions on competitive businesses (or foreclosing price increases) will detract from efficiency:  for example, -- rent control has been demonstrated to result in a reduction in rentable properties.  Similarly, preventing a merger on the grounds that prices would subsequently rise seeks to lock firms into unsustainable positions, forcing them to treat their capital and marketing assets as sunk.  It is, in short, a veiled form of price control.

Contestability

Following Baumol.  Panzar and Willig's work (10), the notion of contestability has extended the realm within which regulation can be safely excluded.  The ability of a rival to take all the market from an incumbent is reason enough for the latter to behave as though competition was actually present.

Contestability has a particularly important role in areas that are subject to considerable innovation.  The ACCC has however taken a static approach to a number if issues that have come before it in areas where technological change is bringing great fuidity in the definition of a particular market.  These include the Australis Foxtel proposal.  They also include the proposal of Optus to buy AAPT a proposal which the ACCC indicated it is likely to reject because it would remove a vigorous competitor.  They also include the proposal of the ASX to buy the Sydney Futures Exchange on the grounds that this would create an undue concentration.

With these moves, the ACCC is discounting the value of contestabilty.  It is taking the view that the removal of one competitor will leave the merged entity free to rape and pillage.  In point of fact technological change and globalisation make this well nigh impossible.  The ASX has almost 100% of stock trades in Australia because it is cheap.  If it were not, we would very quickly see a rival foreign exchange offering its services.  It was its ability to exploit economies of scale and scope was stymied by the ACCC reaction to the proposal not its ability to exploit the consumer!


INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

Lippert (11) traces back the first ever patent to Florence in 1421 to Filippo Brunelleschi.  The invention, a loading crane, was granted because Florence wished to attract people of enterprise at a time of considerable commercial growth.  Its rival city, Venice, soon followed suit as did the German and Dutch trading cities.

The issue of intellectual property rights is the cynosure of regulatory intrusion into business with the attack on Microsoft and possibly Intel by the Department of Justice.  Who said attacking "tall poppies" was a peculiarly Australian art form?

With intellectual property rights, the two principles that have driven economic success -- vigorous competition for the consumer's dollar and firm property rights -- are in collision.  Property rights like patents and copyright entail a monopoly.  The artist or inventor is given an entitlement to the rewards others obtain from use of the patent or copyright.  The owner of the rights will be expected to milk them for all they are worth, the constraint on this being the willingness of consumers to forego purchases and the ability of the producer to exploit the different buyers' strengths of demand (the different parts of the demand curve).  The ability to price differentially is restrained by the ability of buyers to arbitrage between different prices, an ability that is massively increased by the internet.

Moreover, the ability to exploit monopoly profits with innovation is limited by the on-going existence of the technology that is being superseded.  In the case of computer software, although Microsoft faces considerable potential competition from a better system than Windows, the immediate constraint is the fact that almost all potential customers for Windows 2000, already have a perfectly good substitute in Windows 97, Windows 95 or even Windows 3.1.


FREE TRADE:  THE DEBATE ON PARALLEL IMPORTING OF COMPACT DISCS

As intellectual property is assuming increased significance in the goods and services we buy and in promoting economic growth its protection is assuming increased importance.  One issue to achieve prominence in this regard is that covering parallel imports of compact discs (CDs).

Although the issue of CD parallel importing (12) is frequently obscured by allegations of multi-nationals ripping off the consumer and artists, it is patently false to see the music industry as an oligopoly, even if that term were to be analytically useful.  There are half a dozen major and hundreds of minor suppliers of CDs.  The issue regarding compact disc is fundamentally about the conflict between property rights and competition.  It is about whether a producer may be allowed to place a caveat on the sale of her material to control its resale -- a denial of which forms an important part of the Trade Practices Act.

Compact discs can now be legally imported into Australia from any country irrespective of the wishes of those that hold copyright over them.

In the debate on this matter, the weight of the economics profession stood almost four square in favour of allowing parallel imports, that were previously banned.

By contrast to the views of economic commentators, the industry itself, including record artists, were united in favour of retaining a ban.

Effects of Allowing Parallel Importing

Allowing recorded copyright controlled material to be freely imported into Australia from any other country where it is legally sold, will doubtless place downward pressure on prices.  The fact is that in the absence of parallel importing, some material is likely to be priced higher in some markets than in others.  Freedom of trade will tend to equalise all prices, normally by bringing them down to those in the lowest priced market.  An article in the Australian Financial Review (13) estimated the wholesale costs of imported CDs to be 50-55 per cent of the cost of Australian-supplied disks.

The lower prices are unlikely to be in the best interests of the copyright owners -- if they can charge differential prices, they will obtain higher profits.  Although superficially attractive for consumers (once the market forces have pressured the initial importer to lower prices in line with costs) this may not be the best outcome for consumers.  Low prices are only one component of consumer demands and if they come at the expense of a constrained variety of offerings they may not be the preferred outcome.  One single car plant that fully exploited all economies of scale in turning out just one model would not necessarily be beneficial to consumers.

Any firm will seek to segment the market where it can and exploit the demand spectrum by charging a higher price to those with the greatest wish for their product and capability of paying for it.

We see this in a great many markets.  There need be no market power, as conventionally understood, to allow the exercise of price discrimination.  The "law of one price" normally prevails in open markets but suppliers faced by different demand curves for different market segments will often charge different prices.  Exploiting different demand profiles is known as Ramsey pricing and a long and uncontroversial literature suggests that it promotes efficiency.  The difficulty is defining the segments so that the discrimination can take place.

In charging lower prices in some markets, the seller will be keen to prevent higher charged customers migrating to these to take advantage of them.  This puts constraints on the ability to structure separate prices.  Yet we do find this taking place.  Thus, cinemas and hairdressers charge different prices for pensioners and children, (in the case of hairdressers, children are also more difficult to serve!).  By no stretch could the market for these services be said to lack competition.

Implications of removing the ban on Parallel Imports

Almost all products have an element of monopoly which is promoted by branding and differentiation from competitive products.  The objective is to earn greater profit.  There are practical constraints on the ability to price differentiate across markets as a result of internet ordering.  But why should an artist or inventor not try to obtain the best return for his or her product?  Although short term price reductions may follow from regulatory action forbidding this, over the longer term it will reduce returns to innovation and the amount of innovatory activity.  To put in place restrictions, we must therefore be taking the view that there is too much innovation.  This amounts to a new paradigm, which its proponents must justify.

Although the prevention of parallel imports could be seen as an infringement on free trade, it can also be seen as the protection of the property rights of those holding copyright.  Broadly speaking, any diminution of the property rights people hold will mean reduced incentives to develop the property rights in the first place.  This brings us back to Filippo Brunelleschi and the authorities in mediaeval Florence.

There are three directions for the increased revenues consequent on the ability to differentiate prices:

  • to individual record companies if they have some unique skills in pricing by market that are not available to rivals;  maintaining such skills to the exclusion of rivals is most unlikely and once rivals have the same skills, the benefits are passed either to:
    • artists with established reputations in greater remuneration or additional promotional expenditures;  or
    • artists with no reputation, who will see a greater likelhood of being offered contracts;  the potential returns from the cultivation of unknowns is made slightly greater by the abilities of the record companies to earn more revenue by price discrimination and more such risk taking by the CD producers will therefore take place.

In the absence of a cartelised industry, competition will mean the record companies do not earn super profits for their shareholders.  No matter in which of the other two directions the increased revenues can go in the longer term, they would be efficiency enhancing.

In fact, because the CD supply market is intensely competitive, any "rents" from price discrimination are likely to fall to the suppliers of the scarce goods:  namely the artists.  The artist has a unique product and is faced by many possible processors and marketers of that talent.  Why should he or she be prevented from seeking the best return for these creative efforts?

In addition to reducing income for successful artists, constraining the conditions of supply to prevent price discrimination reduces opportunities for new artists.  A CD producer has a great many options in promoting new acts and would lose money in nineteen out of twenty such innovations.  If producers are impeded from seeking to maximise revenue from their products, they must be more cautious in offering opportunities for new performers.  Accordingly, price reductions from intervening in market processes may bring a short term gain to consumers but will mean a future loss in diversity of output.

In many markets, the ability to segment offers opportunities to have that would otherwise be denied some goods affordable access to them.  In a recent case involving jeans, the European Court the denial of parallel imports to continue.  Levy's made in Bulgaria for the East European market were being exported into EC countries and undercutting the regular Levy supplied product.  The Court allowed Levy Jeans to prevent this resale of its Bulgarian jeans.  Levy were able to provide the product to Bulgaria at a marginal cost.  Had the firm been obliged to sell the product at that same low price worldwide, it would surely have opted to cease supply from the Bulgarian factory, to the disadvantage of Bulgarian producers and consumers as well as itself.

Thus the CD debate cannot be couched simply in terms of requiring freedom of trade.  It is also a conflict between the freedom of individuals to pursue their own interests versus one that would constrain that freedom in favour of competition.  The issue is, should an artist (through his agent the record producer) be allowed to retain control of his material after its first sale?  It is, after all her property and almost anything a regulator does to dictate its use will detract from its value to her.


IF IT AIN'T BROKE ...?

It might be argued that we, particularly in Australia, are currently experiencing faster growth than at most periods in our history and if there are deficiencies in our approach to property rights and competition policy they are not manifest in any concrete form.

I don't think we can afford such complacency.

Our present growth owes much to the reforms to competition, particularly the disaggregation of electricity, that had their incubus in the Keating Government.

With the reforms to competition policy introduced in 1995, previously sheltered industries in Australia have experienced a massive increase in productivity.  Gas and electricity have doubled their labour productivity in Victoria and other States have seen comparable increases.  Part of this is due to privatisation, but a major part was due to corporatisation, which placed the businesses themselves on a footing akin to private ownership.  These reforms offer a one-time boost, although they still have some juice left in them.

Another aspect of our improved circumstances has been the budgetary responsibility introduced by the Howard Government and in some State Governments.  Again, judging from recent Commonwealth and State budgets, the stomach for cutting growth sapping welfare expenditures seems to be abating.

Although we are growing at close to 5 per cent, that sort of growth and more should be easily attainable We should be doing much better given our expanding labour market and the shortfall of our measured living standards from those of N. America and much of Europe.

Moreover, we should remember that much of our growth has been on the back of capital imports, as indeed was our previous poor performance.  The counterpart of these is the current account deficit.  The deficit, running at some 5 per cent of GDP is cited by both Moody's (which has Australia on its third highest rating category) and Standard and Poor (which has it on its second highest) as reason for not further improving their rating of Australia.

There is, of course, nothing wrong with capital imports but they must be serviced and paid back.  Over recent years, the present level of capital imports has meant the nation's saving effort is reduced but, at some time in the future, that position will have to be reversed.


CONCLUDING COMMENTS

Deregulation has been accompanied by a considerable reregulation of certain aspects of business.  This process may be leading us into areas of inefficient resource allocation.

The most significant anti-competitive activity we need to fear in the medium term is that arising from government protected entities.  The most important competition policy issue is therefore the elimination of all (unjustified) legal restrictions and interventions in the market which give certain entities (whether wittingly or not) supernormal profits protected from the otherwise inevitable erosion of entry or threat of entry by other firms.  At the very least, there needs to be a critical examination of specific cases and an exit from oversight where competition or contestability is possible.

Enforcing open access on transport/transmission facilities and setting a regulated price on that access is likely to curtail the incentive to build new ones and give inadequate incentives for the maintenance of existing ones.  Other than where some NIMBY interest prevents any possibility of rival provision -- and it is difficult to envisage cases other than some airports that might fall into this category -- the authorities should take the view that the facility is contestable.  Regulation should be confined to requiring a price level that has been set in place by the de facto contract that prevailed prior to competition being allowed.  Competition should then be left to erode those prices that are excessive.

The treatment of mergers and competition policy generally derives from two basic precepts:

  • that competition brings dividends in terms of forcing increases in (allocative, productive and dynamic) efficiency;  and
  • that individual property rights protected by a stable legal system are essential if firms and individuals are to have the incentive to seek out gains from trade and innovation.

There are differences of view about the need for merger and competition commissions and the powers of those commissions.  These stem from a divergent emphasis on the importance of, on the one hand, the capabilities of regulatory oversight to provide superior outcomes, and, on the other, the power of markets to automatically correct serious deviations from a stereotype of "perfect competition".  This spontaneous correction is caused by the attraction of third parties to profitable opportunities.

As Deepak Lal (14) points out, the notion of a market equilibrium whereby there would be no economic rents or excess profits stemming from "market failure" is relatively modern.  There are myriad situations where firms extract higher profits from serving particular groups of customers or where they are able to price-discriminate to squeeze out more profits.  In one sense, these activities can be attributed to some degree of market power.  But to attempt to dismantle all such hurdles in pursuit of the chimera of perfect competition would extend the role of the regulatory authorities into requiring one price only to be charged by hairdressers, airlines, and building owners.  In doing so and denying sellers the right to exploit different market segments resulting from differing demand profiles, the regulatory authorities would require that some demand that could profitably be met goes unsatisfied.

Workable competition is the best we can ever achieve and, indeed, it is the lure of earning super normal profits that provides the stimulus to innovation and optimum usage of labour and equipment.  If mergers result in improved profits, which are their proponents' clear goal, this will often mean higher prices.  Attempting to ensure all players remain in an industry means it is ossified, frozen in a time when production and market characteristics allowed more players than can profitably compete at present.

The one unambiguous role for government is to ensure that its laws do not prevent new players from contesting a particular set of demands.  Beyond that, the attraction of profitable opportunities and the desire of consumers to obtain good value will conspire to prevent sustained price gouging on the part of suppliers.



ENDNOTES

1. Bethell, Tom, The Noblest Triumph, St Martin's Press, New York, 1998.

2. Dewenter K.L., and Malatesta P.H., State-Owned and Privately-Owned Firms:  An Empirical Analysis of Profitability, Leverage and Labor Intensity, March 1999, School of Business Administration, University of Washington Seattle.  This comprises an update of Public Offerings of State Owned and Privately-Owned Enterprises, Journal of Finance, 43 Feb 1997, p 275-298.

3. Property Rights and Efficiency:  Ownership of Innovations and Mineral Prospects, in Issues in the Pricing and Management of Natural Resources, Background Paper No. 16, Economic Planning Advisory Council, 1991.

4. Hilmer, F., M. Rayner & G. Taperell (1993), National Competition Policy:  Report by the Independent Committee of Inquiry, AGPS, Canberra.

5. Trade Practices Commission (TPC) (1992), Merger Guidelines:  Draft for Comment, Canberra.

6. Industry Commission (1996), Merger Regulation, Information Paper, Canberra, June.

7. See Hearings of the HoR Standing Committee on Financial Institution and Public Administration with Professor Fels Hansard, 21 April 1997;  Walker, J. & Woodward L. (1996), "The Ampol/Caltex Australia Merger:  Trade Practices Issues", Trade Practices Law Journal, Vol. 4(1), 21-48. (1996).

8. Ibid.

9. Laine, C. (1995), "The H-H Index:  A Concentration Measure Taking the Consumers' Point of View", Antitrust Bulletin, Summer, pp. 423-32.

10. Baumol, W., J. Panzar and R. Willig (1982), Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York

11. Lipert, O., Individualism, Intellectual Property and the Future of Capitalism, Fraser Forum, March 1999, p.8-10

12. This matter is addressed in detail in an article by me in Agenda volume 6, number 2, May 1999.

13. AFR 7, January 1999, Sanity Records may prevail in slowdown over CD retail prices, by Kath Cummins, p.6.

14.. Lal, D. (1997), "From Planning to Regulation:  Toward a New Dirigism", Cato Journal, Vol. 17(2), pp. 211-27.

Sunday, July 11, 1999

Preambulations

A Speech to Samuel Griffith Society,
Melbourne, 10 July 1999


Mr Chairman, Ladies and Gentleman.

A few months ago, John Stone rang me and gave me that most terrible of all possible speaking assignments.

He charged me with the task of being funny and witty about the Constitution;  a task not unlike being asked to discourse persuasively on the virtues of alcohol to a meeting of the Christian Women's temperance league.  Of course, at least on such occasion one could start by observing firmly in alcohol's favour that it was only by imbibing several glasses of medicinal ale that the task one was currently undertaking could ever be attempted.

To make matters worse, John Stone felt it perfectly reasonable to require me to sound intelligent on the subject while conscious of being followed in my presentation by Sir Harry Gibbs.

The full enormity of the task that John Stone felt free to load on me should now be obvious to everyone.  To be funny and witty about a document which reads, as Greg Craven once memorably said, like the deed of grant of powers it is AND be followed by Australia's most eminent legal mind, talking on the very same subject.

At this point, one is left racking one's brain about what terrible error or injury I had done that John Stone should feel free to visit this speaker's purgatory on me.  It certainly seems a punishment fitting to be inflicted upon some errant individual by a gentleman who was once famously described as eschewing any resort whatever to the knife in the back since he had always found the axe in the forehead quite sufficient.

One remembers at the time of the election of the Hawke Government rumours went around that they were contemplating moving John Stone from his position of signing dollar notes to being Secretary of Defence.  It was felt that, while Ministerial control of the armed forces might then be in doubt, civilian control at least would have been assured.

Now, as it happens, this is the second time I have been in a double bill with Sir Harry.  The previous occasion was when Sir Harry was kind enough to launch a book I had written.  On that occasion, I, fortunately, was the following speaker and, forgoing any attempt to match the preceding speaker, merely thanked him for his kind words and offered myself up for questions.

No such luck this time, I actually have to speak.

But then there is the great saving grace of this awful task.

I actually only have to be amusing about the proposed new preamble.

No real problem at all, then.  Indeed, it is such a little problem that I defy anyone not of the lofty eminence of Sir Harry to discourse for any length of time about the proposed Preamble without collapsing into some sort of laughter, drollery or uncontrollable merriment -- intentionally or otherwise.

If ever there was a thing of smokes and mirrors signifying, as all really good jokes do, at once far too much and yet nothing at all, it would have to be the proposed preamble.

Just consider the paradoxes.  First, there is something so important that we have to go through all the expensive and time-consuming, and relatively rare, effort of a constitutional referendum campaign to consider it.

Yet this something is so insignificant we are gravely assured that it will have no legal effect on anything at all.

Yet this thing without effect is nevertheless so important that the words of our unofficial poet laureate have to be amended for vital legal reasons.

Yet is it so unimportant that it need not bother with such elementary constraints as good English expression.

To discourse on such an object is to be landed, without effort at all, in the land of the surreal.  As strange a place as one can imagine, outside the Party room of the Australian Democrats.  Humour must inevitably follow, of some variety or other.

In fact, Natashas and Natashas of humour, which can but Lees one in huge Kernots of mirth before one can say "all change", like a carrot from its virtuous, noble raw untaxed nirvana to its nasty, shredded, fast-food, taxed purgatory.  But I have to Stott there, or I will Despoja the joke.

Australians, one is glad to say, have lived up to their reputation as folk who like a joke -- one has to have an advanced sense of humour to even pretending to give such personages as Philip Adams (Mr "I have a dream -- and you're not in it") or Robert Manne (our very own distaff Disraeli -- "is that two, or possibly only One, nation I see before me?") status as workaday Sages.  Indeed both display a standard feature of so many Australian commentators:  in the wonderful words of Jagdish Bhagwati about Chalmers Johnson, they refrain from permitting their contempt for their opponents' views to breed familiarity with what they actually say.

Australians have lived up to their reputation and realise that Preambulation is a game anyone can play.

Gareth had already offered his own thoughts of course, but someone who managed to show that too much reading of Biggles when young is dangerous even in the relatively un-aeronautical position of Federal Attorney-General can surely not be absent when nominations for Pomposity in a major national role are being handed out.

Jeff Kennett entered in, playing his long-running feature of anything-you-can-do-I-can-do-better and gave, one must say, a not discreditable performance.

The Democrats and the ALP got together and agreed on a version -- basically a few minor amendments to Gareth's original offering.  As we contemplate the joys of now-you're-in-now-you're-out exempt, but-only-when-we-say-so, food -- the Lees-Howard reprise of the well-known Kernot-Reith performance of the previous Parliament -- we have to conclude that anything cobbled together with the Democrats has to be a bad look.

And this one was agreed with the Greens as well, just for added (in)credibility.

What they came up with was

Having come together in 1901, relying on God, as a Federation under the Crown;

And the Commonwealth of Australia being now a sovereign democracy, our people drawn from many nations;

We, the people of Australia

Proud of our diversity

Celebrating our unity

Loving our unique and ancient land

Recognising indigenous Australians as the original occupants and custodians of our land

Believing in freedom and equality, and

Embracing democracy and the rule of law

Commit ourselves to this our Constitution.

Funny, I thought we were already committed to the Constitution, having voted it in by two rounds of referenda and considered no less than 42 amendment proposals since.  But more of that later.

The Australian newspaper, following its self-appointed role as definer of national identity, and perhaps continuing the role which led the late Paddy O'Brien to call it "The Daily Keating", decided that this was a task beyond, or perhaps beneath, its own august sages and threw the matter open to public competition.  Write your own preamble, our judges to pick the winner:  constitutional drafting as national game-show.  But "Do You Want to Be A Preamble Drafter?" was only a low-grade version, with more effort and much less money or fame than the prime-time original.

And they duly flooded in;  people's earnest, and not-so-earnest, attempts to express what they felt a constitutional preamble should say.

What is a preamble anyway?  In an Act, it is an expression of what the ensuing document is about.  In the words of the Macquarie Dictionary

an introductory part of a statute ... stating the reasons and intent of what follows

Which, of course, the current document already has.

WHEREAS the people of New South Wales, Victoria, South Australia, Queensland, and Tasmania, humbly relying on the blessing of Almighty God, have agreed to unite in one indissoluble Federal Commonwealth under the Crown of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland, and under the Constitution hereby established:

And whereas it is expedient to provide for the admission into the Commonwealth of other Australasian Colonies and possessions of the Queen:

Be it therefore enacted by the Queen's most excellent Majesty, by and with the advice and consent of the Lords Spiritual and Temporal, and Commons, in this present Parliament assembled, and by the authority of the same, as follows:--

Not great poetry of language, perhaps, but it has the great virtue of being true and, even better, not something even the most activist judge is likely to go into a legal frolic over.

Which is the great problem with adding a preamble.  It gives an added gloss on the document, it invites judges to interpret the words in its light.

At which point one contemplates utterly how surreal the whole thing is.  Because this must be the only time anyone has seriously suggested that the preamble should be added to a document a full century after it was written.  A sort of retrospective attempt to tell us what the whole thing was about as if, somehow, we didn't already know.

Then again, when we have a High Court which can discover in the Constitution, albeit with some shuffling back most recently, an implicit bill of rights no-one had noticed for over 90 years.  So perhaps retrospective allocation of purpose is perfectly reasonable.  Not surreal at all, merely cutting-edge legal theory finally getting its full run.

Or perhaps it is modern legal theory which is surreal.  A dream of the mind connected only in the most tenuous terms to any sort of reality.

Perhaps.

But what the preamble seems to be really about in people's minds is defining what sort of nation Australia is, or ought to be, or likes to think it is, or would like to be, or something.  An expression of national values but one, mind you, which has no legal implications, but is terribly, terribly important anyway.  Without actually mattering.

What did John Howard and Les Murray offer us?

With hope in God, the Commonwealth of Australia is constituted by equal sovereignty of all its citizens.

The Australian nation is woven together of people of many ancestries and arrivals

Our vast island continent has helped to shape the destiny of our Commonwealth and the spirit of its people.

Since time immemorial our land has been inhabited by Aborigines and Torres Strait Islanders, who are honoured for their ancient and continuing cultures.

In every generation immigrants have brought great enrichment to our nation's life.

Australians are free to be proud of their country and heritage, free to realise themselves as individuals, and free pursue their hopes and ideals.  We value excellence as well as fairness, independence as dearly as mateship.

Australia's democratic and federal system of government exists under law to preserve and protect all Australians in an equal dignity which may never be infringed by prejudice or fashion or ideology nor invoked against achievement.

In this spirit we, the Australian people, commit ourselves to this Constitution.

But, how much of this is, in any sense, about a constituton?

Do nation's have purposes?  Should nation's have purposes?  Does one drag out one's Oakeshott and contemplate the difference between society as a civil association -- a structure within which people pursue their own ends -- and society as an enterprise association -- something with a common purpose?

Should nations have statements of national purpose?

If one is the United States, the answer is clearly yes.  But the United States of America is the only nation-state in human history explicitly organised around a set of ideas:  ideas that it took a great revolutionary war to forge and then a murderous civil war to temper.  The ideals are indeed grand, but the cost was high.

Unlike the United States, Australia is not an ideocratic state.  We were not born in blood and revolution.  There was no withdrawal or expulsion of defeated Tories to confirm the nature of the new order.  On the contrary, Australia was born in perhaps the most civilised, and the most democratic, creation of a nation and constitutional order in human history.

A nation born in discussion, by popular vote, without shedding a drop of blood.  A grand achievement, actually.

So is it appropriate for Australia to inspire to the grandeur of the US preamble?

We the People of the United States, in Order to form a more perfect Union, establish Justice, insure domestic Tranquility, provide for the common defense, promote the general Welfare, and secure the Blessings of Liberty to ourselves and our Posterity, do ordain and establish this Constitution for the United States of America.

Only if we express the ideals of our original constitutional creation.  Which surely, must give us pause.  Not because those ideals are outdated -- the crucial ones surely aren't.  Indeed, our own revisiting of Constitutional Convening actually showed much less democratic confidence, and must less seriousness of purpose, than the original Conventions.  It is surely entirely appropriate that the memoir of the ConCon was written, not by a soon-to-be Prime Minister in Deakin, but by Steve Vizard, someone well-known for being a comedian.

No, the reason to give us pause is, if the constitutional founders did not write a preamble of grand vision back in the 1890s, why should we attempt to do so on their behalf a century later?

Perhaps we can only speak on our own behalf.  But what are the current, new purposes?  John Howard and Les Murray had a go, but reaction showed that there was no consensus on that point, nor for the set put together by the ALP, Democrats and Greens.

We are left with the purposes of the founders, and their refusal to import a grand vision into our founding national document.

Or perhaps they did.  Perhaps those workaday words expressed perfectly accurately the workaday nature of what they did.  What was, in its understated, way, as fine an achievement as the oft-cursed hand of the political animal has created.

Yes, well, perhaps the preamble is no laughing matter at all;  apart from the attempt to add one on 100 years later.  Thank you.

Covering up a Multitude of Social, Ethical Sins

A Royal Commission investigating a major scandal comprehensively discredits the report of a consultant who appears before it.  The consultant's professional association later appoints her to its ethics committee, and gets her to run a key session on training and professionalism at its annual conference.

Confronted with criticism of this curious appointment, the vice-president of the association reminds members that the ethics committee was set up "to engage with important contemporary issues and challenges and to make sure our code and practice are maintained at the highest standards".

It sounds like something out of former Premier Joh Bjelke-Petersen's administration in the late 1980s.  But unfortunately, it is the present-day story of my own profession of anthropology.

For a couple of decades the signs of decay have been there -- strong attacks on the notions of objectivity and scientific truth;  anthropologists calling on each other to champion the "values and aspirations" of radical minorities, and to promote Aboriginal interests "at Aboriginal directive";  serious suggestions that anthropologists might follow common Mafia practice by keeping two sets of records, a genuine set of research data which would be concealed, and a doctored set that could be made available to the courts or other authorities.

This sorry state of affairs culminated in the Hindmarsh Island Bridge scandal in South Australia during the mid-1990s.  At the apparent behest of a coalition of environmentalists, unionists and wealthy landowners, a group of Ngarrindjeri claimed that a bridge would desecrate their "secret women's business".

This was backed by a number of anthropologists, including Dr Deane Fergie from the University of Adelaide, who wrote a report arguing that "women's business" around Hindmarsh Island was "crucial for the reproduction of the Ngarrindjeri people".

After another group of fourteen respected Ngarrindjeri women publicly stated that the whole thing was a hoax to stop the bridge being built, the state government set up a Royal Commission.  The commission found the "women's business" story was a cynical fabrication from beginning to end, and was very critical of the anthropologists who had supported the claims, singling out Dr Fergie for particular comment.

Fergie had happily used the major study of the Ngarrindjeri by the late Ronald and Catherine Berndt, two of the nation's most experienced field anthropologists, to help her arguments.  But the Berndts had specifically stated that traditional Ngarrindjeri culture was unusual because there was no secret women's business.  This essential fact was completely absent from Fergie's report.

The response of the anthropology profession showed a total lack of understanding of the way that public confidence in its work might be restored.  As well as making Dr Fergie a star performer on its ethics committee, the Australian Anthropological Association and leading anthropologists denounced those few of their of their colleagues who had publicly stated that "secret women's business" was bogus.

The profession also mobilised to undermine the Royal Commission's findings.  Assisted by a number of other prominent anthropologists, Professor Diane Bell recently published a massive book titled Ngarrindjeri Wurruwarrin, which claims that the Royal Commission's conclusions were wrong and unjust.

Of course, no Royal Commission's findings should be treated as sacrosanct.  But those who wish to dispute such findings should first clearly explain why they were reached, and then demonstrate why they are wrong.  Bell didn't bother.  Neither did any other anthropologist.

Indeed, Bell's book shows that she has fully mastered the increasingly popular anthropological technique of simply ignoring crucial information that might undermine one's argument.  For instance, it does not mention that engineering works which would be just as desecrating to the supposed "women's business" as any bridge have gone ahead in the Hindmarsh Island bridge corridor without a hint of opposition from a single Ngarrindjeri.

One of these, the 1996 construction of a marina for a wealthy white anti-bridge land owner, required substantial excavation and pile driving, and was specifically approved by a key Ngarrindjeri proponent of "women's business".  According to Bell's book, this same Ngarrindjeri woman had been hospitalised some years previously because of the "spiritual wounding" she suffered when survey pegs for the proposed bridge were driven into the "sacred land" near the bridge site.

After Quadrant magazine recently published a paper of mine detailing some of the numerous strategic omissions and misrepresentations in Bell's book, the journalist Ben Hills decided to do some research on the general state of anthropology.  His unflattering article appeared in the Sydney Morning Herald last Saturday, and the Courier-Mail published a shorter version last Wednesday.

Hills quoted Dr Les Hiatt, one of our most distinguished scholars, lamenting the "crisis of credibility" that Australian anthropology currently faces.  But instead of trying to address the malaise that is damaging the profession, anthropologists went on the attack.  Hills has been summoned to appear at a specially convened session at the Anthropology Society annual conference in Sydney next Monday, no doubt to be screamed at and given a lecture on ethics.

But not all anthropologists are dismayed by Hills' revelations.  Some are positively delighted that the dirty linen is starting to come out in public.  Dr Tim O'Meara, from the University of Melbourne, sent a response to the Herald which he also forwarded to me, congratulating Hills and recounting an appalling interview he recently had with a post-graduate student in anthropology from the University of Queensland.

According to O'Meara, the student said in a matter-of-fact manner, "that in his consulting work on Aboriginal land cases, he and his professional colleagues commonly fabricate and distort evidence and otherwise do whatever is necessary to ensure that their Aboriginal clients win".  O'Meara added that in speaking so candidly, the student obviously assumed that as a professional anthropologist, he too would approve of such activity.

Anthropologists are no longer just ivory-tower academics studying kava drinking or initiation rites in tiny Pacific islands.  Their work on indigenous land and heritage claims has important implications for the social and economic future of this country.  We need to ensure that we keep the bastards honest.


ADVERTISEMENT